Free Essay

Commodities and Commodity Derivatives

In:

Submitted By derivative
Words 7956
Pages 32
FAO COMMODITY AND TRADE POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER No.22

Threshold cointegration in the sugarethanol-oil price system in Brazil: evidence from nonlinear vector error correction models
George Rapsomanikis and David Hallam1 Commodities and Trade Division Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations September 2006

1

The authors are Economist and Chief in the Trade Policy Service, Commodities and Trade Division.

FAO Commodity and Trade Policy Research Working Papers are published by the Commodities and Trade Division of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). They are working documents and do not reflect the opinion of FAO or its member governments. Also available at http://www.fao.org/es/ESC/ Additional copies of this working paper can be obtained from Olwen.Gotts@fao.org

The designations employed and the presentation of material in this information product do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations concerning the legal or development status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries.

All rights reserved. Reproduction and dissemination of material in this information product for educational or other non-commercial purposes are authorized without any prior written permission from the copyright holders provided the source is fully acknowledged. Reproduction of material in this information product for resale or other commercial purposes is prohibited without the written permission of the copyright holders. Applications for such permission should be addressed to the Chief, Publishing Management Service, Information Division, FAO, Viale delle Terme di Caracalla, 00100 Rome, Italy or by e-mail to copyright@fao.org. © FAO 2006

ABSTRACT
In this paper, the possibility of nonlinear dynamic adjustment in the sugar-ethanol-oil nexus in Brazil is examined. Threshold vector error correction models are employed to test for linearity in the adjustment of prices of sugar and oil, ethanol and oil and ethanol and sugar. Strong evidence of threshold type nonlinearity is found. The results suggest that sugar and oil and ethanol and oil prices are characterised by discrete threshold behaviour, whereas sugar and ethanol can be thought of as being linearly cointegrated. Threshold estimates suggest that sugar prices adjust rapidly to a long run equilibrium, determined by oil prices, in an asymmetric manner, when disequilibria are negative. The dynamic adjustment of ethanol prices is faster when the oil-ethanol price spread widens and ethanol prices are below a critical threshold. Both sugar and ethanol prices are found to be determined by oil prices and no evidence for a causal relationship that runs from oil to ethanol to sugar is found. JEL Classification: C12, C22, Q11. Keywords: Cointegration, Threshold, Oil, Ethanol, Sugar, Prices

RÉSUMÉ
Les auteurs étudient la possibilité d'un ajustement non-linéaire dynamique du rapport sucre-éthanolpétrole au Brésil. Des modèles de correction d'erreurs de vecteurs de seuil sont utilisés pour tester la linéarité de l'ajustement des prix du sucre et du pétrole, de l'éthanol et du pétrole, et de l'éthanol et du sucre. Des preuves solides de non-linéarité de seuil ont été observées. Les résultats indiquent que les prix du sucre et du pétrole et ceux de l'éthanol et du pétrole se caractérisent par un léger comportement de seuil, alors qu'on peut considérer que ceux du sucre et de l'éthanol présentent une cointégration linéaire. Selon les estimations de seuil, les prix du sucre s'ajustent rapidement à un équilibre à long terme, déterminé par les prix du pétrole, de façon asymétrique lorsque les déséquilibres sont négatifs. L'ajustement dynamique des prix de l'éthanol est plus rapide lorsque l'écart entre les prix du pétrole et de l'éthanol s'élargit et que les prix de l'éthanol sont inférieurs à un seuil critique. Il apparaît que les prix du sucre et de l'éthanol sont tous deux déterminés par les prix du pétrole et aucune preuve d'un rapport de cause à effet n'a été observée entre le pétrole et l'éthanol et le sucre.

RESUMEN
En este documento, se analiza la posibilidad de un ajuste dinámico no lineal en el nexo azúcar-etanolpetróleo en Brasil. Se emplean modelos de corrección de errores de vectores de umbral para probar la linealidad del ajuste de precios del azúcar y petróleo, etanol y petróleo y etanol y azúcar. Se hallaron marcados indicios de no linealidad del tipo de umbral. Los resultados sugieren que los precios del azúcar y el petróleo y del etanol y el petróleo se caracterizan por un discreto comportamiento de umbral, mientras que se puede considerar que el azúcar y el etanol están cointegrados linealmente. Las estimaciones de umbral sugieren que los precios del azúcar se ajustan rápidamente a un equilibro de largo plazo, determinado por los precios del petróleo, de una manera asimétrica, cuando los desequilibrios son negativos. El ajuste dinámico de los precios del etanol es más rápido cuando se amplía el margen de los precios del petróleo y el etanol y los precios del etanol se encuentran por debajo de un umbral crítico. Se descubrió que los precios del petróleo determinan tanto los precios del azúcar como del etanol y no existen indicios de que exista una relación causal que vaya del petróleo al etanol y del etanol al azúcar.

i

ii

CONTENTS
ABSTRACT/RÉSUMÉ/RESUMEN....................................................................................................... i 1 2 3 4 5 INTRODUCTION.......................................................................................................................... 1 THE SUGAR-ETHANOL-OIL MARKETS ................................................................................. 1 THRESHOLD VECTOR ERROR CORRECTION MODELS ..................................................... 3 EMPIRICAL RESULTS ................................................................................................................ 5 CONCLUSIONS ............................................................................................................................ 7 .......................................................................................................................................... 11

REFERENCES....................................................................................................................................... 9 TABLES APPENDIX .......................................................................................................................................... 13

.

iii

1

INTRODUCTION

Nonlinear vector error correction models (VECMs), since their introduction by Balke and Forby (1997), became increasingly popular in empirical applications that often focus, in agricultural economics and in commodity analysis, on testing the Law of One Price and assessing the nature and the extent of market integration (Abdulai, 2000; Fackler and Goodwin, 2001; Goodwin and Piggott, 2001; Barrett and Li, 2002; Sephton, 2003, Balcombe, forthcoming). In mainstream economics, nonlinear VECMs examine the term structure of interest rates and asset pricing. The popularity of nonlinear VECMs has led to contributions that developed an analogue to Granger’s representation theorem for nonlinear vector autoregressions (see Corradi et al., 2000; Escribano and Mira, 2002; Bec and Rahbec, 2004; Saikkonen, 2005). Threshold behaviour and discrete adjustment characterise many economic relationships that determine commodity and asset prices, inventories, interest and exchange rates and employment. Thresholds are normally thought of as functions of transaction and adjustment costs, or economic risk that prevent agents from adjusting continuously to changes in markets, as reflected by the empirical notion of cointegration and the related linear VECMs. Threshold cointegration, as considered by Balke and Forby (1997) includes such discrete adjustment to long run equilibrium. In this model, the cointegrating relation between two variables is inactive within a certain threshold, resulting in the variables not adjusting to deviations from the equilibrium, with adjustment taking place only when deviations become large and exceed the threshold. There is a number of important issues related to nonlinear VECMs. These include testing for the null of linear cointegration against the alternative of threshold cointegration, the identification and estimation of threshold parameters that govern regime switching, as well as that of the model’s slope parameters and the provision of the corresponding standard errors. These issues have been addressed in differing ways by a growing literature that encompass discrete and smooth threshold VECMs and Markov-chain VECMs, classical and Bayesian estimation and inference.1 In this paper, the discrete two regime threshold cointegration approach is adopted, utilising an algorithm developed by Hansen and Seo (2002) to test for threshold behaviour in the oil-ethanol-sugar price system in Brazil. The objective of this paper is to contribute in the current debate on the behaviour of commodity prices, and especially sugar prices, in the wake of the oil price hike. Prices of oil reached historically high levels in 2005-2006, resulting in increases in the Brazilian price of ethanol and sugar. Casual observation and cost-accounting exercises suggest the possibility of nonlinear behaviour in this system with sugar and ethanol prices adjusting to oil prices in a discrete manner when disequilibria exceed a critical threshold. The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a description of the relationship between the ethanol and sugar markets in Brazil and the manner this has been shaped by government intervention and technical change. Threshold behaviour and the estimation of TVECMs are discussed in section 3. Section 4 presents the empirical application and results, whilst section 5 presents the concluding remarks.

2

THE SUGAR-ETHANOL-OIL MARKETS

Demand for biofuels, such as methanol, ethanol and biodiesel, has been growing worldwide mainly due to environmental reasons. Biofuels, being derived from cellulosic biomass, emit lower carbon dioxide levels, as compared to fossil fuels and, for many Kyoto Protocol signatory countries, consist of the main option for mitigating greenhouse emissions. Ethanol, is currently the most widely used

Discrete and smooth threshold behaviour has been examined by Hansen and Seo (2002) and Kapetanions et al. (2006) respectively. For Bayesian estimation and inference of threshold VECMs see Balcombe (2006)

1

1

biofuel. Its production is based on commodities that are traditionally produced for food, such as sugarcane in Brazil, maize in the United States and wheat in the European Union. Brazil is the most important producer and consumer of ethanol in the world. In 2005-2006, approximately half of Brazil’s sugarcane production was processes into ethanol, sufficing for approximately one fifth of the country’s total transport fuel energy consumption. The growth of the Brazilian ethanol market has been realised due to a combination of factors, including government policies and technical change both in the processing of sugarcane into ethanol and in the manufacturing of vehicles that can use high level blends of ethanol with petrol. The national alcohol programme began in 1975 with the aim of reducing the country’s oil import bill. The programme consisted by a number of different policy instruments that included production quotas and institutional setting of the price for ethanol at a level lower than that of petrol, combined with subsidies to ethanol distillers. The ethanol programme was effectively eliminated in the 1990’s and a transition to full liberalisation took place between 1996 and 2000. Although, the government no longer exercises direct control over ethanol production and exports, it sets an official blending ratio of anhydrous ethanol with petrol to 20-25 per cent and periodically provides support in the form of purchases and sales from ethanol strategic reserves (International Energy Agency, 2004). In most countries, production costs of ethanol are higher relative to the costs of extraction of fossil fuels and government policies are essential in providing incentives to the industry in order to produce adequate quantities of biofuels (Goldemberg et al., 2004; OECD, 2006). However, the Brazilian alcohol programme assisted the industry to achieve economies of scale which, in conjunction with technology improvements, have resulted in Brazil being the only country where ethanol production costs are lower than the regional supply costs of petrol in volume terms. In energy terms, when prices per litre are converted into prices per energy unit, ethanol production costs are, in general, higher that regional supply costs for petrol. However, substantial increases in the price of oil not only during the period 2005-2006, but also for a number of months in the years 2002 and 2003 have resulted in increasing ethanol’s competitiveness (International Energy Agency, 2004; Goldemberger et al., 2004; Hamelick and Faaj, forthcoming). In a similar manner, cost-accounting exercises suggest that ethanol is competitive with petrol over a price level of US$39 per barrel (Organisation for Economic Development and Cooperation, 2006). With crude oil prices reaching historically high levels of US$60 per barrel since 2005 onwards, the demand for ethanol has strengthened considerably, with the price of ethanol in Brazil increasing by over 60 percent from May 2005 to the same month in 2006 (Food and Agriculture Organisation, 2006). Strong derived demand for sugarcane in Brazil, the world’s leading sugar producer and exporter, affected the world sugar market balance, thus fuelling world sugar prices that, during the first half of 2006, reached a level almost twice as high relative to the same period in 2005. Both formal cost-accounting and casual observations in market developments suggest that the oil price and the prices of sugar and ethanol in Brazil may co-move outside a certain threshold, that is defined over a certain price spread and mainly determined by adjustment costs in the sugar-ethanol processing industry, as well as by technical factors, such as the extent to which petrol can be substituted for ethanol. The introduction of flex-fuel vehicles that can use any combination of petrolethanol blends, but also pure ethanol only, has enhanced considerably the substitution possibilities between these fuels and the demand prospects for ethanol. The sale of flex-fuel cars, assisted by some tax incentives, has increased dramatically since their introduction in 2003. Flex-fuel cars comprised 40 percent of total car sales in Brazil in 2005, with forecasts for 2006 suggesting that their share in total car sales will increase to over 60 percent of total car sales, allowing petrol and ethanol to be purchased on the basis of relative prices (Goldemberger et al., 2004; Tokgoz and Elobeid, 2006). At the sugar mill – sugar distillery level, the decision to utilise sugarcane for the production of ethanol or sugar is also made on the basis of relative prices, as the industry consists of a large number of firms with a dual-processing structure that can that can switch easily between the production of sugar and ethanol. The surge in prices, in conjunction with the continuously increasing substitution possibilities between ethanol and oil, provides good economic reasoning for the existence of threshold effects in the oil-ethanol-sugar price complex in Brazil.

2

3

THRESHOLD VECTOR ERROR CORRECTION MODELS

Threshold vector error correction models (TVECMs) have been initially applied by Blake and Forby (1997) and Hansen and Seo (2002), having their origin in the Self-Exciting Autoregressive model (SETAR) by Tong (1978, 1983). In TVCEMs, threshold effects follow variants of the specification of Balke and Forby (1997) where the rate of adjustment to the long run equilibrium of two variables yt′ = y1,t , y2,t differs between regimes as follows:

(

)

∆yt = µt + F ( et −1 ) I + ∑ γ k ∆yt − k + ut F ( et −1 ) = δα1et −1 + (1 − δ ) α 2 et −1 i =1

k

(1)

δ

 = 1 if et −1 ≤ λ1 = 0 if et −1 > λ2

where t=1,...n, and F (

) is an indicator function of the error correction et-1 which is assumed to be

covariance stationary with zero mean. Vectors α i′ = α1,i , α 2,i and γ i′ = γ 1,i ,...γ k ,i

(

)

(

) are adjustment

and short run dynamic parameters. As in linear VECMs, the error correction term is defined as et −1 = y1,t −1 − β1 y2,t −1 − β 0 − β 2t , whilst the parameters β0 and β2 may assume values equal to zero. The TVECM errors ut is assumed to be an iid Gaussian sequence with a finite covariance matrix, Σ = E {ut ut′} . Models such as (1) with λ1 ≤ λ2 allow for a Band TVECM specification, where there is no adjustment inside the threshold, when the error abide by λ1 < et −1 ≤ λ2 , whilst a simple two-regime threshold model is specified with λ1 = λ2 . Other popular threshold models, such as the Momentum Threshold Autoregressive models of Granger and Lee (1999), Enders and Granger (1998) and Escribano and Pfann (1997) allow for the variables to adjust differently depending on whether the disequilibria are negative or positive.2 Balke and Forby (1997) view cointegration as a global characteristic of the series, whilst threshold behaviour consists of a local characteristic and, therefore, conduct estimation in two steps. The first step comprises of testing for non cointegration and the estimation of the cointegrating vector, by means of the Engle-Granger method. As a second step, tests for nonlinearity in the residuals of the cointegration relation are performed by means of cumulative least squares tests, as well as by the threshold autoregression tests developed by Tsay (1989). In theory, such a two-step estimation procedure is appropriate, as in the event that the residuals follow a univariate SETAR process, the threshold of this model should be identical with the threshold in the cointegrating relationship. In practice, however, such an estimation procedure may not be optimal, if threshold behaviour was present, since the likelihood function, on which the estimates of the cointegrating vector are based, depends on the threshold parameters. In addition, Balke and Forby (1997), on the basis of simulation exercises, note that non parametric tests, such as that of Tsay (1989) have, in general low power as compared to model based tests. Nevertheless, the estimation of bivariate threshold models is quite complex. In general, the inequality constraints implied by the threshold behaviour are difficult to enforce and lead to statistical problems in both estimation and inference. Firstly, Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) is complicated, as the likelihood function is jagged and not differentiable, rendering optimisation methods that are based on derivatives inadequate. Secondly, as second derivatives are non existent, inference is difficult.
2

Balke and Forby (1997) present more general specifications than the one reflected by equation (1) which give rise to a variety of non linear behaviour that can be characterised by more than one threshold, as well as by attractor mechanisms to the long equilibrium relationship different than the adjustment coefficients.

3

Finally, the threshold parameter is not identified under the null of a linear model, involving a Davies’ problem (Davies, 1987). Optimal classical statistics solutions to such a problem have been proposed by Andrews (1993) and Andrews and Ploberger (1994) and involve concentrating out nuisance parameters with respect to a priori supremum, or weighting function and calculating the critical values for the likelihood ratio statistics, as their distribution is non-standard. Hansen and Seo (2002) (hereinafter HS) follow such an approach and propose a quasi-MLE method based on a grid-search over the cointegrating vector and the threshold parameter, in conjunction with a ‘fixed regressor’ bootstrap to test for threshold effects in a two regime model as in (1) with λ1 = λ2 = λ and

β 0 = β 2 = 0 .In more detail, HS consider the following likelihood function: n n 1 n L ( ai′, γ i′, β1 , Σ, λ ) = − log Σ − ∑ ut ( ai′, γ i′, β1 , Σ, λ )′ ∑ −1 ut ( ai′, γ i′, β1 , Σ, λ ) 2 2 t =1 t =1

(2)

The maximisation of the likelihood function is feasible if parameters (α i′, γ i′, Σ ) are concentrated out, by holding parameters ( β1 , λ ) fixed, thus giving rise to a constrained maximum likelihood estimator that is equivalent to OLS regressions of ∆yt on et −1 and ∆yt −1 ,...,∆yt − k , for each fixed β1 and λ, and for sub-samples
1 i

ˆ ˆ ( a′ ( β , λ ) , γˆ′ ( β , λ ) , Σ ( β , λ ) ) are utilised to yield the concentrated likelihood: i 1 1

for

which

et −1 ≤ λ and et −1 > λ1 . As a second step, the estimates

n ˆ ˆ ˆ L ( β1 , λ ) = L β1 , λ , ai′ ( β1 , λ ) , γˆi′ ( β1 , λ ) , Σ ( β1 , λ ) = − log Σ ( β1 , λ ) − n 2
The maximum likelihood estimator

(

)

(3)

( βˆ , λˆ )
1

ˆ minimise log Σ ( β1 , λ ) subject to a constraint that

reflects the probability P that observations lie over or below the threshold:

π 0 ≤ P ( et −1 ≤ λ ) ≤ 1 − π 0

(4)

with π0 being a trimming parameter usually taking values between 0.05 and 0.15 (Andrews, 1993). As the function L is jagged and not differentiable, HS propose a numerical maximisation method based on an evenly grid-search starting with consistent estimates of the cointegrating vector from the linear model. The algorithm sets sub-regions of the parameter space for β1 based on a confidence interval

[ β1l , β1u ] constructed from [λl , λu ] is obtained so as

% the linear estimate β1 . For the threshold parameter λ , a sub-region th λl and λu represent the π 0 and (1 − π 0 ) percentiles of the error th

% correction term, et-1, also based on the linear estimate β . The null of linear cointegration is tested against the alternative of threshold cointegration by means of the supremum Lagrance Multiplier test following Andrews (1993) and Andrews and Ploberger (1994):

% SupLM = sup LM β1 , λ λl ≤ λ ≤ λu

(

)

(5)

% The function LM β1 , λ is not differentiable and, therefore, is evaluated by means of a grid-search over [ λl , λu ] . HS also propose an additional test SupLM 0 with β1 fixed at an a priori known, or estimated value. Both LM tests are based on the restriction that the adjustment coefficients are equal, α1=α2, whilst the threshold parameter is treated as fixed to its maximum likelihood value. Since the asymptotic distribution of the test is not known, it is approximated by means of a residual bootstrap. In addition, HS perform a ‘fixed regressor’ bootstrap procedure, holding the regressors fixed at their

(

)

4

sample values (Hansen 1996). The fixed regressor bootstrap is not intended to approximate better the finite sample distribution of the test statistic, as compared to the residuals bootstrap, but allows for heteroscedasticity of unknown form and provides heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors.

4

EMPIRICAL RESULTS

The HS estimation method is applied on logarithmic transformations of weekly prices for crude oil, ethanol and sugar in Brazil, expressed in Real for the period between July 2000 and May 2006.3 Price pairs of sugar and oil, ethanol and oil and ethanol and sugar are examined, assuming that causation runs from oil to ethanol to sugar. The method comprises of a series of tests, starting with tests for unit roots and stationarity, estimation of cointegrating relationships between price pairs and testing for non cointegration, estimation of linear and threshold VECMs and testing for the null of linearity against the alternative of threshold-type non linearity. The direction of causation in the variables is also investigated by means of Granger causality tests. Table 1 presents the results of unit root and stationarity tests. Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Phillips and Peron (PP) tests for unit roots were conducted along with the Kwiatkowski-PhillipsSchmidt-Shin (KPPS) test for stationarity.4 The lag lengths were selected using the Schwarz-Bayes information criterion. The ADF and PP tests fail to reject the null of unit roots around the mean for all series at a 5 percent level of significance. Similar evidence is provided by the KPPS tests that rejects stationarity around the mean for all prices at the same confidence level. The inclusion of a deterministic trend in the tests provides some mixed evidence. For sugar the unit root tests fail to reject the null of unit roots around a trend at a 5 percent level. For oil and ethanol the tests suggest that the price series could be consistent with being stationary around a trend at a 10 percent level. Likewise the KPPS test fails to reject the null of stationarity around a trend at 10 percent level of significance. Nevertheless, all tests indicate that, at 5 percent confidence level the series are consistent with unit roots around a trend. The results of tests for pair-wise non cointegration between sugar-oil, ethanol-oil, and sugar-ethanol are presented in Table 2. Non cointegration is tested utilising the Johansen approach that is based on MLE and likelihood ratio testing (Johansen, 1988). The results provide sufficient evidence for cointegration for all price pairs, being consistent with variables that contain unit roots and have a stationary cointegrating relation. The tests were conducted on the basis of a cointegrating VAR with a drift and linear trends in the series levels, whilst the lag length was selected by means of the SwartzBayes information criterion.5 The TVECMs are estimated following HS, on the basis of a a priori known cointegrating vector, estimated by means of the Johansen MLE approach, as opposed to estimating the cointegrating vector by means of the grid-search. Consequently, testing for linear cointegration is conducted by means of the SupLM 0 test-statistic. This choice of sequential testing procedure, consisting of tests for non cointegration, estimation of the cointegrating vector, estimation of TVECMs and tests for linear cointegration, may suffer from bias and, therefore, warrants more discussion. HS restrict the deterministic components of the VAR to include an intercept in the VECM, that reflects linear deterministic trends in the levels of the variables that cancel in the cointegrating relation, but no intercept in the cointegrating relation. In the case of prices in different, but strongly related markets, an
Data on sugar and ethanol have been collected by UNICA, the Sao Paolo Sugar Cane Agro Industry Union (www.unica.com.br), data on world oil prices have been collected from the Energy Information Administration of the United States government (www.iea.doe.gov) and information on exchange rates from the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis (http://research.stlouisfed.org). The data covers the period 24 March 2001 to 20 May 2006.
4 5 3

For these tests see Dickey and Fuller (1979), Phillips and Perron (1988) and Kwiatkowski et al. (1992).

For the sugar-oil and ethanol-oil price VARs, two lags were selected. For the ethanol-sugar VAR, four lags were selected. Intercept was included in both the cointegration relation and the VECM.

5

intercept ought to be included in the cointegration relation in order to ensure that the error correction term in the VECM has a zero mean. As a grid-search over three parameters, that is the intercept, β1 and λ, would be very complex and possibly intractable, it is preferable that the application relies on priori estimated cointegrating vector. HS conduct Monte Carlo experiments in order to assess the power of both tests and report that the SupLM0 test has slightly more power that the SupLM in which the cointegrating vector is initially unknown and is estimated by means of the grid-search. Estimates of the linear VECMs and the threshold VECMs, obtained by means of the HS approach are presented in Tables 3 to 5. The grid-search for λ is conducted over 300 grid points, whilst both the fixed regressor and the standard residual bootstrap experiments are used to calculate the p-values for the SupLM0 test. Note that in all estimated linear VECMs, the adjustment coefficients are very low, mainly due to the high frequency of the price series. For the sugar-oil price pair, presented in Table 3, the estimated cointegrating parameter is 0.64, implying that a 10 percent increase in the price of oil brings about over 6 percent increase in the price of sugar. The value of the SupLM0 test is 27.47 and the p-values are 0.028 and 0.004 for the fixed regressor and the residual bootstraps respectively, supporting the threshold cointegration hypothesis. In both linear and threshold VECMs, the statistical significance of the estimates of the adjustment parameters also reveal that oil is the dominant market. The adjustment parameter in the sugar ECM is statistically significant, whilst that in the oil ECM is not, suggesting that, in the long run, oil prices Granger-cause sugar prices, but not vice versa, an outcome that corresponds to long run weak exogeneity in the econometric sense (Granger, 1988). The estimated threshold is -0.02 and identifies two regimes, an extreme regime and a typical one, with 16 and 84 percent of the data respectively. The adjustment coefficients in the sugar price ECM indicate a fast adjustment to the long run equilibrium in the extreme regime with an estimated value of -0.21.6 In the typical regime adjustment is about twenty times slower. Since the TVECM has been estimated using the logarithmic transformations of the variables, the threshold implies that adjustment is fast when sugar prices lie 2 percent below its long run equilibrium, as this is determined by the price of oil. Nevertheless, a value for the threshold that as low as -0.02 may indicate that the nonlinear relationship between the sugar and oil prices can be characterised as asymmetric, allowing the variables to adjust differently depending on whether the disequilibria are negative or positive (see Granger and Lee, 1999; Escribano and Pfann, 1997; Enders and Granger, 1998). The estimated parameters of the differenced terms that reflect the transitory effects, suggest strong autoregressive behaviour in sugar, with a change in one week been followed by a somewhat smaller change in the following week. In the short run, oil prices also influence the sugar price level, at least in the typical regime. Nevertheless, most of effect is accounted for by the error correction term.7 The estimates of the ethanol-oil price relationship are presented in Table 4. The cointegrating parameter estimate is 0.60, approximately equal to that in the sugar-oil price relationship. In the long run changes in oil prices are incompletely, but for the most part, transmitted to the price of ethanol. The SupLM0 test statistic has a value of 21.47, with p-values the fixed regressor and the residual bootstraps at 0.02 and 0.03 respectively, strongly rejecting the null of linear cointegration. The threshold parameter λ, is estimated at -0.20, with an extreme regime accounting for 18 percent of the observations and a typical regime accounting for 82 percent of the observations. As in the case of sugar, oil appears to influence the long run development of ethanol, in a ‘no levels feedback’ manner. As the adjustment parameters in the oil ECMs are statistically not significant, oil can be considered as a driving trend in the system, causing ethanol prices in the Granger sense, being weakly exogenous. The threshold in conjunction with the estimated adjustment parameters in the ethanol price threshold
Figures of the negative log-likelihood function against threshold values, as well as figures depicting the relationship between the error correction term and the change in the dependent variable in the VECM are presented in the Appendix. This observation is based on the statistical significance of the estimates in the TVECMs. It is important to note that HS have no formal distribution theory and therefore warn towards cautious interpretation of the EickerWhite standard errors.
7 6

6

ECMs indicate that ethanol price adjusts about four times as fast to its long run equilibrium in the extreme regime, as compared to the typical regime. The adjustment is rapid at approximately 12 percent of the disequilibrium, when ethanol and oil prices abide by the relationship, Ethanol ≤ 0.60Oil − 0.20 , indicating that for this fast adjustment to take place the price of ethanol should be about 20 percent below its long run trend, as this is determined by the price of oil. The estimated TVECMs also suggest that there is also strong autoregressive behaviour in both ethanol and oil prices. However, the evidence suggests that the transitory effects between the prices are minimal. The support for threshold cointegration, as well as the estimated threshold value confirm the a priori expectations for non linear behaviour between ethanol and oil prices. Oil price increases appear to draw ethanol prices at a faster rate, when the later are possibly sluggish, lingering well below their long run trend. For the ethanol-sugar price relationship, the results are presented in Table 5. The cointegrating parameter is estimated to be equal to 0.87, a level quite close to unity. The restriction of β1=1 was imposed and tested by means of a Likelihood Ratio test, as suggested by Johansen and Juselius (1992). The test statistic value is 1.02 and hence accepted with a p-value of 0.31, suggesting that changes in the price of sugar are completely transmitted to the price of ethanol in the long run. The SupLM 0 test fails to reject the null of linear cointegration. The value of the test statistic is 27.61 and the p-values are 0.12 and 0.19 for the fixed regressor and the residual bootstraps respectively. The estimated linear VECM suggests that sugar is weakly exogenous and influences the long run behaviour of ethanol prices without being influenced by them, as the adjustment parameter in the sugar price ECM is not statistically significant. This is a rather surprising result as one would expect that increases in the demand of ethanol and subsequent increases in the derived demand for sugarcane would mean that ethanol prices Grangercause sugar prices, with the direction and order of causation running from oil to ethanol to sugar. These results reflect, in conjunction with the results of the sugar-oil price relationship, that sugar prices respond to changes in the price of oil, instead of following ethanol prices.

5

CONCLUSIONS

The paper explored the possibility of threshold effects in the relation between prices of sugar and oil, ethanol and oil, and ethanol and sugar, applying a threshold cointegration approach for estimation and inference. The results supported threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment in the sugar and oil, and sugar and ethanol price relations. Thus, the evidence supports a priori expectations on the behaviour of these prices, with the dynamic behaviour of sugar and ethanol prices being governed by oil prices and more specifically by the magnitude of the spread between these prices and the price of oil. It appears that when the spread widens, with the price of oil increasing and the prices of sugar and ethanol being sluggish, adjustment of these prices to their long run trend is fast. More specifically, the long run behaviour of sugar prices was found to be determined by oil prices and, rather surprisingly, not ethanol prices. Sugar prices were found to adjust to a long run equilibrium, determined by oil prices, in an asymmetric manner with adjustment being fast when disequilibria are negative and slow when disequilibria are positive. Ethanol prices were also found to be Grangercaused by oil prices. Evidence for threshold behaviour suggested that ethanol prices adjust fast when they are about 20 percent lower than their trend, as this is determined by oil prices. There was no evidence for threshold cointegration between sugar and ethanol prices. The results suggested that these prices were linearly cointegrated, with sugar being the dominant market. In addition, the tests suggested that changes in the sugar price are completely transmitted to the price of ethanol. The direction and order of causation is also an interesting finding. The results indicate that oil is weakly exogenous and Granger-causes both ethanol and sugar. It appears that sugar responds directly to oil price changes and not in a successive manner through ethanol prices.

7

The analysis suggests that if the prices of crude oil were to continue their upward trend, ethanol will become increasingly competitive with petrol. World sugar prices will also increase, as Brazil, the major sugar producer and exporter in the world, influences the world sugar balance. In the long run, sustained high sugar prices may result in an increase in the area under sugarcane not only in Brazil, but also in developing low-cost producer countries, such as Malaysia, that already invest in ethanol production. Nevertheless, it is important to note that infrastructure development is necessary to allow further expansion of the area under sugar cane and of ethanol processing capacity in many countries. Whilst, high sugar prices may benefit sugar farmers, consumers become worse off. Such a development may not result in net losses for many developing countries that produce and export sugar, given the relatively low expenditure on sugar as compared to other foods. Nevertheless, sustained increases in oil price may result, in the long run, in increases in the prices of other commodities that may be used for ethanol production, such as maize, as well as changes in the allocation of land. Given the large volume of food commodities that are necessary for the production of relatively small volumes of biofuels and the demand for food, the co-movement of oil and food commodities may result in high food prices, thus exerting additional pressure on food importing developing and least developed countries.

8

REFERENCES
Abdulai, A. 2000. “Spatial Price Transmission and Asymmetry in the Ghanaian Maize Market.” Journal of Development Studies, 63:327-349. Andrews, D.W.K. 1993. “Tests for Parameter Stability and Structural Change with Unknown Change Point.” Econometrica, 61:821-856. Andrews, D.W.K. and W. Ploberger. 1994. “Optimal Tests when a Nuisance parameter is Present Only Under the Alternative.” Econometrica, 62:1383-1414. Balcombe, K. 2006. Bayesian Estimation of Cointegrating Thresholds in the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Empirical Economics, 31:277-289 Balcombe K., A. Bailey and J. Brooks. Forthcoming “Threshold Effects in Price Transmission: The Case of Brazilian Wheat, Maize and Soya Prices.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, in press. Balke, N.S. and T.B. Fomby. 1997. “Threshold Cointegration.” International Economic Review 38:627-645. Barrett, C.B. and J.R. Li. 2002. “Distinguishing Between Equilibrium and Integration in Spatial Price Analysis.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 84:292-307. Bec, F. and A. Rahbek. 2004. “Vector Equilibrium Correction models with Nonlinear Discontinuous Adjustments.” Econometrics Journal 7:628-651. Corradi, V., N. Swanson and H. White. 2000. “Testing for Stationarity Ergodicity and for Comovements between Nonlinear Discrete Time Markov Processes.” Journal of Econometrics 96:3973. Davies, R.B. 1987. Hypothesis Testing When a Nuisance parameter is Present Only Under the Alternative.” Biometrica, 74:33-44. Dickey D. and Fuller W. 1979. “Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root.” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74:427-431. Enders, W. and C.W.J. Granger. 1998. “Unit Root Tests and Asymmetric Adjustment with an Example Using the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 16:304-311. Escribano, A. and S. Mira. 2002. “Nonlinear Error Correction Models.” Journal of Time Series Analysis 23:509-522. Escribano, A. and G.A. Pfann. 1998. “Nonlinear Error Correction, Asymmetric Adjustment and Cointegration.” Economic Modelling 15:197-216 Fackler, P.L. and B.K. Goodwin. (2002). “Spatial Price Analysis.” Handbook of Agricultural Economics. B.L. Gardner and G.C. Rausser, eds. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science. Food and Agriculture Organization, United Nations. 2006. “Food Outlook.” No.1, June. Goldemberg, J., S.T. Coelho and O. Lucon. 2004. “How Adequate Policies Can Push Renewables.” Energy Policy 32:1141-1146. Goodwin B.K. and N.E. Piggott. 2001. “Spatial Market Integration in the Presence of Threshold Effects.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 82:302-317. Granger C.W.J. and T.H. Lee. 1989. “Investigation of Production Sales and Inventory Relationships using Multicointegration and Non-symmetric Error Correction Models.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 4, (Supplement: Special Issue on Topics in Applied Econometrics):S-145-S-159. Hamelinck, C.N. and A.P.C. Faaij. Forthcoming. “Outlook for Advanced Biofuels.” Energy Policy, in press.

9

Hansen, B. E. 1996. “Inference when a Nuisance Parameter is not Identified Under the Null Hypothesis.” Econometrica 64:413-430. Hansen, B. and B. Seo. 2002. “Testing for Two-Regime Threshold Cointegration in Vector ErrorCorrection Models.” Journal of Econometrics 110:293-318. International Energy Agency. 2004. Biofuels for Transport: An International Perspective, France:Chirat. Johansen, S. 1988. “Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12:231-254. Johansen, S. and K. Juselius. 1992. “Testing Structural Hypotheses in Multivariate Cointegration Analysis of the PPP and the UIP for UK.” Journal of Econometrics, 53:211-244. Kapetanios, G., Y. Shin and A. Snell. 2006. “Testing for Cointegration in Nonlinear Smooth Transition Error Correction Models.” Econometric Theory, 22:279-303. Kwiatkowski, D., P.C.B. Phillips, P. Schmidt and Y. Shin 1992. “Testing the Null of Stationarity Against the Alternative of a Unit Root: How Sure Are We That Economic Time Series Have a Unit Root?” Journal of Econometrics, 54:159-178. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 2006. “Agricultural Market Impacts of Future Growth in the Production of Biofuels.” Working Party on Agricultural Policies and Markets, February. Phillips, P.C.B. and P. Perron. 1988. “Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression.” Biometrica, 75:335-346. Saikkonen, P. 2005. “Stability Results for Nonlinear Error Correction Models.” Journal of Econometrics 127:69-81. Seo, B. 2004. “Testing for Nonlinear Adjustment in Smooth Transition Vector Error Correction Models” Econometric Society, Far Eastern Meetings. Sephton, P.E. 2003. “Spatial Market Arbitrage and Threshold Cointegration.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 85:1041-1046. Tokgoz, S. and A. Elobeid. 2006. “Policy and Competitiveness of US and Brazilian Ethanol.” Iowa Agr Review 12, No. 2. Tong, H. 1983. Threshold Models in Nonlinear Time Series Analysis: Lecture Notes in Statistics, 21. Berlin:Springer. Tsay, R.S. 1989. “Testing and Modelling Threshold Autoregressive Processes.” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 84:231-240.

10

TABLES
Table 1 – Unit root and stationarity tests without time trend ADF Sugar Oil Ethanol -1.82 -1.33 -2.48 PP -1.68 -1.18 -2.23 KPPS 0.71 1.89 0.73 ADF -2.44 -3.39 -3.17 with time trend PP -2.26 -3.39 -2.70 KPPS 0.12 0.13 0.13

Note: Critical values for the ADF and PP tests without (with) a deterministic trend for 5 percent and 10 percent level of significance are -2.87 (-3.42) and -2.57 (-3.14) respectively. For the KPPS the corresponding critical values are 0.46 (0.15) and 0.35. (0.12).

Table 2 – Johansen test for non cointegration
Maximum Eigenvalue test Zero vs One Cointegrating Vector Sugar-Oil Oil-Ethanol Ethanol-Sugar 20.18 19.54 21.44 One vs Two Cointegrating Vectors 2.59 2.54 2.98

Note: Critical values for 5 percent and 10 percent level of significance are 15.49 and 13.42 respectively.

Table 3 - Linear and Threshold VECMs: Sugar - Oil
Regressors Percentage observations et-1 ∆Sugar, t-1 ∆Oil, t-1 Intercept Cointegrating Vector Threshold Estimate λ SupLM0
Note: Standard errors in italics

Linear VECM of Sugar -0.0261 0.0061 0.7799 0.0512 0.0533 0.0269 Oil -0.0076 0.0116 -0.0416 0.0789 0.2377 0.0625

Threshold VECMs First regime 0.16 Sugar -0.2099 0.0587 0.9570 0.0882 0.0515 0.1007 Oil -0.0409 0.0821 -0.1344 0.1214 0.2190 0.1396 -0.0034 0.0098 Second regime 0.84 Sugar -0.0154 0.0067 0.7508 0.0557 0.0594 0.0281 0.0023 0.0026 Oil -0.0165 0.0155 -0.0258 0.0923 0.2379 0.0674 0.0083 0.0051

0.0061 0.0048 -0.0061 0.0022 0.0034 0.0052 (-1, 0.6428) -0.0169 Test Statistic Value: 21.4723 Fixed regressor p-value: 0.0286 Residual bootstrap p-value: 0.0470

11

Table 4 - Linear and Threshold VECMs: Εthanol - Oil
Regressors Percentage observations et-1 ∆Ethanol, t-1 ∆Oil, t-1 Intercept Cointegrating Vector Threshold Estimate λ SupLM0
Note: Standard errors in italics

Linear VECM of Ethanol -0.0389 0.0136 0.5512 0.0751 0.0195 0.0425 Oil -0.0099 0.0122 0.0264 0.0550 0.2331 0.0638

Threshold VECMs First regime 0.18 Ethanol -0.1279 0.0594 0.5397 0.1248 0.2824 0.1805 Oil 0.0027 0.0386 -0.0345 0.0699 0.0283 0.1490 0.0168 0.0156 Second regime 0.82 Ethanol -0.0332 0.0165 0.5870 0.0898 -0.0289 0.0358 0.0008 0.0023 Oil 0.0104 0.0208 0.0648 0.0680 0.2707 0.0677 0.0002 0.0208

0.0006 0.0029 -0.0378 0.0136 0.0027 0.0235 (-1, 0.6004) -0.2059 Test Statistic Value: 21.4686 Fixed regressor p-value: 0.0250 Residual bootstrap p-value: 0.0364

Table 5 - Linear and Threshold VECMs: Ethanol - Sugar
Regressors et-1 ∆Ethanol, t-1 ∆Sugar, t-1 ∆Ethanol, t-2 ∆Sugar, t-2 ∆Ethanol, t-3 ∆Sugar, t-3 Intercept Cointegrating Vector Threshold Estimate λ SupLM0 H0: β1=1 vs H1: β1≠1 Likelihood Ratio test
Note: Standard errors in italics

Linear VECM Ethanol -0.0682 0.0195 0.6678 0.0989 0.0571 0.1047 -0.2583 0.1074 0.0606 0.1292 0.1306 0.0781 -0.1457 0.0712 0.0007 0.0021 (-1, 0.8711) 0.0331 Test Statistic Value: 27.6159 Fixed regressor p-value: 0.1226 Residual bootstrap p-value: 0.1786 Value: 1.02 p-value: 0.31 Sugar 0.0003 0.0106 0.1176 0.0476 1.0262 0.0703 0.0256 0.0557 -0.3439 0.0869 -0.0499 0.0451 -0.0650 0.0746 0.0008 0.0012

12

APPENDIX
Figure A1 – Sugar-Oil Concentrated Negative Log-Likelihood

Figure A2 – Sugar Price Response to Error Correction

13

Figure A3 – Ethanol-Oil Concentrated Negative Log-Likelihood

Figure A4 – Ethanol Price Response to Error Correction

14

FAO COMMODITY AND TRADE POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPERS 2006 22 21 20 19 18 17 16 15 14 13 Threshold cointegration in the sugar-ethanol-oil price system in Brazil: evidence from nonlinear vector error correction models George Rapsomanikis and David Hallam Estimating price elasticities of supply for cotton: a structural time-series approach Ben Shepherd Market access and preferential trading schemes: Evidence from selected developed and developing countries Piero Conforti and Luca Salvatici The role of agriculture in reducing poverty in Tanzania: A household perspective from rural Kilimanjaro and Ruvuma Alexander Sarris, Sara Savastano and Luc Christiaensen Producer demand and welfare benefits of rainfall insurance in the United Republic of Tanzania Alexander Sarris, Panayiotis Karfakis, and Luc Christiaensen Household vulnerability in rural Tanzania Alexander Sarris and Panayiotis Karfakis The use of organized commodity markets to manage food import price instability and risk Alexander Sarris, Piero Conforti and Adam Prakash The impact of domestic and international commodity price volatility on agricultural income instability in Ghana, Vietnam and Peru George Rapsomanikis and Alexander Sarris Linkages between domestic and international maize markets, and market-based strategies for hedging maize import price risks in Tanzania Alexander Sarris and Ekaterini Mantzou Food import risk in Malawi: simulating a hedging scheme for Malawi food imports using historical data Wouter Zant

2005 12 The effect of direct payments of the OECD countries in world agricultural markets. Evidence from partial and general equilibrium frameworks Piero Conforti 11 The impact of import surges: country case study results for Senegal and Tanzania Ramesh Sharma, David Nyange, Guillaume Duteutre and Nancy Morgan

2004 10 Agricultural trade liberalization in the Doha round. Alternative scenarios and strategic interactions between developed and developing countries Piero Conforti and Luca Salvatici 9 The EU cotton policy regime and the implications of the proposed changes for producer welfare Giannis Karagiannis 8 The impact of domestic and trade policies on the world cotton market Daneswar Poonyth, Alexander Sarris, Ramesh Sharma and Shangnan Shui 7 Price transmission in selected agricultural markets Piero Conforti 6 The marketing potential of date palm fruits in the European market Pascal Liu 5 World markets for organic citrus and citrus juices: Current market situation and medium-term prospects Pascal Liu 4 Agricultural Policy Indicators Timothy Josling and Alberto Valdés (also issued as ESA Working Paper No. 2004/4) 2003 3 Quantifying appropriate levels of the WTO bound tariffs on basic food products in the context of the Development Box proposals Ramesh Sharma 2 The WTO and environmental and social standards, certification and labelling in agriculture. Cora Dankers 1 The Brazilian ethanol programme: impacts on world ethanol and sugar markets Tatsuji Koizumi

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Commodity Derivative Trading India

...ABSTRACT Commodity markets are important constituents of the financial market of any country. Similarly, commodity derivatives markets play a crucial role in price risk management as well as price discovery in any agriculture dominated economy like India. The present study is related with the derivative market in different commodities in India. The study has tried to describe about the various functions of commodity derivatives market like the players (hedgers, speculators, and arbitrages), the functions of a commodity exchange (NCDEX), clearing and settlement process and also the future potential of commodity derivatives. The role of the regulatory body (forward market commission) and its function is also being discussed. Also the recent development in the field of commodities derivative trading is also being discussed. This report also discuss the evolution of derivatives market in India and also deal with the derivatives like future, forward, swaps and options. Synopsis Commodity markets are an important constituent of the financial markets of any country. It is the market where a wide range of products, viz., precious metals, base metals, crude oil, energy and soft commodities like palm oil, coffee etc. are traded. It is important to develop a vibrant, active and liquid commodity market. This would help investors to hedge their commodity risk, take speculative positions in commodities and exploit arbitrage opportunities in the market....

Words: 2615 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Commodity Derviatives in India

...Commodity Derivatives Market in India: Development, Regulation and Future Prospects Introduction The Indian economy is witnessing a mini revolution in commodity derivatives and risk management. Commodity options trading and cash settlement of commodity futures had been banned since 1952 and until 2002 commodity derivatives market was virtually nonexistent, except some negligible activity on an OTC basis. Now in September 2005, the country has 3 national level electronic exchanges and 21 regional exchanges for trading commodity derivatives. As many as eighty (80) commodities have been allowed for derivatives trading. The value of trading has been booming and is likely to cross the $ 1 Trillion mark in 2006 and, if all goes well, seems to be set to touch $5 Trillion in a few years. Chequred History The history of organized commodity derivatives in India goes back to the nineteenth century when the Cotton Trade Association started futures trading in 1875, barely about a decade after the commodity derivatives started in Chicago. Over time the derivatives market developed in several other commodities in India. Following cotton, derivatives trading started in oilseeds in Bombay (1900), raw jute and jute goods in Calcutta (1912), wheat in Hapur (1913) and in Bullion in Bombay (1920). However, many feared that derivatives fuelled unnecessary speculation in essential commodities, and were detrimental to the healthy functioning of the markets for the underlying commodities...

Words: 3982 - Pages: 16

Premium Essay

Commodity Swaps

...POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER 1667 Dealing with Commodity Price Uncertainty Plantos Varangis Dont Larson Market liberalization has increased the appeal of commodity derivative instruments (such as futures, options, swaps, and commodity-linked notes)as a means of managing price uncertainty. many In emerging countries both government and the private sector are increasinglyusing these instruments. The World Bank International Economics Department Commodity Policy and Analysis Unit October 1996 POLICYRESEARCH WORKINGPAPER1667 Summary findings Liberalization in commodity markets has brought profound changes in the way price risks are allocated and managed in commodity subsectors. Price risks are increasingly allocated to private traders and farmers rather than absorbed by the government. The success of market reform depends on the ability of the emerging private sector to make full use of the available range of modern commodity marketing, price risk management (such as futures, options, swaps, commodity bonds, and so on), and financing instruments. Because farmers do not generally have direct access to these instruments, interinediaries must be developed. Larger private traders and banks are in the best position to become these intermediaries. Preconditions needed for accessing modern commodity marketing, price risk management, and financing instruments are: * Creating an appropriate legal, regulatory, and institutional framework. * Reducing government...

Words: 4953 - Pages: 20

Premium Essay

Market

...Issues and Concerns of Commodity Derivative Markets in India: An Agenda for Research Nilanjan Ghosh 1. Introduction Commodity derivative markets have traditionally been a contentious issue at various policy forums across the world, particularly with the imbroglio created by allegations from various corners that they encourage excessive speculation and are therefore responsible for the recent commodity price escalation. While this suspicion of excessive speculation in the commodity markets has always been there among policymakers in developing nations like India, it has become more widespread since 2008 in the wake of worldwide inflationary pressures on food and energy. The sudden deflation in the value of various assets underlying different derivatives, which includes commodity derivatives, in the wake of the global meltdown has provoked greater apprehension about the economic utility of futures markets. The suspicion has reached such a high that even the U.S., the biggest proponent of market forces with the most active commodity exchanges in the world, is considering new modes of regulation, and is also investigating the role of commodity derivative trading in the steep rise in prices of wheat, rice, and crude oil. On the other hand, ever since commodity derivative trading was allowed in India in the new millennium, there has always been a hue and cry against such markets, with the alleged notion of excessive “speculation”, though there has rarely been any evidence for it. Rather...

Words: 6878 - Pages: 28

Premium Essay

Case Study on Pepsico’s Use of Financial Derivatives

...Case Study on PepsiCo’s Use of Financial Derivatives 1. Introduction 1.1 PepsiCo’s History The Pepsi-Cola Company was incorporated in 1919 by Caleb Bradham, the inventor of the Pepsi-Cola soft drink. PepsiCo became a multinational beverage and snack food company in 1965 when Pepsi-Cola merged with Frito-Lay. Since the 1965 merger PepsiCo has expanded its operations by acquiring Quaker-Oats, Tropicana, and Gatorade brands. With sales of $66.86 billion in 2014 and with products sold in over 200 countries, PepsiCo is one of the leading food and beverage companies in the world (PepsiCo, 2014). 1.2 PepsiCo’s Industry The beverage and snack food industries are both in the mature stage in their life cycles, and companies in these industries largely depend on product innovation, brand recognition, and low prices to remain competitive. Like all companies PepsiCo faces risk of increases in operating expenses and decreases in net income due to market risk. Companies in PepsiCo’s industry have been forced to expand its product offerings into healthy foods and drinks due to an insurgent health and wellness in American culture. 1.3 PepsiCo’s Competitors PepsiCo’s top competitors consist of The Coca-Cola Company, Dr Pepper Snapple Group, and Nestle; additionally, because PepsiCo is a multinational company it must also compete with countless local snack and beverage companies across the globe. Coca-Cola has been viewed as PepsiCo’s main rival for around 100 years, and the competition...

Words: 4581 - Pages: 19

Premium Essay

Derivatives

...FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES (A Future of Indian Financial Market) Dr. Ritu Kothiwal, Associate Professor, BIET, Hyderabad Contact No: 09246193330 Email Id: kothiwal55@gmail.com Mr. Ankur Goel, Research Scholar (Management), Mewar University, GZB. Contact No: 9917745990 Email Id: mrankurgoel@gmail.com. ABSTRACT Among all the innovations that have flooded the international financial markets, financial derivatives occupy the driver's seat. These specialized instruments facilitate the shuffling and redistribution of the risks that an investor faces. Thus aids in the process of diversifying ones portfolio. The volatility in the equity markets over the past years has resulted in greater use of equity derivatives. The volume of the exchange traded equity futures and options in most of the mature markets have seen a significant growth. It goes beyond that the local derivative in the emerging markets have witnessed widespread use of the derivative instrument for a variety of reasons. This continuous growth and development by the emerging market participants has resulted in capital inflows as well as helped the investors in risk protection through hedging. INTRODUCTION AND CONCEPT OF DERIVATIVES: Derivatives are financial contracts whose values are derived from the value of an underlying primary financial instrument, commodity or index, such as: interest rates, exchange rates, commodities, and equities. The International Monetary Fund defines derivatives as "financial...

Words: 2550 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Development of Derivative Market in India China and Malaysia

...sizable, expanding and fast growing. Asia specific derivative market has hold nearly 40 percent of world capitalization in 2015 and having annual volume of 9.7 Billion. Markets in countries like Japan, Korea, Malaysia, China, India and Korea are also sizable. Indian, China and Malaysia were second tier exchange in derivative market but growing rapidly. 2.0 Development of Derivative Market 2.1 Malaysia Malaysia start joining the derivative market trading community in October of 1980’s with the launched of crude palm oil futures at Kuala Lumpur Commodity Exchange (KLCE). KLCE was known as the first futures exchange in Malaysia and all of Southeast Asia, established in 1980. In December of 1995, Kuala Lumpur Options and Financial Future Exchange (KLOFFE) were officially licensed as a futures and options exchange, and trading on in its flagship stock index futures. In December 1998, KLCE and Malaysia Monetary Exchange (MME) were merged to establish Commodity and Monetary Exchange of Malaysian (COMMEX). Shortly after, in January 1999, KLOFFE became subsidiary of Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange (KLSE). In June 2001, KLOFFE merged with COMMEX and form Malaysian Derivative Exchange (MDEX). Later Bursa Malaysia Derivative Berhad has listed in 2005. 2.2 China In 1980’s the relevant department study abroad to prepare and actively preparing for China's futures market .The China Zhengzhou Grain Wholesale Market, was the first commodities futures market opened at China in 1990 October. Due...

Words: 1002 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Derivatives in India and China Market

...STUDIES | Indian and Chinese Derivative Markets | A Comparative Analysis | Submitted to: Dr. Kumar BijoyBy: Anney Banderwal - 75112Larika Azad- 75130Ayushi Sharma- 751142/18/2014 | Contents Acknowledgement 3 Introduction 4 History and Evolution 4 Medieval Europe 5 A Major Step Forward 6 The New World 7 The Computer Age 8 India 8 China 10 Comparative Study 12 Exchanges and Instruments 12 Regulatory Aspects 14 India 14 China Regulatory Framework 19 Conclusion 26 Bibliography 27 Acknowledgement We would like to take this opportunity to thank all those who have helped us in completing this project report. First of all we would like to thank our teacher Dr. Kumar Bijoy for guiding us throughout this project. Then we would like to thank our parents for their immense support. In the end we would like to thank GOD almighty for giving us strength to complete this project. Introduction A derivative is a financial contract which derives its value from the performance of another entity such as an asset, index, or interest rate, called the "underlying". Derivatives are one of the three main categories of financial instruments, the other two being equities (i.e. stocks) and debt (i.e. bonds and mortgages). Derivatives include a variety of financial contracts, including futures, forwards, swaps, options, and variations of these such as caps, floors, collars, and credit default swaps. Most derivatives are traded over-the-counter (off-exchange)...

Words: 8457 - Pages: 34

Premium Essay

Commodity Trading

... TRADING IN COMMODITIES SUBMITTED TO: SUBMITTED BY: MS.PALLAVI DAWRA DEEPAK JASLEEN NEHA TASHNEET INTRODUCTION Commodity trading in India is regulated by the Forward Markets Commission (FMC) headquartered at Mumbai, it is a regulatory authority which is overseen by the Ministry of Consumer Affairs and Public Distribution, Govt. of India. It is a statutory body set up in 1953 under the Forward Contracts (Regulation) Act, 1952. COMMODITY TRADINGCommodity markets are quite like equity markets. The commodity market also has two constituents i.e. spot market and derivative market. In case of a spot market, the commodities are bought and sold for immediate delivery. In case of a commodities derivative market, various financial instruments having commodities as underlying are traded on the exchanges. It has been seen that traditionally in India people have hedged their risks with Gold and Silver. | COMMODITY FUTURESCommodity future is a derivative instrument for the future delivery of a commodity on a fixed date at a particular price. The underlying in this case is a particular commodity. If an investor purchases an...

Words: 2241 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Management

...3.1: Basic Rules of Differentiation Rule 1: Derivative of a Constant The derivative of a constant function = is zero; that is, () = 0. Rule 2: The Power Rule: Let be any number. Then = Chapter 3: Differentiation Examples: If = , then its derivative is the function 2; that is, = 2. If = , then the derivative is 3 ; that is, = 3 . Q. What is the slope of the curve = at the point = −2? a) -32 c) 16 Rule 3: Constant-Multiple Rule Let be any constant. Then () = () b) -10 d) 80 Rule 4: Sum Rule + () = () + () Q. Differentiate = + Q. Differentiate = 2 A. 2 ⁄ =2 ⁄ =2 ⁄ = ⁄ A. = + = + = 3 + 2 Q. Differentiate = 3 + Q. Differentiate = a) 3 + 2 c) 5 a) ⁄ b) ⁄ d) ⁄ c) b) 3 + 2 d) 3 ⁄ Rule 5: General Power Rule () = () To summarize: Rule 3: Constant-Multiple Rule () = () Rule 4: Sum Rule + () = () + () Rule 5: General Power Rule () = () () () Q. Differentiate = + 3 A. +3 = 2 +3 +3 = (2 + 6)(3 ) = 6 + 18 Q. Differentiate = + 1 Q. Differentiate = 5 3 + A. Let’s  first  rewrite  the  formula  as   = 5 3 + 5 3 + ⁄ =5 =5 = 3 + 3 + a) 8 + 2 c) 2 + 6 ⁄ ⁄ b) 4 + 4 d) 4 + constant-multiple rule Q. Differentiate = + 2 ⁄ 9 + 1 general power rule a) 6 + 16 +...

Words: 6619 - Pages: 27

Premium Essay

Indian Financial

...Indian Capital Market Nidhi Bothra Payel Jain Vinod Kothari & Company What are Financial markets Financial market is a market where financial instruments are exchanged or traded and helps in determining the prices of the assets that are traded in and is also called the price discovery process. 1. Organizations that facilitate the trade in financial products. For e.g. Stock exchanges (NYSE, Nasdaq) facilitate the trade in stocks, bonds and warrants. 2. Coming together of buyer and sellers at a common platform to trade financial products is termed as financial markets, i.e. stocks and shares are traded between buyers and sellers in a number of ways including: the use of stock exchanges; directly between buyers and sellers etc. Financial markets may be classified on the basis of • • • • types of claims – debt and equity markets maturity – money market and capital market trade – spot market and delivery market deals in financial claims – primary market and secondary market Indian Financial Market consists of the following markets: • • • Capital Market/ Securities Market o Primary capital market o Secondary capital market Money Market Debt Market Primary capital market- A market where new securities are bought and sold for the first time Types of issues in Primary market • • • • • Initial public offer (IPO) (in case of an unlisted company), Follow-on public offer (FPO), Rights offer such that securities are offered to existing...

Words: 7747 - Pages: 31

Premium Essay

Foreign Exchange

...International Journal of Marketing, Financial Services & Management Research Vol.1 Issue 11, November 2012, ISSN 2277 3622 Online available at www.indianresearchjournals.com INDIAN CURRENCY FUTURES: AN ANALYTICAL STUDY OF ITS PERFORMANCE DR. DEVAJIT MAHANTA* * Vice President-Benzcom Consulting Pvt. Ltd. 3A-Oberon Appartement, 6-Lamb Road Ambari, Guwahati-781001, Assam, India ABSTRACT Since its inspection in 2008, currency derivative trade in India had experienced explosive growth, both in volumes and value over the years across all the four currencies contracts that were in operation in INRUSD, INRGBP, INREUR and INRJPY. However in terms of the open interest currency derivatives trade in MCX is more as compared to the NSE. By consider both stock and commodity exchanges for launching currency futures contracts government of India has done a commendable job which is expected to increase the number of quality players, introduce healthy competition and boost trading volumes of Indian currency futures. The global markets (mainly USA) become active only after Indian markets close at 5.00 pm and as a result there is an evident fear about the risks associated with overnight fluctuations in the currency pair. Therefore the functioning as well as the profitability in Indian currency futures is effected by the current performance of the international currency futures market. It is imperative that any evaluation, projection on Indian currency futures market should be undertaken keeping...

Words: 2651 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Currency Derivative

...International Journal of Marketing, Financial Services & Management Research Vol.1 Issue 11, November 2012, ISSN 2277 3622 Online available at www.indianresearchjournals.com INDIAN CURRENCY FUTURES: AN ANALYTICAL STUDY OF ITS PERFORMANCE DR. DEVAJIT MAHANTA* * Vice President-Benzcom Consulting Pvt. Ltd. 3A-Oberon Appartement, 6-Lamb Road Ambari, Guwahati-781001, Assam, India ABSTRACT Since its inspection in 2008, currency derivative trade in India had experienced explosive growth, both in volumes and value over the years across all the four currencies contracts that were in operation in INRUSD, INRGBP, INREUR and INRJPY. However in terms of the open interest currency derivatives trade in MCX is more as compared to the NSE. By consider both stock and commodity exchanges for launching currency futures contracts government of India has done a commendable job which is expected to increase the number of quality players, introduce healthy competition and boost trading volumes of Indian currency futures. The global markets (mainly USA) become active only after Indian markets close at 5.00 pm and as a result there is an evident fear about the risks associated with overnight fluctuations in the currency pair. Therefore the functioning as well as the profitability in Indian currency futures is effected by the current performance of the international currency futures market. It is imperative that any evaluation, projection on Indian currency futures market should be undertaken keeping...

Words: 2651 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Tips Case

...Case Write-up #2: Innovation at the Treasury: TIPS Federico Martinoli 1) TIPS are an inflation-indexed form of debt: they are 10 year treasury notes with semiannual coupon payments. Both the principal and the coupons are adjusted every semester by the percentage raise of the Consumer Price Index (CPI). Therefore if a CPI has a nominal value of 100 and pays 2% interest and the CPI raises by 5% the principal will become USD 105 and the coupon will be USD 2.1 (so the interest rate against the principal remains 2% but it becomes 2.1% of the original face value of the bond). To the contrary in case of deflation the TIPS would never fall below the face value. Different types of inflation indexed securities are sold by other governments like the UK, Brazil, Chile, Israel, Australia, etc.). This is not the only possible way to structure an inflation-indexed bond. A bond could be structured to only adjust its coupon and not the principal, or it could also be structured to adjust for deflation. TIPS are probably the best structure for small investors that are investing their savings for their retirement or for their kid’s college as they adjust both principal and coupon only upwards. 2) The price of TIPS is affected by the current yield of other forms of government securities and in general by the economic condition of the issuing country. In fact if the issuing country goes into a recession and the yields of the various treasuries rise also the TIPS yield will rise causing the TIPS bond...

Words: 814 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Derivative

...DERIVATIVES A derivative is a financial instrument - or more simply, an agreement between two people or two parties - that has a value determined by the price of something else (called the underlying). It is a financial contract with a value linked to the expected future price movements of the asset it is linked to - such as a share or a currency. There are many kinds of derivatives, with the most notable being swaps, futures, and options. However, since a derivative can be placed on any sort of security, the scope of all derivatives possible is nearly endless. Thus, the real definition of a derivative is an agreement between two parties that is contingent on a future outcome of the underlying. Some of the widely known underlying assets are: * Indexes (consumer price index (CPI), stock market index, weather conditions or inflation) * Bonds * Currencies * Interest rates * Exchange rates * Commodities * Stocks (equities) Categorization Derivatives are usually broadly categorized by the: * relationship between the underlying and the derivative (e.g., forward, option, swap) * type of underlying (e.g., equity derivatives, foreign exchange derivatives, interest rate derivatives, commodity derivatives or credit derivatives) * market in which they trade (e.g., exchange-traded or over-the-counter) * pay-off profile (Some derivatives have non-linear payoff diagrams due to embedded optionality) Another arbitrary distinction is between:...

Words: 1908 - Pages: 8