Free Essay

Food Appropriation Through Large Scale Land Acquisitions

In:

Submitted By bvbm
Words 5844
Pages 24
Rising Food Prices, Poverty, and the Doha Round
Sandra Polaski
Senior Associate and Director, Trade, Equity and Development Program MAY 2008

Summary
This paper examines the issues at stake in the Doha Round in light of rising food prices and their impact on global poverty. It first reviews the causes of high food prices, emphasizing those that are susceptible to action by governments. The author then presents recent evidence on how food prices affect the poor and concludes that, although many poor households will require urgent assistance, more are likely to gain from rising prices than lose. She argues that the Doha Round must allow developing countries adequate policy flexibility so that they can build up their own agricultural sectors, increase food supply in the medium and long term, and shield the poor from market failures that can affect their very survival. An agreement should: • • • Sharply restrict domestic and export subsidies provided to wealthy country farmers, which drive farmers in developing countries off the land or into poverty. In-kind food aid should also be restricted in favor of cash assistance. Allow developing countries to shield at least twenty percent of tariff lines from reductions as “special products” to foster greater domestic production and shield poor households until they become more productive or find other livelihoods. Create a robust “special safeguard mechanism” that would permit developing countries to address short term volatility in global food markets by raising tariffs in response to import surges or agricultural price drops.

Introduction
The rapid increase in prices of rice, wheat, corn and other food staples has sent a shock wave through poor households around the world, as well as through governments and international policy makers. While food prices are always volatile, recent increases are of a magnitude last seen in the 1970s.

There are multiple causes: rising demand in large developing countries that have experienced growth in household incomes; neglect of agriculture in many developing countries over recent decades, leading to reduced supply; increased costs to farmers due to high fuel and fertilizer prices; competition from biofuels for land use; supply disruptions caused by drought in major agricultural exporting countries; speculation and an asset bubble in commodity markets; and the decline of the dollar, the currency in which many commodities are priced on global markets. The impact of the price increases on poverty varies among countries and within countries. The effects on the poor depend on whether they are net sellers or net buyers of food, as well as whether they depend on the agricultural sector for wages or other sources of income. This paper identifies those causes of the price increases that would be susceptible to policy changes and discusses the poverty impacts, sometimes counterintuitive, that must be borne in mind. One area of policy that is directly at stake is trade policy. The Doha Round of negotiations at the World Trade Organization offers a particular challenge, because those trade talks appear to be reaching a crescendo just as food prices have spiked. This paper examines specific proposals in the Doha Round in light of its findings. Before turning to those issues, it must be noted that the rise in food prices has created a crisis for many poor households that demands an immediate policy response from the global community. The poor, often those displaced by civil strife, who already depend on aid agencies for their food supply must be protected from hunger caused by rising prices. The UN World Food Program estimates it will need over $700 million in additional resources this year simply to maintain current feeding levels. Rising prices will push many other poor households into deeper poverty and increase demands on food programs. The world must supply additional aid quickly. The initial response from wealthy countries has been promising, although translating commitments by heads of state into actual appropriations and delivery of aid remains to be accomplished. Pressure must be kept up. In many developing countries, governments will need to provide safety nets, such as cash vouchers or subsidized food, to help poor households afford adequate nutrition. Some countries will have the budgetary resources to fund such programs, but many low-income countries will need help from international donors. Beyond the immediate aid needed to prevent hunger and increased poverty, however, the complexity of the situation demands careful analysis if appropriate policy responses are to be found. Which combination of policies will be effective over the medium and long term is the crucial question.

2

Causes of the Current Increase in Food Prices
The starting point for a serious discussion of current food price increases must be the historical pattern of price changes. Two consistent patterns emerge. First is that food prices are always volatile, because both food supply and food demand respond slowly to changes in price. As a result, any disruption in the match of supply and demand will produce exaggerated changes in price. Figure 1 illustrates the volatility of prices for one crop, rice, over the last 30 years, adjusted for inflation. Figure 1. The Real Price of Rice 1970–2008
450 Price Index (1970 = 100) 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50
91 94 97 00 03 20 76 79 82 85 70 73 88 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 20 20 06

Source: UN Food and Agriculture Organization, staff estimates The second historical pattern is that the price of food has shown a downward trend over the past century, relative to prices of manufactured goods. Figure 2 presents a generally accepted food price index for the period 1900–1987 developed by World Bank economists, updated with calculations by IMF staff for the period 1957–2006.1 While food prices have been rising for the last several years, they are still well below levels that prevailed for most of the last century. Is there reason to think that the current price spikes are harbingers of a fundamental shift in trends? On the one hand, rising food demand from growing developing countries, a significant factor in current increases, is likely to persist and this is indeed a positive development, as it indicates that more people can afford adequate nutrition. On the other hand, higher prices will elicit increased production—this can already be observed in this season’s planting data. However other contemporary factors have complicated the relationship between supply and demand. The competition of biofuels for crops and land use has had a modest impact on food prices to date, but the effects will grow unless the United States and 3

European Union revisit policies that subsidize biofuels and require their use in the two huge markets. While encouraging efficient biofuels could be an appropriate policy choice to diversify energy supply and relieve climate change pressures, some current sources of biofuels, particularly corn, actually add to global warming in addition to competing for crops that are important to food supplies. These policies should be reexamined as a high priority, in light of the increasing evidence of their negative effects. Figure 2. Long Term Trends in Real Food Prices
Grilli and Yang Index 175 150 Price Index (1957 = 100) 125 100 75 50 25
14 70 07 91 77 35 56 21 00 28 42 49 63 19 84 98 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 20 05

IMF Index

Source: IMF World Economic Outlook September 2006.

A large explanatory factor in the current mismatch between supply and demand for food can be found in the decades-long underinvestment in agriculture in many developing countries. As a result, some countries that were once self-sufficient in food have lost that capacity and others have had to import growing shares of their food supply. In a recent report on agriculture and development, the World Bank argues that this was the result of five factors: falling international commodity prices that made agricultural investment less profitable; increased competition for development aid from social sectors such as health and education; emergency responses to crises; opposition from farmers in some aid donor countries to support for agriculture in their export markets; and opposition from environmental groups. 2 The World Bank’s own support for agriculture dropped even more precipitously than that of other donors, from thirty-three percent of its development aid in 1981 to only eight percent in 2001.3 In many cases IMF structural adjustment programs and the Bank’s lending also restricted developing country governments from spending their own resources on agricultural development and support to poor farmers. These adverse policies were undertaken despite longstanding evidence that economic growth in the agricultural sector is more 4

effective in raising incomes of extremely poor people than growth originating in other sectors.4 The policy implications are clear: the World Bank and other donors should dramatically increase investment in developing country agriculture and abandon the harmful conditionalities that prevent governments from supporting their agricultural sectors in appropriate ways. Two other factors are worth noting because of their significance in recent price rises and because they are susceptible to policy responses. First is the role of the dollar. Most commodities are priced in dollars on global markets and the sharp decline of the dollar against many other currencies has exaggerated the rise in prices. For example, Figure 3 shows recent food price changes in dollars and euros. A second factor is the huge flow of funds into financial markets linked to commodity futures, including those for agricultural commodities. Various estimates put the flow at between $100 billion and $300 billion over the past few years, as hedge funds, large institutional investors and others have fled the real estate market and looked for high returns elsewhere. This has amplified both increases and volatility in food prices. While there has always been speculation in commodities markets, the size of the current investment surge is of a different order of magnitude and has disrupted the functioning of these markets for farmers who use them to hedge against weather and other risks. It must be anticipated that, as with all asset bubbles, when prices turn downward, money leaving these markets will accelerate the fall in agricultural prices, perhaps precipitously. Recent crises in global financial markets and housing markets in the United States and elsewhere are reminders that market failure is not uncommon and that financial markets amplify underlying failures.

Figure 3: Food Price Index Measured in U.S. Dollars and Euros
Food Price Index Measured in U.S. Dollars Food Price Index Measured in Euros Price Index (Jan 2007 = 100) 160 140 120 100 80 Jan-07 Jan-08 Apr-08

Sources: IMF Food Price Index; Euro/dollar exchange rates

5

Impact of Food Prices on Poverty
Rising food prices can either reduce or increase poverty, depending on how poor households earn their income and how they spend it. For example, households that produce and sell food crops will benefit from an increase in prices, unless they buy more food than they sell. In addition to direct selling and buying of food, the poverty impact will also depend on how price changes are transmitted through labor markets. For example, if rising prices lead farmers to expand production and hire more farm labor, landless farm workers may benefit. Unskilled workers in urban areas may also be affected. If food prices go down, laborers from the countryside may search for work in nearby towns and cities, contributing to the supply of labor and perhaps lowering wages. Rising prices might improve local economies in rural areas in ways that benefit non-farming households, such as those of small-scale traders and service providers, although their rising costs for food might outweigh the benefits. The factors determining the impact on poverty are complex and the results are likely to vary among countries and for different crops. Because about seventy-five percent of the world’s poor live in rural areas where agriculture is the main economic activity, one might assume that rising food prices would tend to alleviate poverty on average and at the global level. Surprisingly, the conventional view has been the opposite in recent decades. This view held that because more poor households were net food buyers than were net food sellers, lower food prices would alleviate poverty. There were relatively few studies that used actual data on sources of household incomes as well as household food expenditures to explore this question. Now, however, a number of studies using detailed household data have called that generalization into question. A forthcoming study by two World Bank researchers finds that in a sample of nine low income countries, the net food sellers were poorer than net food buyers.5 Rising food prices would tend to transfer income from richer to poorer households, while lower prices do the opposite. Among poor net food buying households, almost half spent less than ten percent of their income on food, meaning that rising prices would have only small impacts on expenditure and might be outweighed by changes in income. The study then explores the links between agricultural prices and the sources of income for net food buying rural households, finding that about half of their income depends on agriculture, whether directly through farming or pastoral activities or through wage and business income that is linked to agricultural incomes. Two other seminal studies, one for Bangladesh and one for Mexico, developed theoretical models of the role of labor markets, land markets, and spillover effects of agricultural prices in rural economies and tested them with household survey data.6 They demonstrate that secondary effects may outweigh the direct effects of food prices. Findings from all of these studies indicate that a simple focus on net consumption versus net production is likely to be misleading. They also provide important analytical foundations for further work to better understand the relationship of food prices to poverty. 6

Overall, fifty-four percent of the world’s poor live in India and China and thus the response of poverty in these two countries is an important component in assessing how changes in food prices will affect global poverty. A recent study by the Carnegie Endowment probed the effect of food price changes in India, the country with the largest number of poor in the world, where over eighty percent of the population live on less than $2 per day. 7 Using a general equilibrium model to simulate the impact of different prices, we found that an increase in the price of rice would benefit most poor households (Figure 4). The detailed household data we used included information on vulnerable social groups (defined in the Indian constitution as “scheduled tribes,” “scheduled castes,” and “other backward classes”). The poorest households and the most disadvantaged groups saw the largest gains (up to six percent increase in income from a fifty percent increase in the price of rice). Only the richest ten percent of rural households would lose from a price increase. Figure 4. Impact of an Increase in the World Price of Rice on Indian Households
(% change in real income relative to baseline nominal income to households)

Scheduled Tribes

Scheduled Castes Rural

Other Backward Classes

Others

Scheduled Tribes

Scheduled Castes

Other Backward Classes

Others

Urban

We found that labor markets played a largely positive role in transmitting price effects. Income increased for rural workers at all education levels and for both men and women; the largest gainers were illiterate workers and disadvantaged groups. The impact on urban households was more varied, with some poor households gaining slightly and others losing slightly. Illiterate urban workers from all disadvantaged groups would see their incomes rise, while the results for other urban workers showed a mix of small gains and small losses with no consistent pattern. Declines in the world price of rice would have negative effects on all major components of the Indian economy, including private consumption, government spending, investment, exports, imports, and total domestic production (Table 1). Seventy-eight percent of households would experience 7

real income losses and the distributional impact would be regressive. Real income would fall for all rural households except the richest ten percent, with the poorest households and disadvantaged groups in rural areas losing the most (Figure 5). Most urban households would feel little impact from the price declines. The lowest income brackets of disadvantaged groups experience small income losses. Table 1. Impact of a Change in the World Price of Rice on India's Economy (% change from baseline)
Macroeconomic indicator Private consumption Government consumption Investment consumption Absorption Import demand Export supply Total domestic production World price of rice decreases by 25 percent -0.16 -0.09 -0.19 -0.16 -0.88 -0.64 -0.12 World price of rice decreases by 50 percent -0.24 -0.12 -0.28 -0.24 -1.28 -1.24 -0.17 World price of rice increases by 25 percent 0.30 0.17 0.39 0.31 1.82 0.60 0.23 World price of rice increases by 50 percent 0.84 0.52 1.20 0.89 5.62 1.08 0.70

The drop in rice prices would reduce demand for unskilled labor in rice production sharply, by almost twelve percent in the case of a fifty percent decline, and reduce overall demand for labor in the agricultural sector. Displaced rural laborers would spill over into urban unskilled labor markets, either driving down wages or increasing unemployment. Our study demonstrates that the inclusion of linkages between rural and urban labor markets is necessary to understand the impact of agricultural prices on the poor. Figure 5. Impact of a Decrease in the World Price of Rice on Indian Households
(% change in real income relative to baseline nominal income to households)

Scheduled Tribes

Scheduled Castes Rural

Other Backward Classes

Others

Scheduled Tribes

Scheduled Castes

Other Backward Classes

Others

Urban

8

We conducted a similar exercise for increases and decreases in wheat prices. The results showed similar patterns but with more muted effects. The overall effect of a decline in wheat prices could be to increase poverty, as 92 million rural households in the bottom six deciles of income would experience some real income loss, while only 32 million urban households in the same deciles would experience income gains. As noted, India is home to the largest number of poor people in the world. The second largest concentration of the poor is in China. Several studies using general equilibrium models have shown that rising world prices for grains would reduce poverty in China.8 Higher prices are offset by higher earnings for labor and land, leading to a decline in poverty for all household groups with significant poverty, including urban households.9 Most historical studies conclude that the large reduction in poverty in China since 1978 was based primarily on better incomes in rural areas, attributable mainly to higher prices for food. Two other recent studies looked at groups of developing countries that did not include China and India. One study found that higher food prices would reduce extreme poverty in nine of fifteen countries studied.10 Another looked at nine countries and found that rising food prices would increase poverty in seven.11 It is evident that patterns of poverty, income, and expenditure differ among developing countries and so the impact of food price increases will differ. Some countries will undoubtedly suffer increases in poverty when prices rise, while others will see poverty decline. The important conclusion that emerges is that it would be incorrect to generalize from the experience of particular countries or simple net consumer/net producer ratios to judge the effects of food price increases on poverty. The wide variation in impacts across countries, for different crops, and for different types of poor households demonstrates the need for varied policy responses and importance of avoiding misdiagnosis or one-size-fits-all policy prescriptions. We return to this topic in the section of the paper dealing with relevant issues in the Doha negotiations.

How Will the Doha Round Affect Food Prices?
It is generally acknowledged by experts that a Doha settlement would have no short-term impact on food prices. The tariff changes and other rules of a final deal will not begin to take effect until after the agreement is concluded, ratified by member states, and comes into force, a process that will take several years. Countries will then begin to phase in agreed changes over a number of years. The prior Uruguay Round, for example, allowed countries ten years to implement commitments. The trade negotiations, however, are not aimed at the short term. The rules and tariffs negotiated will prevail for the foreseeable future, until changed by some yet unscheduled future round of global trade talks. As a result, the Doha Round must be assessed for its medium and long term implications. 9

During the six years since the launch of the Doha Round, numerous general equilibrium studies have been undertaken to simulate its potential impacts. All studies have found that a Doha package that includes reductions in domestic agricultural subsidies, export subsidies, and tariffs will raise food prices modestly on global markets. These studies have also reached the common conclusion that most developing countries will see some benefits from the Round, although net food importing countries including Bangladesh and many sub-Saharan African countries are likely to be net losers because of the increased cost of food. Public discourse on the link between rising food prices and the Doha Round has sometimes been based on a mistaken belief that a conclusion to the negotiations is needed to lower prices by requiring countries to cut tariffs. However all countries currently have the right to lower the tariffs they actually apply—including to zero—at any time. WTO membership only obligates countries not to raise tariffs beyond levels agreed to in previous rounds of negotiations (these are called “bound” rates). In practice, many developing countries have already cut tariffs in the context of rising food prices to bring immediate relief to their consumers, including the poor. There is a large gap between bound and applied tariff rates, particularly in agriculture, and it is more common for developing countries to maintain such gaps. A major reason they have sought to maintain higher bound rates while sometimes applying low tariffs in practice is their need to deal with the volatility of agricultural prices, discussed above. When global food prices are high, as now, governments have the ability to lower tariffs. When global food prices fall (as they have and will again), governments can raise tariffs back up to the bound level to shield their farmers from sharp drops in income. This flexibility is particularly desirable going forward, when two factors may increase price volatility. First, scientists predict more extreme and variable weather as a result of climate change, which could lead to more frequent supply shortfalls. The other factor is the increasing role played by futures markets for agricultural commodities, discussed above. Like other financial markets, they are driven as much or more by speculation, expectations, and herd behavior than by underlying fundamentals and so tend to be much more volatile than actual supply and demand.

Optimizing Decisions in the Doha Round to Reduce Poverty and Increase Food Security
In the long term, reducing poverty and increasing food security will require many developing countries to expand agricultural production and improve domestic agricultural markets. There are a number of issues still under negotiation in the Doha Round that will affect the ability of governments to achieve these goals and manage food price changes in the future.

10

Domestic Subsidies, Export Subsidies, and Food Aid The domestic and export subsidies provided by the United States, the European Union, and some other wealthy countries to their farmers have the effect of inducing greater supply than market prices would warrant and allowing excess production to be sold on world markets at prices below production costs. This has reduced global food prices over recent decades, which was seen as positive by some net food importing countries. However it has hurt farmers in developing countries who cannot compete with subsidized exports in global markets. For subsistence and small scale farmers, it has displaced or lowered prices for their output in their domestic markets, thereby driving them off the land or into poverty. A similar effect is caused by in-kind food aid, which is the main form of food assistance provided by the United States. While most other wealthy countries have shifted to providing food aid by purchasing from farmers in countries targeted for assistance or in neighboring countries, the United States still does so by shipping its excess domestic supplies to destination countries, displacing production or depressing prices there. Agricultural subsidies and in-kind food aid by wealthy countries have discouraged production and investment in developing country agriculture. The resulting shortfall has emerged starkly as global food demand has risen. Thus, while reducing these agricultural subsidies and constraining in-kind food aid will increase prices modestly in the short run, it is a necessary correction to global agricultural market distortions and an essential part of the Doha deal if developing countries are to build up their own agricultural sectors and increase food supply in the medium and long term. Special Products Earlier in the Doha Round a framework agreement was reached to allow developing countries to shield some agricultural products, designated special products, from tariff reductions in order to address the livelihood security, food security, and rural development concerns that have been discussed above. Negotiations continue on how extensive these exceptions will be. A large group of developing countries known as the G33 has proposed that twenty percent of tariff lines should be subjected to lesser or no tariff cuts based on these considerations. 12 The United States and some other countries have sought to sharply limit the number of eligible tariff lines and to require other constraints in the designation of special products. The outcome will determine how much flexibility developing country governments will have to provide some price continuity as a long term incentive to their farmers to increase production. It will also influence the degree to which they will be able to shield poor farmers and rural communities from high levels of risk or periods of depressed prices that they are ill-prepared to absorb.

11

While the G33 has been outspoken throughout the negotiations about the need for this policy flexibility, the recent price volatility and supply shortfalls on global food markets have convinced some other developing countries that they need to consider ways to achieve greater domestic production in order to improve food security and reduce vulnerability to global markets. Many African countries in particular have the land and labor endowments needed for increased food production if they invest in irrigation and other rural infrastructure and can induce farmers to invest and increase production. Even if they are able to mobilize resources for public investments, greater effort by farmers and more private investment will not be forthcoming unless governments retain the tariff flexibility to shield farmers, particularly small and vulnerable ones, from the worst of global market volatility and negative price shocks. A robust outcome on special products would be needed. As already discussed, the impact of food prices on poverty and income distribution varies widely among countries and for different agricultural crops within countries. As a result, the decisions on how to select special products must be left to developing country governments themselves. Efforts in the negotiations to severely limit the number of special products or to impose restrictions on their selection would undermine the ability of developing country governments to balance the needs of rural and urban poor while addressing food supply and longer term rural development. Decisions on such fundamental issues must be left to governments that are accountable to their populations, not to negotiators seeking to maximize profits for their own commercial farmers or to dispute settlement panels that have no such accountability. Special Safeguard Mechanism Developing countries also seek a special safeguard mechanism that would permit them to raise tariffs in response to agricultural price drops or import surges. While the special products exceptions discussed above would provide some policy space for developing countries to address medium term food security and livelihood concerns and long term rural development strategies, a safeguard mechanism would still be needed to address short term volatility in food markets. As noted, food prices have always been volatile and volatility is likely to increase due to climate change and increased use of commodities as investments and hedges. Small producers in developing countries are in no position to bear the risk of sharp price and supply swings. The special safeguard mechanism must be easy to use, allow developing countries to respond swiftly to market disruptions, and be available for relatively small disruptions. In the simulations we performed of the impact of changing rice prices in India, a twenty-five percent decrease in rice prices imposes losses on poor households almost as large as a fifty percent decrease ( Figure 5). A current proposal that would require import prices to fall by as much as thirty percent compared to the average price for the previous three years (the “trigger price”) before the safeguard mechanism could be employed would vitiate this important tool. Another current proposal would limit a 12

responding tariff increase to one-half of the difference between the lower import price and the trigger price. The practical effect would be to require that half of global market disruptions be absorbed by poor farmers in affected countries. The proposal should be abandoned. Consideration must also be given to the situation of developing countries with low bound tariffs, which might need to raise them well above current bound levels to have an effect on import surges and negative price shocks.

Conclusion
The policy tools needed to address the current food crisis cover a broad range. They include immediate assistance for the poor and hungry and dramatically increased investment in developing country agriculture by the international financial institutions, wealthy country development agencies, and developing country governments. Financial regulators should turn their attention to financial markets in agricultural commodities, which show signs of the speculation, mania, and overshooting that have resulted in ongoing crises in global finance and some housing markets. As painful and destructive as those crises have been, they pale by comparison with the threat of serious market failure in the case of food. Trade policy also has a role to play. Many developing countries aspire to link their agricultural producers to larger regional and global markets as they gain the capacity to compete against more efficient producers under conditions of volatility. However, trade liberalization that removes flexibility from the hands of developing country governments prematurely or leads them to rely on global food markets and not invest in their own agricultural sectors has proven to be shortsighted. In the case of the Doha Round, a quick conclusion would not influence the current spike in food prices. Instead, an agreement should be carefully constructed to ensure that in the future, developing countries will retain the policy flexibility necessary to develop and provide appropriate incentives to their domestic agricultural sectors, to increase food security, and to shield the poor from market failures that can affect their very survival.

13

Notes
E. R. Grilli and M. C. Yang, “Primary commodity prices, manufactured goods prices and the terms of trade of developing countries: what the long run shows,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 2, No. 1, 1988; International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook September 2006 (Washington, D.C. International Monetary Fund). Prices are deflated by the Manufactures Unit Value (MUV) index. Due to definitional changes, the Grilli and Yang index is not precisely comparable to the IMF index. 2 World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, October 2007) available at: http://econ.worldbank.org. 3 Independent Evaluation Group of the World Bank, “World Bank Assistance to Agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa” (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2007). 4 Discussed in World Development Report 2008, op.cit. 5 M. Ataman Aksoy and Aylin Isik-Dikmelik, “Are Low Food Prices Pro-Poor? Net Food Buyers and Sellers in Low Income Countries,” (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, forthcoming). The countries covered in the study are Bangladesh, Bolivia, Cambodia, Ethiopia, Madagascar, Nicaragua, Peru, Vietnam, and Zambia. 6 Martin Ravallion, “Rural Welfare Effects of Food Price Changes under Induced Wage Responses: Theory and Evidence for Bangladesh,” Oxford Economic Papers 42 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990); George A. Dyer, Steve Boucher, and J. Edward Taylor, “Subsistence Response to Market Shocks,” Working Paper 05-004, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics (Davis: University of California, 2005). 7 Sandra Polaski, A. Ganesh-Kumar, Scott McDonald, Manoj Panda, and Sherman Robinson, India’s Trade Policy Choices: Managing Diverse Challenges (Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 2008) available at: www.carnegieendowment.org/trade. 8 Recent examples include Fan Zhai and Thomas Hertel, “Economic and Poverty Impacts of Price Distortions in China,” prepared for the 2008 Global Trade Analysis Project, April 2008, available at: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/res_display.asp?RecordID=2706; and “Food Prices and Inflation in Developing Asia: Is Poverty Reduction Coming to an End?,” (Manila: Asian Development Bank, April 2008) available at: http://www.adb.org/Documents/reports/food-prices-inflation/default.asp. 9 Fan Zhai and Thomas Hertel, op.cit. 10 Thomas W. Hertel, Roman Keeney, Maros Ivanic, and L. Alan Winters, “Distributional Effects of WTO Agricultural Reforms in Rich and Poor Countries,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4060 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, November 2006) available at: http://econ.worldbank.org. 11 Maros Ivanic and Will Martin, “Implications of Higher Global Food Prices for Poverty in Low-Income Countries,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4594 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, April 2008) available at http://econ.worldbank.org. 12 This position is proposed by a coalition of developing countries known as the G33, which has grown to include the following 46 countries: Antigua and Barbuda, Barbados, Belize, Benin, Bolivia, Botswana, China, Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Cuba, Dominica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Grenada, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, India, Indonesia, Jamaica, Kenya, Rep. Korea, Madagascar, Mauritius, Mongolia, Mozambique, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Peru, Philippines, St Kitts and Nevis, St Lucia, St Vincent and the Grenadines, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Suriname, Tanzania, Trinidad and Tobago, Turkey, Uganda, Venezuela, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.

14

Sandra Polaski is director of the Trade, Equity, and Development Program at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Her work focuses on trade, development, and employment policies in the context of globalization. Until April 2002, Polaski served as the U.S. Secretary of State’s Special Representative for International Labor Affairs. Her most recent publication is: India’s Trade Policy Choices: Managing Diverse Challenges, 2008.

© 2008 CARNEGIE ENDOWMENT FOR INTERNATIONAL PEACE The Carnegie Endowment for International Peace is a private, nonprofit organization dedicated to advancing cooperation between nations and promoting active international engagement by the United States. Founded in 1910, Carnegie is nonpartisan and dedicated to achieving practical results.

15

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Land Grabbing

...This article was downloaded by: [Tsinghua University] On: 19 March 2014, At: 22:22 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK The Journal of Peasant Studies Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/fjps20 Land grabbing in Latin America and the Caribbean Saturnino M. Borras Jr. , Jennifer C. Franco , Sergio Gómez , Cristóbal Kay & Max Spoor Published online: 28 May 2012. To cite this article: Saturnino M. Borras Jr. , Jennifer C. Franco , Sergio Gómez , Cristóbal Kay & Max Spoor (2012) Land grabbing in Latin America and the Caribbean, The Journal of Peasant Studies, 39:3-4, 845-872, DOI: 10.1080/03066150.2012.679931 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03066150.2012.679931 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently...

Words: 15852 - Pages: 64

Premium Essay

Land Acquisition in India

...LAND ACQUISITION IN INDIA A REPORT SUBMITTED FOR THE COURSE “THE INDIAN ECONOMY” SUBMITTED BY: BISWAPRIYA SAHA DEEPSHIKHA GOVLI HIMANI KABRA ITISHREE DASH MRITYUNJAY BASAK PGP/17/076 PGP/17/077 PGP/17/080 PGP/17/083 PGP/17/094 Page 2 of 13 Table of Content ACKNOWLEDGEMENT ............................................................................................................................ 3 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY .......................................................................................................................... 4 INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................................................ 5 BENEFITS OF LAND ACQUISITION ....................................................................................................... 6 NEGATIVE IMPACT ON FARMERS ........................................................................................................ 6 NEGATIVE IMPACT ON TRIBALS .......................................................................................................... 6 NEGATIVE IMPACT ON SOCIETY.......................................................................................................... 6 NEGATIVE IMPACT ON ENVIRONMENT ............................................................................................. 6 CRITICISM OF LAND ACQUISITION POLICY ...................................................................................... 7 LAND...

Words: 3341 - Pages: 14

Free Essay

Project

...…………………………………………………………………………… 38 o Livestock …………………………………………………………………………… 49 o Arts, Culture & Tourism …………………………………………………………………………… 40 o Commerce & Industry …………………………………………………………………………… 41 o Education …………………………………………………………………………… 42 – 43 o Energy (Rural Electrification) ………………………………………………………………………….. 44 – 46 o Water Resources ………………………………………………………………………….. 47 – 59 o Rural Water & Sanitation ………………………………………………………………………….. 50 – 52 o Drainage & Sewage/Environmental Protection …………………………………………………… 53 o Forestry ………………………………………………………………………….. 54 o Health ………………………………………………………………………….. 55 – 56 o Information & Orientation ………………………………………………………………………….. 57 o Community Development ………………………………………………………………………….. 58 o Lands, Surveys & Housing ………………………………………………………………………….. 59 o Administrative Building ………………………………………………………………………….. 60 – 61 o Transport ………………………………………………………………………….. 62 o Works (Roads) ………………………………………………………………………….. 63 – 68 o Rapid Response Agency ………………………………………………………………….. 69 o Women Affairs & Social Development ………………………………………………………………… 70 o Youth & Sports ………………………………………………………………………….. 71 o Oil Producing...

Words: 32812 - Pages: 132

Premium Essay

Compiler Design

...COMPENDIUM Budget Terms and Concepts Donald M. Patimo, MPM In partial fulfillment of the requirements in Budget Preparation and Fiscal Management October 18, 2008 Ability to pay This refers to the borrower’s ability to make interest and principal payments on debts. Accelerated depreciation This refers to any depreciation method that produces larger deductions for depreciation in the early years of an asset’s life. Account This refers to a record of a business transaction. This refers to a written or unwritten contract to purchase and take delivery with payment to be made later as arranged. Account balance This refers to the difference between the debit and the credit sides of an account. Accounting period This refers to a time interval at the end of which an analysis is made of the information contained in the bookkeeping records. Also, the period covered by the profit and loss statement. Accounting price A term often used synonymously with shadow price. The term “accounting” indicates that the price is not market price. Accounting prices reflect, for example, the economic value of inputs and outputs as opposed to their financial or market value. Accounts payable Money owed to an individual or business for goods or services that have been received but not yet paid for. Accounting rate of return The ratio of profit before interest and taxation to the percentage of capital employed at the end...

Words: 31511 - Pages: 127

Premium Essay

Housing in Nigeria

...CHAPTER ONE Introduction There are three basic needs of man in life, namely food, clothing and shelter. From the beginning, man has worked very hard to provide himself with shelter which protects him from adverse weather and hard climatic conditions. Of all the facets of human environment, a few influences a man’s life more than that of a house in which he seeks shelter, security, comfort and dignity. It is indeed where he begins and ends his days. Proper housing is an important need for every human being. Man’s proper utilization of his resources and economic wellbeing greatly depends on the type of accommodation he has been provided with. “a decently housed citizen is a more productive individual, a good housing scheme complimented by high environmental standard equates with less expense on public health, and less adverse social effect produces a higher gross national income figure for a country” . This is why it is generally accepted that good housing is a social index of a good government especially in developing countries like Nigeria should especially accept the provision of housing as a major social responsibility. Housing is a set of durable assets, which accounts for a high proportion of a country’s wealth and on which households spend a substantial part of their income. It is for these reasons that housing has become a regular feature in economic, social and political debates often with highly charged emotional contents(Agbola, 1998). All...

Words: 3860 - Pages: 16

Premium Essay

Administrative Code

...officers and employees as it embodies changes in administrative structures and procedures designed to serve the people; NOW, THEREFORE, I, CORAZON C. AQUINO, President of the Philippines, by the powers vested in me by the Constitution, do hereby promulgate the Administrative Code of 1987, as follows: INTRODUCTORY PROVISIONS SECTION 1. Title. — This “Administrative Code of 1987.” Act shall be known as the SECTION 2. General Terms Defined. — Unless the specific words of the text, or the context as a whole, or a particular statute, shall require a different meaning: (1) Government of the Republic of the Philippines refers to the corporate governmental entity through which the functions of government are exercised throughout the Philippines, including, save as the contrary appears from the context, the various arms through which political authority is made effective in the Philippines, whether pertaining to the autonomous regions, the provincial, city, municipal or barangay subdivisions or other forms of local government. (2) National Government refers to the entire machinery of...

Words: 111254 - Pages: 446

Free Essay

Managing the Internationalization Process

...Managing the internationalization process Learning outcomes After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ➤ Understand the motives for internationalization. ➤ Apply the theories underpinning the internationalization process. ➤ Explain the Psychic Distance and Born Global concepts. 5 ➤ Advise a multinational firm on choosing an appropriate entry mode for internationalization. ➤ Advise a multinational firm on de-internationalization. 148 Global strategic development Opening case study Internationalization of a French retailer—Carrefour In 1960, Carrefour opened its first supermarket in France. In 1963, Carrefour invented a new store concept—the hypermarket. The hypermarket concept was novel, and revolutionized the way French people did their shopping. It moved daily shopping from small stores to enormous stores where customers find everything they want under one roof, in addition to selfservice, discount price, and free parking space. The first Carrefour hypermarket store was established at the intersection of five roads—hence the name, Carrefour, which means ‘crossroads’. Carrefour is the leading retailer in Europe and the second largest worldwide, with Exhibit A International development of Carrefour Year Country and mode of entry No. of stores (2009) 1969 1973 1975 1982 1989 1991 1993 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1997 1998 1998 2000 Belgium—Carrefour’s first hypermarket outside France Spain Brazil—Carrefour’s first hypermarket in the Americas Argentina Taiwan—Carrefour’s...

Words: 14656 - Pages: 59

Premium Essay

Phi93246

...SECTION 1. Title. — This Act shall be known and cited as the "Local Government Code of 1991". SECTION 2. Declaration of Policy. — (a) It is hereby declared the policy of the State that the territorial and political subdivisions of the State shall enjoy genuine and meaningful local autonomy to enable them to attain their fullest development as self-reliant communities and make them more effective partners in the attainment of national goals. Toward this end, the State shall provide for a more responsive and accountable local government structure instituted through a system of decentralization whereby local government units shall be given more powers, authority, responsibilities, and resources. The process of decentralization shall proceed from the national government to the local government units. (b) It is also the policy of the State to ensure the accountability of local government units through the institution of effective mechanisms of recall, initiative and referendum. (c) It is likewise the policy of the State to require all national agencies and offices to conduct periodic consultations with appropriate local government units, nongovernmental and people's organizations, and other concerned sectors of the community before any project or program is implemented in their respective jurisdictions. SECTION 3. Operative Principles of Decentralization. — The formulation and implementation of policies and measures on local autonomy shall be guided...

Words: 95323 - Pages: 382

Free Essay

Budget

...OVERVIEW UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF DEFENSE FISCAL YEAR 2014 BUDGET REQUEST APRIL 2013 OFFICE OF THE UNDER SECRETARY OF DEFENSE (COMPTROLLER) / CHIEF FINANCIAL OFFICER Preface The Overview Book has been published as part of the President’s Annual Defense Budget for the past few years. This continues for FY 2014, but with modifications as proposed by congressional staff. From FY 1969 to FY 2005 OSD published the “Annual Defense Report” (ADR) to meet 10 USC Section 113 requirements. Starting with the President’s FY 2006 Budget, this report was no longer produced. Subsequently, the Overview began to fill this role. This year to ensure compliance with Section 113, new chapters are added to include reports from each Military Department on their respective funding, military mission accomplishments, core functions, and force structure. Key initiatives incorporated in the FY 2014 Defense budget. Our budget is formulated based on aligning program priorities and resources based on the President’s strategic guidance. This year’s budget involves key themes to: achieve a deeper program alignment of our future force structure with resource availability; maintain a mission ready force; continue to emphasize efficiencies by being even better stewards of taxpayer dollars; and continue to take care of our people and their families. Implementing Defense Strategic Guidance. The FY 2014 budget request continues the force structure reductions made in the FY 2013 budget request. Following...

Words: 74297 - Pages: 298

Premium Essay

Climate Change

...This article was downloaded by: [Texas A&M University-Commerce] On: 05 January 2015, At: 16:08 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Geopolitics Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/fgeo20 Rethinking Climate Change, Conflict and Security Jan Selby & Clemens Hoffmann a a b Department of International Relations, University of Sussex, Brighton, UK b Department of International Relations, Bilkent University, Ankara, Turkey Published online: 30 Oct 2014. Click for updates To cite this article: Jan Selby & Clemens Hoffmann (2014) Rethinking Climate Change, Conflict and Security, Geopolitics, 19:4, 747-756, DOI: 10.1080/14650045.2014.964866 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14650045.2014.964866 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon...

Words: 5013 - Pages: 21

Premium Essay

Supermarkets

...packets, fake smiles from bored checkout assistants isn't there a better way to get our food? Supermarkets wield immense power over the way we grow, buy and eat our food. They are shaping our environment, our health and the way we interact socially. These changes have gone unchallenged because consumers have been sucked into superstore lifestyles, persuaded that the opportunity to select from six different brands of cut-price oven chips at three in the morning represents choice and value. What’s Wrong With SUPERMARKETS But the tide may be turning. Unease at the true cost of supermarket food is spreading among consumers, who are beginning to join forces with the farmers and workers who have always known that supermarket 'choice' is a bad deal. This booklet aims to help campaigners get to grips with the reality of supermarket domination and argues why we must start looking for alternatives. Researched and written by Lucy Michaels and the Agriculture Project at Corporate Watch What’s wrong with Supermarkets www.corporatewatch.org.uk What's Wrong with Supermarkets? Overview: Supermarkets sweep up 2 3 10 11 The supermarkets we know today started in Britain with the Cooperative Movement in the 19th century. This was a group of independent local retailers controlled by its consumer members, who sold un-adulterated foods at prices working people could afford. It was in post-war Britain that the foundations...

Words: 14175 - Pages: 57

Premium Essay

Game Zone

...Pre-Feasibility Study GAMING ZONE Small and Medium Enterprise Development Authority Government of Pakistan www.smeda.org.pk HEAD OFFICE 6th Floor, LDA Plaza, Egerton Road, Lahore. Tel: (042) 111-111-456, Fax: (042) , 6304926, 6304927 Helpdesk@smeda.org.pk REGIONAL PUNJAB OFFICE 8th Floor, LDA Plaza, Egerton Road, Lahore. Tel: (042) 111-111-456 Fax: (042) 6304926, 6304927 helpdesk@smeda.org.pk REGIONAL SINDH OFFICE 5TH Floor, Bahria Complex II, M.T. Khan Road, Karachi. Tel: (021) 111-111-456 Fax: (021) 5610572 Helpdesk-khi@smeda.org.pk REGIONAL OFFICE NWFP REGIONAL OFFICE BALOCHISTAN Ground Floor State Life Building The Mall, Peshawar. Tel: (091) 9213046-47 Fax: (091) 286908 helpdesk-pew@smeda.org.pk Bungalow No. 15-A Chaman Housing Scheme Airport Road, Quetta. Tel: (081) 2831623, 2831702 Fax: (081) 2831922 helpdesk-qta@smeda.org.pk March, 2009 Pre-feasibility Study Gaming Zone DISCLAIMER The purpose and scope of this information memorandum is to introduce the subject matter and provide a general idea and information on the said area. All the material included in this document is based on data/information gathered from various sources and is based on certain assumptions. Although, due care and diligence has been taken to compile this document, the contained information may vary due to any change in any of the concerned factors, and the actual results may differ substantially from the presented...

Words: 7106 - Pages: 29

Free Essay

Economic Sectors

...Twelfth Five Year Plan (2012–2017) Economic Sectors Volume II Copyright © Planning Commission (Government of India) 2013 All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or utilised in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording or by any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. First published in 2013 by SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd B1/I-1 Mohan Cooperative Industrial Area Mathura Road, New Delhi 110 044, India www.sagepub.in SAGE Publications Inc 2455 Teller Road Thousand Oaks, California 91320, USA SAGE Publications Ltd 1 Oliver’s Yard, 55 City Road London EC1Y 1SP, United Kingdom SAGE Publications Asia-Pacific Pte Ltd 33 Pekin Street #02-01 Far East Square Singapore 048763 Published by Vivek Mehra for SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd, Phototypeset in 11/13pt Minion Pro by RECTO Graphics, Delhi and printed at Saurabh Printers, New Delhi. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Available ISBN: 978-81-321-1131-3 (PB) The SAGE Team: Rudra Narayan, Archita Mandal, Rajib Chatterjee and Dally Verghese Twelfth Five Year Plan (2012–2017) Economic Sectors Volume II Planning Commission Government of India Thank you for choosing a SAGE product! If you have any comment, observation or feedback, I would like to personally hear from you. Please write to me at contactceo@sagepub.in —Vivek Mehra, Managing Director and CEO, SAGE Publications India Pvt...

Words: 131771 - Pages: 528

Premium Essay

Smeproject

...chapter 1 introduction 1.1 overview of the industry Banking means accepting the deposits from the customers for lending to the needy and extending the other services as to issue of DD etc. Nowadays after introduction of private sector banks the banks have become a profit centre and the functions become changed and now banks are doing the insurance and mutual funds also. But nationalised banks are still service oriented in extending loans for Education loan, and rural development activities. A Bank is an organization which lends money to the borrowers for a purposeful task, and provides a facility to deposit and withdraw money when needed and charge for it. HISTORY OF BANKING IN INDIA Phase I The General Bank of India was set up in the year 1786. Next came Bank of Hindustan and Bengal Bank. The East India Company established Bank of Bengal (1809), Bank of Bombay (1840) and Bank of Madras (1843) as independent units and called it Presidency Banks. These three banks were amalgamated in 1920 and Imperial Bank of India was established which started as private shareholders banks, mostly Europeans shareholders. In 1865 Allahabad Bank was established and first time exclusively by Indians, Punjab National Bank Ltd. was set up in 1894 with headquarters at Lahore. Between 1906 and 1913, Bank of India, Central Bank of India, Bank of Baroda, Canara Bank, Indian Bank, and Bank of Mysore were set up. Reserve Bank of India came in 1935. During the first phase the growth was very...

Words: 12862 - Pages: 52

Free Essay

Practical Implicaitons of Robust

...requires the bundling of MNE and complementary local assets, which they call location or country-specific advantages, but implicitly assume that those assets are freely accessible to MNEs. In contrast to both of these MNE-centric views, I explicitly consider the transactional characteristics of complementary local assets and model foreign market entry as the optimal assignment of equity between their owners and MNEs. By looking at the relative efficiency of the different markets in which MNE and complementary local assets are traded, and at how these two categories of assets match, I am able to predict whether equity will be held by MNEs or by local firms, or shared between them, and whether MNEs will enter through greenfields, brownfields, or acquisitions. The bundling model I propose has interesting implications for the...

Words: 17374 - Pages: 70