Free Essay

I Just Want to Join !!!

In:

Submitted By cortcortt
Words 6864
Pages 28
Modeling Culture in Trade: Uncertainty Avoidance*
Gert Jan Hofstede Wageningen University gertjan.hofstede@wur.nl Catholijn M. Jonker Delft University of Technology c.m.jonker@tudelft.nl Tim Verwaart LEI Wageningen UR tim.verwaart@wur.nl

Keywords: trade, culture, agents, uncertainty avoidance, negotiation Abstract A model is presented of the way that our cultural attitude towards the unknown influences the decisions we make in trade. Uncertainty avoidance is one of Hofstede’s five cultural dimensions. The paper presents a model of how this dimension affects trade. This influence has been explicated for the decisions regarding trade: partner selection, negotiation behavior, trust, and the interpretation of the trade partner’s behavior. It has been verified in simulations showing that the generic tendencies as attributed to uncertainty avoidance are reflected in the simulation results. Our approach is an example of instantiating generic knowledge on the influences of culture on decision-making in general.

INTRODUCTION The international food economy is rapidly changing. Important issues are concentration and globalization, growing information intensity, consumer demands, and social responsibility [Kinsey 2001]. An important issue in current food trade research is the emergence and performance of international supply chain networks [Lazzarini et al. 2001]. Agent-based modeling extends the understanding of processes in society and economy. It enables simulation of the emergence of macro-level phenomena from micro-level interactions between individual agents [Tesfatsion and Judd 2006]. It is therefore well-suited for modeling the emergence and performance of supply chains under different institutional and social arrangements. Differences between national cultures are well-known to have their effect on trade at the micro-level: cultural differences hinder international business contacts - e.g., [Trompenaars 1993]. Relevant processes at the micro-level with respect to chain networks are strategy determination, trade partner selection, negotiation, delivery, and monitoring. The influence of culture on these processes and on trust as an enabler has been the subject of research. In particular negotiation had much research attention - e.g., [Gelfand and Brett 2004] - and the attention for trust, in
____________________

1.

particular in relation to the food economy, is growing - e.g., [Fritz et al. 2006]. [Gorobets and Nooteboom 2006] give evidence by means of a multi-agent simulation that different economic systems (trust versus opportunism) may be efficient in different societies. Other economic literature stresses the relevance of culture for international trade, but models it at the macro-level - e.g., [Bala and Long 2005] and [Kónya 2006]. Given that cultural differences exist and that they are recognized as relevant, realistic agent-based modeling of international trade requires culturally differentiated agent behavior. This paper introduces an exercise in modeling of culture based on the work of [Hofstede 2001]. The context is a gaming simulation of trade in commodities with invisible quality properties [Meijer et al. 2006]. That game is designed as a research tool for study of human behavior with respect to trust in commodity supply chains and networks in different institutional and cultural settings. The work reported in this paper is a step toward modeling of cultural aspects of behavior in trade, that may eventually be validated in this or other games. It reports a multi-agent modeling step in the research cycle described in [Jonker et al. 2006]. Figure 1 schematically depicts this cycle.

Theory Multi-agent simulation Hypotheses Gaming simulation Validation results

Figure 1. Research cycle, schematically after [Jonker et al. 2006].

Hofstede recognized five dimensions of culture. The present paper focuses on the dimension of uncertainty avoidance. The other dimensions are dealt with in other publications e.g., [Hofstede et al. 2006]. Isolating a single dimension and analyzing it separately from the other dimensions is artificial, but it brings the opportunity to verify the partial

* Accepted for presentation at the Agent-Directed Simulation Symposium (ADS'08), part of the 2008 Spring Simulation Multiconference (SpringSim'08), April 14-17, 2008, Ottawa, Canada.

model and validate it against specifically designed gaming simulations. In future work, integrating all the dimensions should lead to more realistic agents; this paper represents an intermediate step. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces culture and the uncertainty avoidance dimension. Section 3 elaborates on the dimension of uncertainty avoidance in trade processes. Section 4 models the dimension of uncertainty avoidance for application in agents. Section 5 presents some experimental results. Section 6 concludes the paper and discusses future research.

2.

CULTURE AND UNCERTAINTY AVOIDANCE People live in groups. Any one person is a member of several groups, e.g. nuclear family, extended family, village, region, club, political organization, religion, country, company. The existence of a group implies that there is an outer boundary. Some cultures like to draw strict, solid boundaries between the various group identities that exist, while in others, group boundaries are not a big issue. Why this is so, is a matter of speculation. From an evolutionary point of view, human beings are in a state between a purely solitary life and one as a perfect group – between a bear’s lair and a bee hive. This implies that in almost all human social interactions, the question “are we part of the same group?” is relevant. The practical implications are that more trust is placed in members of the same group. It is evolutionarily natural for people to collaborate with group members against other groups. At the same time we are more or less flexible in our group memberships. The details are dependent on group culture. [Hofstede 2001] identified five major issues that a society has to resolve in order to function as a group: issues of (1) individual freedom versus group loyalty, (2) division of power, (3) aggression and permissiveness against offenders, (4) gratification of needs, and (5) the unpredictable. This last issue will be examined in the present paper, artificially tearing it apart from social life as a whole. The world is an unpredictable place, and people are aware of this. This knowledge is stressful, but not equally much to all people, nor to all societies. Individual people who cannot cope with unpredictability are likely to score high on neuroticism tests. Cultures that practice strong rituals and beliefs to cope with unpredictability are called uncertainty avoiding. [Hofstede 2001, p. 161] defines this dimension of culture as “the extent to which the members of a culture feel threatened by uncertain or unknown situations”. It is important to realize that this has nothing to do with computable risk. It is about fear of situations in which “anything can happen and one has no idea what” [ibid., p. 148]. Hofstede goes on to explain “Uncertainty-avoiding cultures shun ambiguous situations. People in such cultures look for structure in

their organizations, institutions, and relationships, which makes events clearly interpretable and predictable. Paradoxically, they are often prepared to engage in risky behavior in order to reduce ambiguities – such as starting a fight with a potential opponent rather than sitting back and waiting.” People from societies or groups that are highly uncertainty avoiding do not tolerate ambiguity as to who is a member of their group. In case of doubt they have a tendency to close the ranks and shut strangers out. They tend to have strict moral criteria as to who fits in: adherents of the same religious subgroup, perhaps, or people from the same region, people who speak their language, people of their gender, or similar clear-cut criteria. People from such societies will not easily engage in interactions with others who do not share their most salient group characteristics. It follows that trade will often be a within-group activity, and contacts with alien groups are not easily made. Withingroup contacts, on the contrary, are charged with tokens of loyalty, often through intricately prescribed shared ritual that is needed to counteract the stress that people experience. The average person in such a society is more neurotic, and less agreeable, than in an uncertainty tolerant culture [Hofstede and McCrae 2004]. According to [Hofstede and Hofstede 2005] countries high on uncertainty avoiding are: Central and Latin Europe, Latin America, Japan, South Korea, Russia, Middle East, and Pakistan. On the other hand, societies or groups that are uncertainty tolerant are easy travelers, and will engage in novel activities without needing much time to adjust. They will strike up trade relations with foreigners if the opportunity presents itself. Their social interactions tend to be laid-back. Countries with this orientation are China and Southeast Asia, Scandinavia, Anglo countries and India. The origin of differences on this dimension is not clear. Presumably, uncertainty avoiding societies have occurred where evolution favored conservatism and closed social networks, and uncertainty tolerant societies have occurred where evolution rewarded exploration and mixing. Societies with an old tradition of agriculture are frequently uncertainty avoiding and those that involve fishing or trading are uncertainty tolerant; but there are exceptions. Current pressures of globalization may change the situation; yet evidence for the moment does not indicate that worldwide differences in uncertainty avoidance have been changing over the last decades. Thus, in discussing trade behaviors, uncertainty avoidance can be considered a causal factor. Pairs of countries that differ much on this dimension of culture and less on others, where the first is the more uncertainty avoiding, are Japan-China, Germany-Great Britain, South Korea-Singapore, Italy-Ireland, Finland Denmark. Table 1 displays some distinctions that characterize the difference between uncertainty avoiding and uncertainty tolerant societies.

Table 1. Some distinctions - relevant for trade - between norms in uncertainty avoiding and uncertainty tolerant societies) Uncertainty tolerant Uncertainty avoiding Being busy is not a value per Inner urge to be busy (1) se Suppression of emotions Expression of emotions (2) Openness to change and Conservatism, law and order (3) innovation Willingness to take unknown Only known risks are taken (4) risks What is different is curious What is different is (5) dangerous Tolerance of diversity Xenophobia (6) Comfortable with ambiguity Need for clarity and structure (7) and chaos Appeal of novelty and Appeal of purity (8) convenience source: [Hofstede 2001, p. 161]

3.

UNCERTAINTY AVOIDANCE IN TRADE The core of trade is the execution of transactions: exchange of commodities or rights for money. Transactions are based on a contract that may specify additional conditions, to enforce delivery according to the contract. From the perspective taken in this paper, contracting is not the only relevant activity of trading agents. Figure 2 presents a process model of trading agents.

determine trade goal negotiate contract select trade partner

cooperate or defect update beliefs trust or test

Figure 2. Processes and internal information flow of trading agents

Before entering negotiations, agents have to select each other as partners to negotiate with, based on their trade goals (sell or buy?; which commodity?; which quality?; what risk is acceptable?) and knowledge about potential partners. This information also plays an important role during the negotiation process. Once a contract has been agreed upon, the traders have to deliver. In this phase of the transaction they can either cooperate (deliver according to the contract) or defect, deliberately or as a flaw of their control system. Traders may either trust their partner to deliver truthfully or monitor the delivery (put it to the test). The latter usually incurs some cost, while trust is for free. The decisions about cooperation and trust are based on personal preferences and

cultural background, as well as beliefs about the trade partner and the trade environment. Delivery and monitoring and the decisions about cooperation and trust are relevant for both sellers and buyers. However, the research reported in the present paper models trade in the Trust And Tracing game [Meijer et al. 2006]. In this context the cooperation decision is relevant for agents in the selling role and the trust decision is relevant for agents in the buying role. Experience from the negotiation and delivery processes may change a trader’s beliefs about the trade environment or about individual trade partners. The beliefs will, in addition to a trader’s preferences, guide decision making in future trading. In the present paper we limit ourselves to beliefs about trade partners. For the purpose of modeling trade processes three traits about partners can be defined that trading agents maintain a belief about: - the belief about another agent’s fairness represents an agent’s expectation that a fair contract can be negotiated in a fair way with the other agent; - the belief about another agent’s trustworthiness represents an agent’s expectation that the other agent will deliver according to contract; - the belief about another agent’s benevolence represents an agent’s expectation that the other will accept deliveries without putting them to the test, in other words that the other agent will trust. (Note that what the authors call benevolence may in other cultures be seen as credulity.) The effect that uncertainty avoidance has on these beliefs, and on the decision making in trade processes, is also influenced by the agent’s cultural background with respect to the other dimensions. This mutual influence is not taken into account for the moment. Based on the works of [Hofstede 2001, 2005] and preliminary observations in the Trust And Tracing game [Meijer et al. 2006] hypothetical differences in behavior can be formulated for traders from different cultures. The following paragraphs describe expected differences across the uncertainty avoidance dimension. The descriptions are used in the next section to specify rules for agent behavior. Negotiation behavior. The first bid of an uncertainty avoiding trader tends to be modest in the sense that it is a price he thinks is right. The uncertainty avoiding have an emotional style of negotiation, making sure that the opponents understand their feelings (see row 2 in table 1). They will not adapt their behavior to their opponent’s. In the bargaining that follows they will not easily give in nor will much time be spent. After a few unsuccessful iterations, the uncertainty avoiding trader will break off the negotiation. The uncertainty tolerant traders on the other hand have a relaxed style of negotiation. They try to adapt their behavior to their counterparty's, although they are not prepared to come to an agreement at all cost. They do not show their emotions and may be disconcerted if their opponents do. They are careful not be more yielding than

their counterparts are, not especially modest, and are ready to break off negotiations in case of insufficient progress. Trade goal selection. In uncertainty avoiding societies the main concern of traders is not to be deceived. They are willing to pay a price for certainty. Although they prefer valuable high quality commodities, they will opt for cheaper low quality rather than valuable high quality if they do not feel certain about the high quality. Traders with a cultural background of uncertainty tolerance opportunistically trade both low and high quality products and have a neutral risk attitude. They prefer high quality, but only if the price is right, and they are not adverse of trading low quality if it brings them a profit. Maintenance of beliefs about partners. In uncertainty avoiding societies the traders need some external justification (group membership or reputation) for doing business with new partners. The new partners will not be trusted. However, a low estimate of trustworthiness does not hinder a transaction. If the uncertainty avoiding know what to expect, they arm themselves and enter only into contracts with sufficient securities. Once, in the course of repeated transactions, sufficient evidence for trustworthiness has been found through tracing of deliveries, and partners have become familiar, the uncertainty avoiding will come to trust their partners and expect them to follow the rules like they do themselves. After they have come to trust, any unexpected revelation of deceit provokes furious reactions from uncertainty avoiding traders. They will not easily deal again with a partner that abused their trust. Like for uncertainty avoiding, uncertainty tolerant traders increase the partner's future acceptability if negotiations result in an agreement, and decrease it if negotiations fail. Uncertainty tolerant traders are not particularly distrusting, and trust will develop through repeated transactions. They will trace now and then, with decreasing frequency as trust develops. Revealed deceit will of course reduce trust and increase the frequency of tracing. Truthful or untruthful delivery. After an agreement has been reached, it comes to delivery. If the quality of the commodity is invisible at first sight, the supplier can be opportunistic and try to deliver a lower quality product than agreed upon, thus making an extra profit. An uncertainty tolerant trader may be tempted to do so, calculating the risk of being exposed as a deceiver and the damage that would do to his reputation and future trading opportunities. An uncertainty avoiding trader may have a lot of rules and contracts that forbid defecting, but that does not mean that he will follow the rules. Depending on the other dimensions of culture, traders from uncertainty avoiding cultures may just as easily or even more defect than uncertainty tolerant, especially when dealing with out-group partners. Trust or distrust. An uncertainty avoiding trader does not expect the rules to be broken and will trust, unless he is dealing with a stranger. A new partner will be distrusted

until sufficient evidence for the contrary has been found. In uncertainty tolerant societies, the other dimensions of culture determine the level of trust. The rules and contracts do not have a value per se for the uncertainty tolerant. Partner selection. In both uncertainty avoiding and uncertainty tolerant societies, traders prefer to deal with familiar relations, because that brings the experience gathered in previous transactions to value. However, in uncertainty tolerant societies traders will not hesitate to propose or enter negotiations with strangers, if for some reason dealing with familiar relations is inconvenient. Uncertainty avoiding traders on the other hand have a high threshold for entering into new relations. They feel uncomfortable proposing to parties they did not deal with before. For acceptance of new partners, they need an external justification, for instance based on group membership or a good reputation. In addition, they prefer to deal with counterparts having equal status (and profession if applicable).

REPRESENTATION IN AGENTS This section defines production rules that formalize the knowledge about the influence of uncertainty avoidance on trade processes. The rules are formulated for one-to-one verification of the agents in DESIRE [Brazier et al. 2002]. The simulation applies many more rules, but because of space limitations we only present the rules that involve the uncertainty avoidance index of culture. The relevant attributes of transactions are the economic value of the transaction, the quality of the traded goods as a status attribute in its own (“we deal in superior quality products”) and a perceived risk that the trade partner will not fulfill its contractual obligations. The latter is based on trust, contractual conditions, and other attributes of the transaction, including product quality: higher valued products like organic food, designer clothes, and jewelry are a more likely target for swindle and counterfeiting than lower valued products. The negotiation model for both traders, i.e. buyer and seller, uses a utility function to compare bids. 1 Ubid = w1f1(value) + w2f2(quality) + w3f3(risk) (1)

4.

with w1+w2+w3=1, and wi in [0, 1], for all i. f1 presents normalized economic value of the bid in the interval [0, 1]; it is more or less objective in terms of cost and market value, but is calculated differently for buyers and sellers: e.g., a high price for low quality has a high value for sellers, but a low value for buyers. f2 presents normalized additional
1

In the context of the current research, we apply equation (1). If for some reason another utility evaluation function were used, the knowledge presented in this section would remain valid, but some rules might need to be reformulated.

value in [0, 1] that is attached in society to trading high quality; it is subjective and its value may differ according to personal preferences and cultural background. f3 evaluates the risk of swindle normalized in [0, 1], with 1 representing a transaction without any risk; for a buyer it is based on the opportunity for the seller to deceive and the buyer’s belief about seller’s trustworthiness; for a seller it is based on opportunity and belief about the buyer’s benevolence. Weight factors characterize an agent’s strategy, e.g., represent an opportunistic trade strategy, a quality-minded strategy, and represent a thrifty strategy. Traders in uncertainty avoiding cultures strongly prefer a quality-minded strategy, while traders in uncertainty tolerant societies tend to follow an opportunistic strategy (see rows 4, 7, and 8 in table 1). Uncertainty avoiding agents have an increased risk aversion for “strangers”. In our simulation we use labels to distinguish groups of agents and societal status. The following rule uses these variables as indicators of similarity of agents. Let the relation agent_trait_value: ISSUE × Real, stand for the natural inclination of the agent to weigh an issue. Then the effect of uncertainty avoidance and agent labels of both negotiation partners can be implemented as follows.
/* 1 calculate w-factors using UAI and group and status labels*/ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and agent_label(status, S: Real) and agent_label(group, G: Group_label) and partner_model_contains_belief(T: Trader, status, Y: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T, group, L: Group_label) and group_distance (G, L, D: Real) and agent_trait_value(value_preference, P: Real) and agent_trait_value(quality_preference, Q: Real) and agent_trait_value(risk_aversion, R: Real) and N: Real = (P + Q + R+(1-R)*U*(1+max(D,abs(S-Y)))/2 ) then weight_for_value_toward( T, P / N ) and weight_for_quality_toward( T, Q / N ) and weight_for_risk_toward(T, (R+(1-R)*U*(1+max(D,abs(S-Y)))/2) / N );

Agents accept offers if the difference of their own bid’s utility and partner’s bid utility is less than the utility gap, realistically valued 0.02 according to human experiments. If an agent does not accept an offer, it has to decide whether to stop the negotiation or to make a counteroffer. The simulated agents use a random generator for this decision. The following rules - involving impatience, cut-off value, and minimal progress value – express that impatient agents (impatience is an agent trait) and agents from uncertainty avoiding cultures are more likely to stop (rows 1 and 2 in table 1). In these rules a uniform random variable Z in [0, 1] is used. The probability of stopping if the other conditions in rules 2 and 3 hold is equal to the maximum of the cultural uncertainty avoidance index and the impatience as a personality trait.
/* 2 rather stop if impatient or UA and cut-off value is not met */ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and current_negotiation(T: Trader, X: Integer, L: Commodity_list) and agent_trait_value(cut_off_value, C: Real) and agent_trait_value(impatience, I: Real) and current_round(X) and others_bid_utility_in_round(B: Real, X) and B < C and random(0, 1, Z: Real) and max(I, U) > Z then stop_negotiation(T, X, L, gap); /* 3 rather stop if impatient or UA and partner makes little progress */ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and current_negotiation(T: Trader, X: Integer, L: Commodity_list) and agent_trait_value(minimal_progress, M: Real) and agent_trait_value(impatience, I: Real) and current_round(X) and X > 3 and progress_in_bids(X-3, X, P: Real) and P < M and random(0, 1, Z: Real) and max(I, U) > Z then stop_negotiation(T, X, L, no-accom);

Traits, status, and uncertainty avoidance index are real numbers in [0, 1]; N is the sum of the the weight factors wi before normalization. The divisions by N normalize the sum of the weight factors to 1. Agents use the utility function to decide whether to accept or to refuse a bid, and, in the latter case, whether to break off the negotiation or to make a counteroffer. The simulated negotiation process applies the negotiation architecture of {Jonker and Treur 2001]. Parameters in this approach are utility gap, impatience, concession factor, and negotiation speed. Furthermore the algorithm uses a cut-off value and a minimal progress value as criteria to break off negotiations. All parameters are implemented as agent traits, i.e. they are represented in real values in the interval [0, 1]. Some are influenced by the value of the uncertainty avoidance index. Realistic base values of the parameters were established in human experiments [Bosse 2004].

If an agent does not stop following rules 2 and 3, it tries and makes a counteroffer. In the process of preparing a counteroffer the agent may still stop if no room for further concessions can be found, taking the minimum utility into account. The minimum utility is related with the opening bid through the concession factor γ: Uminimum=(1γ)Uopening_bid. We assume that Uminimum is not significantly different across the cultural dimension of uncertainty avoidance, but that agents in uncertainty avoiding cultures are more modest in their opening bid and have a lower concession factor (rows 3 and 7). They also have a lower negotiation speed, i.e. their relative concessions from their previous bid towards the minimum utility are smaller. As an example we present the rule for the maximal concession.
/* 4 uncertainty avoiding agents make smaller concessions */ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and current_round(X: Integer) and my_bid_utility_in_round(B: Real, X-1) and agent_trait_value(minimum_utility, M: Real)

and base_negotiation_speed (S: Real) and ua_negotiation_speed (V: real) then maximal_concession_in_round (X, (B-M)*((1-U)*S+U*V) );

The agents stop the negotiation if the maximal concession is less than 0.01. In this rule and some other decision rules linearly weighted sums are used, with the uncertainty avoidance index as weight factor. Future validation of the models must decide if this simplification is justified. After successful negotiations the supplier has to deliver the commodities. If the agreement was to deliver a high quality commodity, the supplier may deliver low quality, if the difference is invisible at first sight. Whether an agent actually defects or cooperates depends on many factors, including the quality of the relation with the customer and the estimate of the customer’s benevolence. An uncertainty avoiding agent’s has a lower threshold for defection of strangers than for similar partners (table 2, rows 5, 6, and 7).
/* 5 uncertainty avoiding have a low deceit threshold for strangers */ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and agent_label(status, S: Real) and agent_label(group, G: Group_label) and current_partner(T: Trader) and partner_model_contains_belief(T, status, Y: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T, group, L: Group_label) and group_distance (G, L, D: Real) and agent_trait_value(honesty, H: Real) then deceit_treshold_toward(T, H * (1-U*max(D,abs(S-Y)));

with δ+ and δ- in the interval [0,1]; tC,x represents trust in agent C after round x; eC,x represents the experienced result with C in round x. In this case the result of tracing eC,x is either 1 (partner cooperated) or 0 (partner defected). An uncertainty avoiding agent has a low value of δ+ and an high value of δ- (table 2, rows 3 and 7), in particular if it has little in common with its trade partner (rows 5 and 6).
/* 7 trust comes slowly and vanishes rapidly in UA societies */ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and agent_label(status, S: Real) and agent_label(group, G: Group_label) and partner_model_contains_belief(T: Trader, status, Y: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T , group, L: Group_label) and group_distance (G, L, D: Real) and agent_trait_value(base_neg_update_factor, N: Real) and agent_trait_value(base_pos_update_factor, P: Real) and max_ua_neg_update_factor(E: Real) and min_ua_pos_update_factor(F: Real) then neg_update_factor_toward(T, N*(1-U)+E*U*(1+max(D, abs(S-Y))/2) and pos_update_factor_toward(T, P*(1-U)+F*U*(1+max(D, abs(S-Y))/2);

The deceit threshold is used in the rules for the decision whether to cooperate or to defect. The latter rules are not presented in this paper for space limitations. They do not differ across the dimension of uncertainty avoidance. The customer has to decide whether to trust the delivery or put it to the test (trace it). The likelihood that a customer will rather test, depends on his trust in the partner, but an uncertainty avoiding customer will rather trace if he has little in common with the supplier (rows 4, 5, 6 in table 2).
/* 6 uncertainty avoiding agents do not trust strangers */ If cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and deal_in_round (T: Trader, B: Bid, X: Integer) and current_round (X) and agent_label(status, S: Real) and agent_label(group, G: Group_label) and partner_model_contains_belief(T , trustworthiness, W: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T , status, Y: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T , group, L: Group_label) and group_distance (G, L, D: Real) and random(0, 1, Z: Real) and (1-U)*(1-W) + U*max(D,abs(S-Y),(1-W)) > Z then to-be-traced(B);

In this rule the UA-factors differ a factor of at least 3 with the base-factors. Fairness, as defined in section 3, is used to select a future trade partner. Agents will rather select a partner they believe to be fairer than another partner. The belief about a partner’s fairness is maintained similar to equation (2) after a negotiation has stopped. For a successful negotiation, the utility is taken as experience value; the experience value of an unsuccessful negotiation is 0. Uncertainty tolerant agents select their partners primarily on the basis of fairness. The following rule expresses that uncertainty avoiding agents have additional preferences for common group membership and common status (table 2, rows 5 and 6).
/* 8 uncertainty avoiding agents prefer similar partners */ if cultural_script_contains(uncertainty_avoidance_index(U: Real)) and agent_label(status, S: Real) and agent_label(group, G: Group_label) and partner_model_contains_belief(T: Trader, fairness, F: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T , status, Y: Real) and partner_model_contains_belief(T , group, L: Group_label) and group_distance (G, L, D: Real) then acceptability (T, F*(1-U*max(D,abs(S-Y))) );

5.

Tracing results are a source for trust update. Trust update can be modeled as follows. tC,x = (1-δ+) tC,x-1 + δ+ eC,x if eC,x ≥ tC,x-1 tC,x = (1-δ-) tC,x-1 + δ- eC,x if eC,x < tC,x-1 (2)

EXPERIMENTAL RESULTS In order to verify the correct formulation of the rules presented in section 4, one-to-one scenarios were simulated step by step. For reasons of space, the results are not included in this paper. Results are available from the authors. Subsequently, the behavior was implemented in a multi-agent model of a trade process, based on the gaming simulation in Meijer et al. (2006). In this simulation sellers and buyers can • select each other for negotiation, • exchange bids,

• deliver commodities, and • send received commodities to a tracing agent for testing. By tracing they incur a tracing fee. The tracing agent is authorized to punish deceivers by a fine. The multi-agent simulation is implemented in Cormas (http://cormas.cirad.fr). Source code is not included in this paper, but is available from the authors. The Cormas simulation is synchronized in time steps. In the first step each buyer may send a bid to a seller of its choice. In each following time step each agent may: • either wait for a reply to a bid it made, • or stop the ongoing negotiation and propose a new one to any agent in the opposite role by sending it a bid, • or reply to a received bid with a counter bid, • or accept a bid and, in case it is selling, send a delivery, • or receive a delivery and decide whether to forward it to the tracing agent or not. In the last two cases it may subsequently propose a new negotiation by sending a bid to any agent in the opposite role. The agents cannot negotiate synchronously with more then one partner. They send no (if they wait for a reply) or one bid per time step. Table 2 presents typical results of example runs for simulation runs of 100 time steps. The agents have a group label that is visible for other agents. The agents interpret other agents carrying a label different from their own as having maximal group distance. One label was attached to uncertainty tolerant agents (UAI=0.2), two different labels were attached to uncertainty avoiding agents (UAI=0.8). Both sellers and buyers either belonged to a single group of eight or were divided into two groups of four in which all group members have an equal group label and UAI. All agents have equal negotiation parameters and other initial settings. Table 2 presents the total number of successful transactions. This number results from the combination of all processes. There may be variance because of the occasional selection of partners, the occurrence of defection that may lower trust in individual relations, and the failure of negotiations if agents lose their patience or do not sufficiently accommodate their partners. If all agents are uncertainty tolerant and belong to a common group, trade goes smoother than if all agents are uncertainty avoiding and belong to a common group (compare run 1 and run 2). If uncertainty avoiding agents can find in-group partners, stratification occurs: the uncertainty avoiding agents exclude out-group traders (see runs 3 and 4). Trade stagnates if the uncertainty avoiding agents cannot deal with in-group partners, but it goes a bit smoother with uncertainty tolerant partners (run 6) than it does with uncertainty avoiding (run 5). The latter effect vanishes in the mixed settings like run 7, where uncertainty avoiding agents are holding up trade. They spend much time on negotiations that fail because of insufficient progress and

impatience of the uncertainty tolerant agents. In run 8 one group of uncertainty avoiding agents (group 1) can find each other; as a result, group 2 and the uncertainty tolerant can speed up.
Table 2. Number of successful transactions between two groups of 4 sellers and two groups of 4 buyers, with different values of uncertainty avoidance index, in simulation runs where sellers and buyers can individually select each other for negotiation (UT: UAI = 0.2; UA1: UAI=0.8; UA2: UAI=0.8; group distances UT-UA1, UA1-UA2, and UA2-UT are all 1.0, so maximal) run 1 seller groups run 3 seller groups run 5 seller groups run 7 seller groups buyer groups UT UT UT 13 25 UT 18 25 buyer groups UA1 UT UA1 36 0 UT 1 46 buyer groups UA2 UA2 UA1 7 4 UA1 9 9 buyer groups UA2 UT UA1 7 10 UA1 12 4 run 2 seller groups run 4 seller groups run 6 seller groups run 8 seller groups buyer groups UA1 UA1 UA1 5 12 UA1 14 14 buyer groups UA1 UA2 UA1 26 1 UA2 3 33 buyer groups UT UT UA1 19 14 UA1 11 13 buyer groups UA 1 UT UA1 25 2 UA2 4 17

6.

CONCLUSIONS AND FUTURE WORK This paper contributes to the research into trade processes by offering a model of the influence of the uncertainty avoidance dimension of culture on trade processes. The work in this paper is a sequel to Hofstede et al. (2006), in which the influence on trade of the masculinity / femininity dimension of culture is modeled. Our choice to model the dimensions first in isolation is deliberate. Despite its partial nature the model is applicable for traders from cultures that differ mostly on this dimension, e.g., JapanChina, Germany-Great Britain, South Korea-Singapore, Italy-Ireland, Finland - Denmark. By modeling only the influence of one dimension, the model can be validated with respect to the general theory, and with respect to dedicated human simulation games. The model is based on the theory of [Hofstede 2001], as well as on the experience of the authors with the Trust and Tracing Game [Meijer et al., 2006], in which people from different cultures participate in a gaming simulation. Trade aspects considered were: trade goal selection, partner selection, negotiation behavior, maintenance of beliefs about trade partners, and related to these trust and the truthful or untruthful delivery of goods. The model has not been validated against human negotiators and this remains to be done. The results do however show good face validity. Uncertainty tolerant agents find it easy to trade with partners they do not know

and their negotiations are often successful. Whether they trust their trade partner or not does not so much depend on group membership. Neither does their selection of trade goods, or their decision to deliver truthfully or not. Furthermore, their interpretation of the behavior of their trade partners, which determines the way they maintain beliefs about these partners, does not depend on the groups they belong to. This is different for people from uncertainty avoiding cultures. They base their selection of trade goals on a minimization of risk, they would rather trade with people they know, are reluctant to trust strangers, progress more slowly during negotiations, and have a low threshold regarding deception of people they have little in common with. Vice versa they are looking for a pretext to see their suspicions confirmed, thus when deceived, they tend to respond furiously, and tend to avoid that partner if possible. The model has been tested in simulations showing that the generic tendencies as attributed to uncertainty avoidance are reflected in the simulation results. Our work shows how the influence of culture on decision-making processes can be modeled. So far, the literature on the influence of culture is largely generic in nature and not formalized into working simulations and/or agent-based systems. The pattern in our approach is that for each possible decision-making rule two aspects are considered. Would the cultural background: • make the rule inappropriate, and • change the parameters of the rule? With this in mind, the normal decision making process for the task at hand is considered in all its stages. Future work. The authors’ aim to validation and calibration the model against experiments with human participants, as depicted in Figure 1. Future work comprises experiments with questionnaires and one-to-one negotiation gaming simulations. As a preparation for this work, more extensive sensitivity analyses are required. When all five dimensions have been modeled and validated in isolation, the next step is to combine models of several dimensions. The main problem here is to maintain validation; by entering too many variables at once, attributing behavior to some of them is hard. For that reason, combinations of two dimensions are aimed for. Combinations will be selected with respect to available pairs of cultures comparable with respect to the remaining dimensions, and differ with respect to the selected two dimensions. The various models that combine the influence of two dimensions are of direct use to model traders coming from the cultures for which only those two dimensions differ, and for traders from cultures for which only one of those dimensions differ. The final model combining five dimensions can be used to model traders from any cultural background.

Acknowledgement. The authors thank John Wolters for engineering the multi-agent simulation. References
Bala, V. and Long, N.V. 2005. “International trade and cultural diversity with preference selection”, European Journal of Political Economy, 21: 143-162. Bosse, T., Jonker, C.M., and Treur, J. 2004 "Experiments in Human Multi-Issue Negotiation: Analysis and Support" in Proc. of the Third International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, AAMAS'04: 672 – 679. Brazier, F.M.T., Jonker, C.M., and Treur, J. 2002. “Principles of Component-Based Design of Intelligent Agents”, Data and Knowledge Engineering, 41: 1-28. Fritz, M., Rickert, U. and Schiefer, G. (eds) 2006. Trust and Risk in Business Networks. Proc. of the 99th European Seminar of the EAAE. Bonn, ILB Press. Gelfand, M.J. and Brett, J.M. 2004. The Handbook of Negotiation and Culture. Stanford University Press. Gorobets, A. and Nooteboom, B. 2006. “Agent Based modeling of Trust Between Firms in Markets” in Advances in Artificial Economics, ed.: Bruun, C., Springer, LNEMS 584: 121-132. Hofstede, G. 2001. Culture’s Consequences, second edition. Sage Publications. Hofstede, G. and Hofstede, G.J. 2005. Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind. McGraw-Hill. Hofstede, G.J., Jonker, C.M., Meijer, S., and Verwaart, T. 2006. “Modeling Trade and Trust across Cultures” in Proc. of the 4th International Conference on Trust Management, iTrust 2006, Springer, LNCS 3986: 120-134. Hofstede, G. and McCrae, R.R. 2004. “Personality and Culture Revisited: Linking Traits and Dimensions of Culture”, CrossCultural Research 38, 52-88. Jonker, C.M., Meijer, S., Tykhonov, D., and Verwaart, T. 2006. “Multi-agent Model of Trust in a Human Game” in Artificial Economics, ed: Mathieu, P., Beaufils, B., and Brandouy, O., Springer, LNMES 564: 91-102. Jonker, C.M. and Treur, J. 2001. “An Agent Architecture for Multi-Attribute Negotiation” in Proc. of the 17th International Joint Conference on AI, IJCAI ’01, ed: Nebel, N., Morgan Kaufman: 1195-2001. Kinsey, Jean 2001. “The New Food Economy: Consumers, Farms, Pharms and Science”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83: 1113-1130. Kónya, I. 2006. “Modeling Cultural Barriers in International Trade”, Review of International Economics, 14 (3): 494–507. Lazzarini, S.G., Chaddad, F.R., and Cook, M.L. 2001. “Integrating supply chain and network analyses: the study of netchains”, Journal on Chain and Network Science, 1: 7-22. Meijer, S., Hofstede, G.J., Beers, G., and Omta, S.W.F. 2006. “Trust and Tracing game: learning about transactions and embeddedness in a trade network”, Production Planning and Control, 17: 569-583. Tesfatsion, L., Judd, K.L. 2006. Handbook of Computational Economics Volume 2 Agent-based Computational Economics. North-Holland. Trompenaars, F. 1993. Riding the waves of culture: understanding cultural diversity in business. Economist Books, London.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

I Just Want to Join

...that it only works with high market share and this is not the only meter for success. Also there are many situations in business where the Dogs can out earn the Cash Cows. The BCG grid may provide a the basis for a business development strategy for large business but what about the small business? It is possible to have a high market share and not have increased profits, or have a low market share and still be profitable. BCG Analysis is a great stepping stone for market research and has great possibilities, but for today's companies it may need to be tweaked just a little. This business model is a pretty decent model and if used in the right situation it can help a business to increase and monitor its market share and growth. All business big or small should have some type of a business plan or model that they can base their business products on and by keeping an eye on the market and watching what consumers want they can increase their profit. A simple BCG Matrix diagram or template can be used to plan your Growth Market Share strategy and many samples can be found on the web. If you prefer you may use BCG Matrix software....

Words: 337 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

I Just Want to Join

...Module 1 Lab Report For this module, I have chosen the movie Taken to analyze. In it, Bryan Mills’ teenage daughter, Kim, travels to Paris with a friend to follow a band on tour. Shortly after arriving, the two share a taxi with a stranger who works in a human trafficking ring. The two are profiled and abducted soon after, but Kim is on the phone with her father at the time of the abduction. Using very limited clues and training as an ex-CIA operative, he tracks down these men all over Europe and rescues his daughter. This modern-day myth shares a very powerful cultural truth-value that we can see in ancient myths such as The Iliad and The Odyssey. The characters in these stories are driven by a strong love for somebody else and will do anything for those they love. This is true in society today, as we would do anything for those we love. In Taken, we only see this portrayed in one character. In these other myths, however, we see a multitude of heroes perform grand acts for those they love. In The Iliad, Menelaus brings together the Achaean armies to attack and conquer the mighty city of Troy for one reason: Love. His beloved wife, Helen, had been taken away by Paris of Troy to be his wife. In an effort to save his wife, he traveled across dangerous land and oceans to Troy where the Greeks fought in a war for 10 years. If not for love, a 10 year war because of a single man’s desire would seem absolutely absurd. However, we all can sympathize with Menelaus because we would...

Words: 768 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

I Just Want to Join

...|GCI-1074A FORFF (1-14) |Arizona Department of Economic Security | | | |Arizona Early Intervention Program (AzEIP) | | | | |DATE | | | |4/9/2016 | | |AzEIP AHCCCS Member Service Request | | |AzEIP SERVICE COORDINATOR’S NAME |PHONE NO. |EMAIL | |Noelle Franks |480-229-5280 |Noelle.ACT@gmail.com | |AzEIP TBEIS CONTRACTOR |PHONE NO. |EMAIL | |Arizona Cooperative Therapies |o-602-547-1111/ |n/a | | ...

Words: 777 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

I Just Want to Join the Site

...nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join the site and for that i need to upload something This is nothing I just want to join...

Words: 558 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

I Just Want to Join and See What This Is About

...Opportunities 10 Organizational Threats 10 Leadership Evaluation 11 Leadership Strengths 11 Leadership Weaknesses 13 Recommendations for Leadership Development 14 Organization Overview Organizational overview provides a framework of the organization. It would ideally be a catalogue all necessary information that would help an external party to assess the organizational fit in a better way and understand whether he/she is in total sync with the organizational goals and the other beneficiaries. The organizational overview addresses the following: * The mission and the history * The stakeholders * The goals and the programs * The budget * The outcomes and the achievements * The sponsors or the funders. I have chosen Salesforce.com as the organization for my analysis and believe that the description provided would help in giving a better understanding of the organization for any third party considering a position with the organization. This organization was developed about fifteen years ago with the objective of bringing together better and reinvented customer relationship management services (CRM) using the mechanism of cloud computing. They have revolutionized the process of CRM, and the way they have incorporated the entire system in cloud computing led to the foundation of a path breaking philanthropic model for them to...

Words: 284 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

My Test

...I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just want to join. I just...

Words: 351 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Joining Site

...I am just trying to join this site and take a look at what kinds of papers and information may be on the site. There is a minimum 250 word essay required to join. I am not presently uploading an actual paper but certainly may once I get on the site and look around and decide if I want to continue or not. I am just trying to join this site and take a look at what kinds of papers and information may be on the site. There is a minimum 250 word essay required to join. I am not presently uploading an actual paper but certainly may once I get on the site and look around and decide if I want to continue or not. I am just trying to join this site and take a look at what kinds of papers and information may be on the site. There is a minimum 250 word essay required to join. I am not presently uploading an actual paper but certainly may once I get on the site and look around and decide if I want to continue or not. I am just trying to join this site and take a look at what kinds of papers and information may be on the site. There is a minimum 250 word essay required to join. I am not presently uploading an actual paper but certainly may once I get on the site and look around and decide if I want to continue or...

Words: 253 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

I Want You...

...“I WANT YOU FOR THE U.S. ARMY!” Now, what would you do if someone were to ask you this? Or if you seen it out in town on a poster? Would you pay any attention to it or just walk on by? Most people would honestly just walk on by, unless, there was something in that particular poster that had caught their attention. Recruiting ads have changed over the years, but this one was popular. This particular recruiting advertisement was an effective argument because of their slogan, Uncle Sam, his stare, his point, and the use of America’s colors; red, white, and blue. I would say this particular recruiting image was for men or boys. Back then it were only the men or boys who could actually join the army. So, this poster excluded any women and girls because they were not allowed to join. The main targeted audience for this was for the younger men and boys, and for more than one reason. The younger they are, the more apt they are to be healthier. The army wants them to be younger because they can move more quickly and act upon things faster than someone who is older. They also want the men who don’t already have a family started because then they won’t have that worry while out in battle and can focus better on what they need to do. Where is the place where you see most advertisements for things? Out in town, right? This image was more than likely posted out in town on public buildings as well, that is where most of a town’s population goes for many different reasons. Having it out where...

Words: 812 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Signup

...Crips did not form until later. Many people question why young men and even kids join gangs, and there can be different answers to that question. However many people can agree that gangs and gang involvement is deviant act. The question now is what type of deviant organization are gangs, according to me, I believe that gangs are organized crime groups, or also a deviant family outlook. I believe that gangs are organized crime groups because gangs make up 48% of violent crimes (www.fbi.gov). Gangs take part in many different violent acts such as murder, theft, rape, kidnaping and etc… That is because gangs compete with other rival gangs, and when asked why they fight most gang members did not have a reason why. (Made in America Video). However they said if they kill one of us, than we go and kill three of them, it is that type of attitude that has led to 48% of violent crimes. (Made in America Video). Gangs to me are also organized crime groups because they participate in drug manufacturing, trade, and distribution which has to be carefully operated, without it being organized there would not be a profit made. Participating in all these different activities within the gang is what leads me to believe that they are an organized crime group. Another question that many people ask is, why do young men and kids join gangs? After reading “Why American Boys Join Gangs” the majority of kids that join gangs are low income minorities. According to Stanley Taylor, “―Ultimately, children...

Words: 1628 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Hazing

...willingness to participate" (Hazing Defined 1). Most hazing deaths occur because the act goes too far; the hazers get carried away. Their intention is to have a team building activity or make sure members are up to snuff (Facts.com 2). However, this is not what really happens. The acts often cross the line, and the victims do not complain because they want to join the group (Facts.com 2). Teens often want to outdo one another; each year, teens do something more dangerous than what happened to them while they were the victims (Bowers 1; Bushweller 3). Not only can these acts be dangerous, but they are also an "abuse of power and [a] violation of human dignity" (High School Hazing). If teens can be educated that this hurtful and inhumane act of bullying is forbidden in high school, then they will know that it is not acceptable in college, where hazing becomes the most dangerous. Although high school hazing starts out and seems harmless, it can quickly escalate to being harmful, dangerous, and illegal. However, in most cases, the victim will still take part because they want to join the group. Take for instance, Casey Culpepper. She wanted to join the volleyball team her first year in high school. All through the summer, the threat of the "initiation" haunted her. One day she and her friends were attacked by seniors after class and smeared with concoctions that included canned dog food, eggs, ketchup, mustard, horse manure and pet feces. They were then hosed off so hard that it hurt (Bowers...

Words: 1801 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Hazing

...Most hazing deaths occur because the act goes too far; the hazers get carried away. Their intention is to have a team building activity or make sure members are up to snuff (Facts.com 2). However, this is not what really happens. The acts often cross the line, and the victims do not complain because they want to join the group (Facts.com 2). Teens often want to outdo one another; each year, teens do something more dangerous then what happened to them while they were the victims (Bowers 1; Bushweller 3). Not only can these acts be dangerous, but they are also an “abuse of power and [a] violation of human dignity” (High School Hazing). If teens can be educated that this hurtful and inhumane act of bullying is forbidden in high school, then they will know that it is not acceptable in college, where hazing becomes the most dangerous. Although high school hazing starts out and seems harmless, it can quickly escalate to being harmful, dangerous, and illegal. Hazing can very quickly turn from a harmless prank into a dangerous situation. In most cases, the victim will still take part because they want to join the group. Take for instance, Casey Culpepper. She wanted to join the volleyball team her first year in high school. All through the summer, the threat of the "initiation" haunted her. One day she and her friends were attacked by seniors after class and smeared with concoctions that included canned dog food, eggs, ketchup, mustard, horse manure and pet...

Words: 2044 - Pages: 9

Free Essay

Socialising 1 Breaking the Ice Worksheets Jd

...decide to attend an international conference. You have never attended such an event before. What is your main reason for attending? Choose one option. a. I’m going to attend lots of presentations so I can keep up-to-date with developments in my industry. b. I’m hoping to meet lots of interesting people – maybe some of them will be useful for my future career. c. I have a target of twenty people that I want to meet, so I can persuade them to buy our products. On the first evening, you attend a ‘welcome party’. You arrive in a large hall filled with about 500 people. They all seem to be talking to each other in groups. There’s nobody that you recognise. What do you do? a. Go up to one of the groups, introduce yourself and ask if you can join them. b. Go up to one of the groups and listen to the conversation. Maybe you can join in later. c. Find where the food is being served and try to start a conversation with someone in the queue. d. Walk around the hall, pretending to be looking for someone. Avoid eye contact with other people. e. Turn around and go home. At the conference party, which of these problems would be worse for you? a. No-one wants to talk to you. b. A really boring person wants to talk to you … and you can’t escape from him/her. Where is the best place to stand if you want people to talk to you? a. In the middle of the hall. b. By the wall. c. Outside. d. By the buffet / bar. Which topics of conversation could you use to break the ice with someone? a. How much you hate...

Words: 1823 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

N/A Character Analysis

...straight to the point they care about… saving money, and it makes them want to put their hand up too. Anything that is going to save us 1000s, I’m good. I’m checking it out. I’m looking toward retirement. We got to save money. MA, OH Who doesn’t want to save money? Interesting. I would put my hand up….I want to save thousands. N/A, Nashville This is the best. Gets right to it. Easy to digest. Tells me what I want to know. IFP, Nashville Who doesn't want to save thousands on health. It’s not cheap. IFP Phoenix Time is very consuming and most people want to get straight to the point. Everything is now straight to the point. Pretty good pitch. Save thousands on health insurance. IFP, Birmingham Though some were skeptical, explaining...

Words: 884 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Religion

...05-19-10. Can Baptist agree on baptism for children? This question is what set some Christian apart when it comes to baptizing their kids at an early age. Because some of them reject baptizing kids at a young age, because children do not understand or know any better. Many nondenominational churches request that members get immerse in water no matter what your age is. While other accepts you as a member just because you had some water sprinkle on you when was a kid (Ken Camp, Baptist Standard Friday April 23, 2010).However, nearly all believers that have been baptize believe it is a no-soul saving power. But some believe baptism to be very vital in becoming a member of any church, so if this is true why such a big deal about children being dunk into some water to prove a point in the first place. Furthermore, many Christians pick a church base on the different programs that are offer like music, two services during Sunday, and of course whether kids are baptize at an early age. Because, some churches want to know before you even join are you or have you ever been baptize or not. Because denominations are losing their grip on member being baptize. Some people move from city to city looking for a church to call home. Wherever, people come from and what reason they are looking for a new home church. All people are looking for is a stable foundation and feeling a part of. Therefore some sociologists of religion think that, some people do not value...

Words: 768 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Personal Narrative Essay

...It happened in the gym, when I was in elementary school. My cheeks were flushed and warm from bouncing nonstop on the hop ball. I relaxed for a minute, and enjoyed the cool air conditioning that caressed my red face. I could almost hear the sizzling. I felt the handle of the hop ball that were gripped in my iron hands. Kids around me were unceasingly playing. Some were shooting hoops, while the rest, like me, were being goofballs and bouncing around, even racing on the hop balls, seeing who could go pass the red line at the end of the gym, first. I heard the joyous laughter that made me want to join in again, so I bounce high. When I came to the glistening gym floor, I felt a sharp pain in my lower back, but it receded as fast as it appeared....

Words: 570 - Pages: 3