Free Essay

Options Futures

In:

Submitted By austinfan
Words 4616
Pages 19
Random Walks
Charles N. Moore Department of Mathematics, Kansas State University Manhattan, KS 66506 U.S.A.

Abstract. We discuss the classical theorem of P´lya on random walks on the integer lattice in o Euclidean space. This is the starting point for much work that has been done on random walks in other settings. We mention a tiny fraction of this work, and discuss in detail “random walks” which can be created using trigonometric functions.

1

P´lya’s Theorem o

Consider the integers {. . . , −2, −1, 0, 1, 2, . . . }. Suppose you are standing at 0. Flip a coin. If the coin comes up heads, move to the right by one step. If it comes up tails, move to the left by one step. Flip the coin again. If it comes up heads, move a step to the right, if it comes up tails, move a step to the left. Repeat and continue this process. Must you come back to zero? Obviously, there is a very good chance of returning to zero: the first two flips could have been head then tail, or tail then head, and these both result in a return to zero. So of the four possible outcomes in the first two flips, half of these take you back to zero. So the probability of returning to zero is at least 1 2 . If you further consider that even if you fail to return to zero in two steps, that after some subsequent flips you might make it back to zero, then clearly the probability of returning to zero is greater than 1 . A natural question arises: 2 What is the probability of returning to zero? The answer was given by Georg P´lya [9] in 1921: o Theorem 1. With probability one, the random walker will return to zero in a finite number of steps. Let us show how to prove P´lya’s theorem. For n = 0, 1, 2, 3, . . . let un = o the probability that the random walker is at 0 after n steps. We make two Figure 1: Georg o simple observations: u0 = 1 (because the walker starts at 0) and un = 0 if P´lya n = 1, 3, 5, 7, . . . , that is, the walker cannot be at 0 after an odd number of steps. For n = 1, 2, 3, . . . , set fn = the probability that the walker returns to 0 for the first time at step n. Set f0 = 0 (being at 0 at step 0 isn’t really a return) and f =


fn . The probability that the

walker returns to 0 is f , the probability of not returning is 1 − f. We now decompose the event that the walker is at 0 at time n, n ≥ 1, into first returns, that is, if the walker is at 0 at time n, then the walker may be back there for the first time or may have

n=0

1

already visited there previously. This gives the relations: u1 = f 0 u1 + f 1 u0 u2 = f 0 u2 + f 1 u1 + f 2 u0 . . . un = f0 un + f1 un−1 + f2 un−2 + · · · + fk un−k + · · · + fn u0 . For example, in the expression for un , the term fk un−k represents the probability that the walker returned to 0 for the first time after k steps and then returned to 0 in n − k more steps. Set U (s) = u0 + u1 s + u2 s2 + . . . and Then U (s)F (s) = u0 f0 + (u0 f1 + u1 f0 )s + (f0 u2 + f1 u1 + f2 u0 )s2 + · · · = U (s) − 1. Lemma 1. If If
∞ n=0 ∞ n=0

F (s) = f0 + f1 s + f2 s2 + . . .

un = ∞ then the probability of returning to 0 is one.

un < ∞ then there is a positive probability of not returning to 0.
N

Proof. Notice that for any N , n=0 un ≤ lim U (s) so if s 1 ∞ n=0

∞ n=0

un = ∞, then lims s 1

1 U (s)

= ∞ and given

the relation U (s)(1 − F (s)) = 1 this forces f = On the other hand, if U (s)(1 − F (s)) = 1 forces
∞ n=0 ∞ n=0 s

fn = lim F (s) = 1.
∞ n=0

un < ∞, then lim U (s) =
1 s 1

un < ∞, which, due to the relation

fn = lim F (s) < 1.

∞ Thus, to determine if our walker returns, we need to compute n=0 un = ∞ u2n . (Recall n=0 un = 0 if n is odd.) If this sum is infinite, the walker returns with probability one, if the sum is finite, there is a positive probability of the walker not returning. Let’s compute u2n . In the first 2n steps, there are a total of 22n different routes which could be taken, each equally likely. How many of these come back to 0? This is a basic combinatorics question. Think of two urns, one labeled left and one labeled right. We want to distribute 2n balls, labeled 1, 2, 3, . . . , 2n (corresponding to the step number) into these two urns. There are 2n ways k to distribute k into one urn and 2n − k into the other; of interest here is the number of ways to put n balls into the urn labeled “left” and n into the urn labeled “right”. Any such distribution of balls corresponds to a route of length 2n which comes back to 0. Thus, there are 2n routes which n lead back to 0. Consequently,

u2n = To get an estimate of u2n we need

2n n 22n

2

Lemma 2. (Stirling’s formula; see e.g. Feller [7] ) As n → ∞, n! ≈ With this estimate, when n is large, u2n Therefore,
∞ n=0 u2n

√ 1 2πnn+ 2 e−n .

√ 1 1 (2n)! 1 2π(2n)2n+ 2 e−2n 1 ≈ √ =√ = n+ 1 −n 2 22n (n!)2 22n πn ( 2πn 2 e )

= ∞ so by Lemma 1, the walker returns with probability one.

2

Many possible directions

P´lya [9] also considered random walks in higher dimensions. Consider the integer lattice in two o dimensional Euclidean space, that is, consider those points with integer coordinates. Start at (0, 0), and toss two coins to determine whether to make a step to either (1, 0), (−1, 0), (0, 1) or (0, −1). Repeat, going one more step, either up, down, left or right, with equal probability. The same question can now be asked: What is the probability this walker returns to (0, 0)? An examination of the proof given in the previous section reveals that the analysis up through Lemma 1 was in no way dependent on the fact that walker was walking in one dimension; this fact only entered into the proof with the computation of u2n . With only slightly more complicated c combinatorics, and again using Stirling’s formula, one can compute that in dimension two, u 2n ≈ n , ∞ as n → ∞, for some constant c. Since then n=0 u2n = ∞, Lemma 1 implies that the walker returns with probability one. The situation changes in dimension three. Here, after some combinatorics and computation, it 3 turns out that u2n ≈ Cn− 2 so that by Lemma 1, there is a positive probability of the walker not returning to the origin. P´lya also showed that this is the case in any dimension greater than or o equal to three. A very drunken man staggers so as to simulate a random walk. Thus, P´lya’s theorem implies o that if he staggers out of a bar into a very narrow long alley, he will certainly return to the door of the bar. Similarly, if he finds himself in the middle of a large plaza, he will eventually stagger and return, with probability one, to the center of the plaza. Birds, however, should be cautioned against drunken behavior, as a drunken bird has a positive probability of not returning to the nest. The walks we’ve discussed above are called symmetric random walks because at each step, each of the possible directions to go was equally likely. Going back to dimension one, let’s consider the situation where we use a weighted coin to determine the direction of travel. This coin has probability p of turning up heads (so that the walker goes right) and probability 1 − p of turning up tails. To determine if a walker using this coin returns to 0, we reason as before and compute u2n . As before, a random walk returns to zero if there are as many steps to the left as to the right, so that u2n = pn (1 − p)n 2n . Here again we may use Stirling’s formula to obtain: n u2n = p (1 − n (2n)! p)n (n!)2

≈ p (1 − p)

n

n



2π(2n)2n+ 2 e−2n 1 = (4p(1 − p))n √ . √ 1 πn ( 2πnn+ 2 e−n )2

1

If p = 1 then 4p(1 − p) < 1, hence ∞ u2n < ∞ and by Lemma 1, there is a positive probability n=0 2 of the walker not returning to 0. In fact, 4p(1 − p) < 1 exactly when p = 1 and so ∞ u2n n=0 2 1 converges if and only if p = 2 . Thus, the walker returns to the origin with probability one if and only if p = 1 . This is not surprising– a gambler who continually plays a game with the odds against 2 him can expect to eventually lose his initial stake.

3

Other lattices may be considered. Our walker could start at the vertex of a hexagonal lattice in R2 . At each step there are three possible directions to go; we could consider a walk where each of these directions is equally likely (it can be shown the walker will return) or a walk where these are not. In fact, we could consider a walk on any lattice, regular or not, in Euclidean space, and ask the same questions. See P. G. Doyle and J. L. Snell [5] for a detailed study of random walks on lattices in Rn as well as an excellent exposition of the connection between random walks and the theory of electrical networks. Another possibility is to consider a sequence of identically distributed independent random variables X1 , X2 , X3 , . . . . Setting S1 = X1 , S2 = X1 + X2 , S3 = X1 + X2 + X3 , . . . we may ask about {Sn (ω)} for points ω in the underlying Figure 2: Hexagprobability space. Here the Xi may take on discrete values or may take values onal lattice in R. In the first case, this allows, say, for walks on an integer lattice in which the walker may jump several steps in a single move. In the case where the Xi take values in R the walker may never get back exactly to 0, but we can ask if he gets arbitrarily close. See K. L. Chung [4] for a treatment of random walks in this generality. Consider a group G with a subset S which generates G. Assume S has the property that s ∈ S implies s−1 ∈ S. The Cayley graph of G is constructed with vertices the elements of G and an edge from x to y if and only if there exists an element s ∈ S such that x = sy. Thus, the Cayley graph depends on G and the generating set S (which is not unique). A walker starts from a vertex of this graph, and at each stage, takes a step along an adjacent edge, chosen uniformly from among the adjacent edges with equal probability. What is the probability the walker returns to the starting point?

3

Return to P´lya’s theorem; trigonometric walks o

Consider the function f (x) = 1 −1 if x ∈ [0, 1 ) 2 if x ∈ [ 1 , 1) 2

Extend this to a 1-periodic function on the real line, and continue to call this extension f. Now consider the functions f (x), f (2x), f (4x), . . . , f (2n x), . . . , restrict these to the interval [0, 1) and call the resulting functions r1 (x), r2 (x), r3 (x), . . . , rn (x), . . . . These are called the Rademacher functions, after Hans Rademacher who introduced these in a paper in 1922. With the possible exception of x which are dyadic points, that is, points of the form x = 2jn , where n = 1, 2, 3, . . . , j ∈ {0, 1, . . . , 2n } we may write rn (x) = sgn(sin(2n πx)) where sgn is defined as sgn(x) = 1 if x ≥ 0 and sgn(x) = −1 if x < 0. (The set of dyadic points is countable, hence of measure zero, and therefore negligible for our purposes. So we could define the rn either way and obtain the same results.) Set s0 (x) = 0, s1 (x) = r1 (x), s2 (x) = r1 (x) + r2 (x), s3 (x) = r1 (x) + r2 (x) + r3 (x), etc. 1 Take x ∈ [0, 1). If x ∈ [0, 1 ) then s1 (x) = 1, if x ∈ [ 2 , 1), then s1 (x) = −1. So for half the 2 x s in [0, 1), s1 (x) takes the value 1, and for half it takes the value −1. Now if x ∈ [0, 1 ), then 4 1 1 s2 (x) = r1 (x)+r2 (x) = 1+1 = 2; if x ∈ [ 4 , 2 ) then s2 (x) = r1 (x)+r2 (x) = 1+−1 = 0; if x ∈ [ 1 , 3 ), 2 4 then s2 (x) = r1 (x) + r2 (x) = −1 + 1 = 0; if x ∈ [ 3 , 1) then s2 (x) = r1 (x) + r2 (x) = −1 + −1 = −2. 4 Each of these four cases, occurring on exactly one-fourth of the unit interval, corresponds to the first two steps of a random walk. Continuing in this way, we have created a model of P´lya’s random o walk on the integers: There is a 1-1 correspondence between {x ∈ [0, 1)| x is not of the form 2jn } 4

and the set of random walks, where x corresponds to the random walk {s n (x)}∞ . In fact, if you n=1 express such an x ∈ [0, 1) in binary and change all the 1 s in the binary representation to −1 s and all the 0 s to 1 s, then sn (x) is just the sum of the first n digits of this string of −1 s and 1 s.
1
1
1

0.5

0.5

0.5

0

0

0

0.25

0.5

0.75

1
-0.5

0

0.25

0.5

0.75

1

0

0

0.25

0.5

0.75

1

-0.5

-0.5

-1

-1

-1

Figure 3: The functions r1 (x), r2 (x) and r3 (x). Thinking in this way, we can rephrase P´lya’s theorem: o Theorem 2. For a.e. x ∈ [0, 1), the sequence sn (x), n = 1, 2, 3, . . . returns to 0 in a finite number of steps. Actually, a little more can be said. Given any integer m, it can be shown that with probability one, the walker will land on m in a finite number of steps. Thinking now of m as a starting point, then with probability one, the walker will return to this position in a finite number of steps. Once the walker has returned, there is no memory of the past, so now the situation is as if the walker is starting for the first time. So with probability one, the walker returns again to m. This continues and consequently, we may conclude: Theorem 3. For a.e. x ∈ [0, 1), the sequence sn (x), n = 1, 2, 3, . . . visits every integer an infinite number of times. Now consider the interval [−π, π] and the functions sin(x), sin(2x), sin(4x), . . . , sin(2 n x), . . . and the sums s1 (x) = sin(x), s2 (x) = sin(x) + sin(2x), s3 (x) = sin(x) + sin(2x) + sin(4x), . . . , n sn (x) = j=1 sin(2j−1 x), . . . .
1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1

-3.14

-1.57

0

1.57

3.14

-3.14

-1.57

0

1.57

3.14

-3.14

-1.57

0

1.57

3.14

Figure 4: The functions sin(x), sin(2x), and sin(4x) on [−π, π]. Given the resemblance of each of the functions sin(2n x) to rn (x), it seems natural to investigate the “random walks” {sn (x)}∞ for x ∈ [−π, π]. Here of course, sums of the rn (x) will always be n=1 integer valued, whereas sums of the sin(2n x) certainly are not. And certainly, for any fixed x, the sequence {sn (x)} is countable, so it could not visit every element in an uncountable set such as the real numbers. The correct analogue to Theorem 3 is that it visits every neighborhood of every point an infinite number of times, or what is equivalent, the sequence {sn (x)} is dense in R. In fact, we can be a little more general: 5

Theorem 4. (Grubb and Moore [8].) Let n sn (x) = j=1 aj sin(nj x + θj )

where the aj , θj , are real, |aj | ≤ 1 for every j and the nj are positive integers which satisfy nj+1 |aj |2 = ∞. Then for a.e. x ∈ [−π, π], {sn (x)} is dense in R. nj ≥ λ > 1. Suppose also that It is easy to verify that the sequence s1 (x) = sin(x), s2 (x) = sin(x) + sin(2x), . . . discussed above satisfies the hypotheses of this theorem. Note that we must have |aj |2 = ∞; otherwise, the sequence of functions {sn (x)} converges in L2 and couldn’t satisfy the conclusion. Previously, D. Ullrich [14] had shown this result under the assumption that |aj | = 1 for every j and the proof of Theorem 4 (which we describe below) borrows many ideas from his work. Series of the form ∞ aj z nj where nj+1 /nj ≥ λ > 1, or their real counterparts such as in j=0 Theorem 4, are called lacunary series, gap series, or often Hadamard series. They arise in the study j of analytic continuation: for example, the series ∞ z 2 represents an analytic function on the j=0 unit disk which cannot be extended to an analytic function on any larger domain. They are also of interest due to the fact, evidenced by this theorem among many others, that the partial sums n nj behave like sums of independent random variables (which they are not). In particular, j=0 aj z we mention here the central limit theorems for lacunary trigonometric series of R. Salem and A. Zygmund [11], the central limit theorem of P. Erd¨s and I. S. G´l [6] and the laws of the iterated o a logarithm of Salem and Zygmund [12] and M. Weiss [15]. The proof of Theorem 4 is not difficult. A theorem due to Zygmund [16], vol. 1, p. 205 shows that the set of x where the sequence {sn (x)} is bounded above or below is of measure zero. Thus, fixing an α ∈ R and an x at which {sn (x)} bounded neither above nor below, then for an infinite number of n (which depend on x) we must have sn (x) on one side of the real number α and sn+1 (x) on the other; that is, in the real line the sequence sn (x) crosses α an infinite number of times. With a little more work it can then be shown that sn (x) must visit any neighborhood of α an infinite number of times. See [8] for details. What about such “trigonometric random walks” in higher dimensions? In analogy to P´lya’s o theorem in two dimensions, we could consider n sn (θ) = k=1 ak eink θ

nk+1 ≥ λ > 1, ak ∈ C, and θ ∈ R. (If each nk is an integer, each sn (θ) is 2πnk periodic, so it suffices to consider θ ∈ [−π, π].) Fix a θ. Each term, ak eink θ can be thought of as a vector, so that s1 (θ) = a1 ein1 θ represents one step of a random walk in C, s2 (x) = a1 ein1 θ + a2 ein2 θ represents two steps of a random walk, etc. Two important results concerning such random walks are due to J.M. Anderson and L. Pitt [1], [2]. To discuss these we make some definitions. Let ε > 0 be fixed, θ ∈ R and suppose that for each z∈C lim inf |sn (θ) − z| ≤ ε. where, as above, n→∞ In this case we say {sn (θ)} is ε-recurrent. If {sn (θ)} is ε-recurrent for almost all θ then we say {sn } is ε-recurrent. If {sn } is ε-recurrent for each ε > 0 we say that {sn } is recurrent.

6

Theorem 5. (Anderson and Pitt [1].) Suppose {λk }∞ is a sequence of positive numbers such that 1 λk+1 ∞ is a sequence of complex numbers satisfying {a } ≥ q > 1 for all k. Suppose {ak }k=1 k ∞ ≡ λk n 2q ∞ ak eiλk θ . Then for ε ≥ {ak } ∞ the sesupk |ak | < ∞ and k=1 |ak |2 = ∞. Set sn (θ) = q−1 k=1 quence {sn } is ε-recurrent. The proof uses tools from complex analysis. For certain types of sums, more can be said: n Theorem 6. (Anderson and Pitt [2].) Let sn (θ) = is recurrent. k=1 eia



where a ≥ 2 is an integer. Then {sn }

The proof of this is difficult and requires complex analysis, probability and number theory. None of the theorems 4, 5, 6 can be shown to be best possible, most likely because they probably are not the best possible. In [3] J. Bretagnolle and D. Dacunha-Castelle present an extensive study of random walks created from sums of independent random variables. Consider partial sums n sn (ω) = k=1 ak Xk (ω) where the Xk are real-valued independent identically distributed mean zero random variables. The hypotheses of their results are too numerous to mention explicitly, but they make several assumptions on the distribution of Xk and several technical assumptions of the 1 n 2 2 → ∞, they show recurrence occurs ak . Then, under these assumptions, and if σn = k=1 ak precisely when ∞ σ1 = ∞. (Of course, one needs to be precise about what recurrence means n=1 n here: if the Xk are integer valued and the ak are integers, then recurrence could only occur in the integers; if the Xk are real valued then recurrence could be in the reals or in some other subgroup of the reals.) Here’s a very rough sketch of the proof: By using the central limit theorem, they c obtain the estimate Prob(sn ∈ I) = σI + o( σ1 ), where I ⊂ R is any interval, and cI is a constant n n depending only on I. The proof is completed by the Borel-Cantelli lemma (actually variations of this) and other fairly standard techniques. Reasoning in this way gives an idea as to what the correct version of Theorems 4, 5 and 6 should be in the trigonometric case, but it won’t give us a proof. Sequences of functions such as {sin(2k x)} or {eiλk θ } are not independent random variables, yet as amply illustrated by many theorems, they do behave much like sequences of random variables. Consider, for example, series of
1 the form sn (θ) = n ak sin(2k−1 θ), where the ak are real. Set σn = 2 n a2 2 and suppose k=1 k=1 k σn that an = o( log log σn ) as n → ∞. Under these hypotheses the central limit theorem for lacunary s trigonometric series of Salem and Zygmund [11] states that the distribution function of σn tends n to that of a Gaussian with mean zero and variance one. That is, as n → ∞,
1

m {θ ∈ [−π, π] :

sn (θ) < λ} σn

1 →√ 2π

λ

e
−∞

−t2 2

dt,
2

where m denotes the probability measure dθ/2π on [−π, π].
2ε √ . 2π s So by this central limit theorem, if ε > 0, and n is large, then Prob(| σn | < ε) ≈ n

Replace ε in this last equation by

ε σn

√1 2π

ε −t 2 ε e

- this is, of course, quite incorrect, as the choice of n

dt ≈

large depends on ε. Assuming such a step were correct, we would obtain Prob(|s n | < ε) ≈ which is analogous to the estimate of Bretagnolle and Dacunha-Castelle above. Then, 2ε Prob (|sn | < ε) ≈ √ 2π n=1 7
∞ ∞ n=1

√2 ε , 2π σn

1 , σn

so that if ∞ σ1 < ∞, then the so-called easy half of the Borel-Cantelli lemma (see e.g. Feller [7], n=1 n Volume 1, Chapter VIII, section 3) implies that for a.e. x eventually |sn | > ε, so that recurrence doesn’t occur in any neighborhood of 0. Similar reasoning could then be used to show that recurrence doesn’t occur at any point of R. If, in addition, the functions sin(2k x) were independent (which is another false assumption) then the Borel-Cantelli lemma (the so-called harder half) would imply that if ∞ σ1 = ∞ then a.e. x is in an infinite number of the sets {|sn | < ε}, that is, recurrence n=1 n occurs at 0. Again, similar reasoning could be applied to show that there is recurrence at any point of R. Of course, this is all specious reasoning, but yet it seems to lead to some central issues, and gives an indication what conjectures to pose. So in the case of trigonometric random walks, there is still much work to be done. Thus, despite the fact there are already thousands of papers and dozens of books written on random walks, there are still many directions left to go.

References
[1] Anderson, J. M., and Pitt, Loren D., On recurrence properties of certain lacunary series. I. General results., J. Reine Angew. Math. 377 (1987), 65–82. [2] Anderson J. M. and Pitt, L. D., On recurrence properties of certain lacunary series. II. The series n exp(iak θ), J. Reine Angew. Math. 377 (1987), 83–96. k=1 [3] Bretagnolle, Jean, and Dacunha-Castelle, Didier, Th´or´mes limites a distance finie pour e e ´ les marches al´atoires, Ann. Inst. H. Poincar´ (1968), 25-73. e e [4] Chung, Kai, Lai, A Course in Probability Theory, Academic Press, New York, 1974. [5] Doyle, Peter G., and Snell, J. Laurie, Random walks and electric networks, Carus Mathematical Monographs, 22, Mathematical Association of America, Washington, DC, 1984. [6] Erd¨s, P., and G´l, I.S., On the law of the iterated logarithm, I,II, Nederl. Akad. Wetensch. o a Proc. Ser. A 58 (1955), 65-84. [7] Feller, William, An Introduction to Probability Theory and Its Applications, Volumes I and II, John Wiley and Sons, New York, 1950, 1966. [8] Grubb, D. J., and Moore, Charles N., Certain lacunary cosine series are recurrent, Studia Math. 108 (1994), no. 1, 21–23. ¨ [9] P´lya, Georg, Uber eine Aufgabe der Wahrscheinlichkeitsrechnung betreffend die Irrfahrt o im Strassennetz, Math. Ann. 84, 149-160, 1921. [10] Rudnick, Joseph, and Gaspari, George, Elements of the Random Walk, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2004. [11] Salem, R. and Zygmund, A., On lacunary trigonometric series, Proc. N.A.S. 33 (1947), 333-338. [12] Salem, R., and Zygmund A., La loi du logarithme it´r´ pour les s´ries trigonom´triques e e e e lacunaire, Bull. Sci. Math. 74 (1950), 209-224. [13] Spitzer, Frank, Principles of Random Walk, Second Edition, Springer-Verlag, New York, 1976. 8

[14] Ullrich, David C., Recurrence for lacunary cosine series, The Madison Symposium on Complex Analysis, Contemporary Math. 137 (1992), 459-467. [15] Weiss, Mary, The law of the iterated logarithm for lacunary series, Trans. Amer. Math. Soc. 91 (1959), 444-469. [16] Zygmund, Antoni, Trigonometric Series, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1959. email address: cnmoore@math.ksu.edu

9

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Futures and Options

...| Futures & Options Report | | | | | | a) Our portfolio consists of five stocks, one put option and one futures contract. The five stocks we have are Exxon Mobil (XOM), Johnson & Johnson (JNJ), Google (GOOG), Ford (F), and Amazon (AMZN). These stocks are all traded on the NASDAQ stock market. We have purchased ten shares of each of the five stocks below. Below is a graph with shows when we purchased the stocks and how much it cost at that time.   | Stock P | Date | Time | AMZN | $179.97 | 3/5/2012 | 1:28pm | XOM | $86.67 | 3/5/2012 | 1:29pm | GOOG | $614.70 | 3/5/2012 | 1:28pm | F | $12.48 | 3/5/2012 | 1:29pm | JNJ | $64.67 | 3/5/2012 | 1:28pm | The table below now shows the results of how the stock performed from 3/5/12 to 3/16/12: We will discuss some stock analysis and the gain/loss later in this report.   | Current | Date | Time | AMZN | 185.05 | 3/16/2012 | 1:28pm | XOM | 86.44 | 3/16/2012 | 1:29pm | GOOG | 625.4 | 3/16/2012 | 1:28pm | F | $12.51 | 3/16/2012 | 1:29pm | JNJ | $65.12 | 3/16/2012 | 1:28pm | Other than having five stocks, we have a put option for Procter & Gamble and a futures contract of Gold. b) Analyzing the futures contract of gold we bought at the beginning, March 2, 2012, it closed at $1,698 which meant our initial value was at $10,125 with a margin call at $7500. If it drops below that price then we would have to borrow money to bring it back up to the initial margin. On March 3...

Words: 2652 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Options, Futures and Swaps

...Future, Option and Swap are three types of stocks bought and sold in the stock market. Future means trading an instrument in the future, options give buyers the right to trade security in future and swaps are derivatives where two parties agree to exchange one stream of cash flow with another. Future Trading The future trading consists of trading of futures where the future contracts are traded on the futures exchange. The trading of future contracts or normally termed, futures involves buying or selling of some underlying instruments sometime in the future where the future date is called the final settlement date or delivery date and the pre-set price is referred to as the futures price. The price set on the underlying asset at the day of delivery date is called settlement price in futures trading. Option Trading Options are basically the financial instruments that give the buyers the right to buy or sell the underlying security within a point of time in the future for a price, which is fixed at the time when the option is bought. The stock option buyers are called the holders and sellers are called writers in option trading terminology. The ‘call’ in option trading gives the owner of option a right but not an obligation to buy an underlying security within the specified time while the ‘put’ gives the owner a right but not the obligation to sell the underlying asset within the specified time at a pre-fixed price. The value of a stock option contract is determined by...

Words: 436 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Options, Futures and Risk Management

...BFF9515 Options, Futures and Risk management Group assignment Semester 1, 2014 Due date: 16.05.2014 BFF5915 Group Assignment Part 1 1. Compute Beta * Method: First, compute the returns of each stocks and the return of the index. They can be calculated using excel with the formula: (current price / the previous price) – 1, Second, use covariance and variance function in excel to calculate the beta of each stock. Third, multiply each beta with the corresponding weight to calculate the portfolio beta. * The beta for each stocks and the beta for portfolio (see table 1.1) Details can be seen in sheet “EquityReturnData” in the data file “Data.xlsx”. Table 1.1 The Beta(s) of Stocks and Portfolio Name | Code | Weight | Beta | CROWN RESORTS | 51333T(RI) | 7.25% | 0.8039 | COMMONWEALTH BK.OF AUS. | 314054(RI) | 7.26% | 0.8950 | NATIONAL AUS.BANK | 901842(RI) | 3.74% | 1.1317 | COCHLEAR | 871051(RI) | 3.96% | 0.8402 | WESTFIELD GROUP | 912307(RI) | 2.56% | 0.7096 | TELSTRA | 871685(RI) | 4.60% | 0.5050 | MACQUARIE GROUP | 865438(RI) | 4.36% | 1.4238 | INVOCARE | 28047X(RI) | 3.87% | 0.7210 | FLIGHT CENTRE TRAVEL GP. | 871048(RI) | 4.28% | 1.0063 | CSL | 131775(RI) | 4.89% | 0.6488 | SLATER & GORDON | 50509L(RI) | 4.79% | 0.3001 | JB HI-FI | 27736M(RI) | 4.50% | 0.8261 | CARSALES.COM | 67967W(RI) | 4.54% | 0.8459 | WOOLWORTHS | 322714(RI) | 4.86% | 0.5500 | FORTESCUE METALS GP. | 314160(RI) | 7.15% | 1.8687 | The Portfolio...

Words: 2147 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Finance Futures and Options

...FIN425 Futures Project 2 In regards to price of the futures contracts over time, both the contracts we chose seemed to fluctuate between positive and negative price changes. The crude oil contract changed at a smaller ratio compared to the e-mini. As with the price of the futures contract, the price of the underlying assets changed at a similar rate. However, because of the dates we chose, the crude oil underlying asset increased at every interval. The underlying asset for the S&P 500 did not. The basis for the crude oil future is increasing at the end of the interval. This is a negative indicator because we are selling this future. The basis for the e-mini is a negative number that is fluctuating. The negative number is a positive indicator in this case because we are buying this contract. The margin account balance for E-mini S&P 500 future was $26,300. That was found by multiplying the initial maintenance fee of $5,060 by the number of E-mini contracts purchased, which is 5. The account balance experienced rise and fall trends, with four separate occasions that required a margin call in order to keep our maintenance margin above $23,000 ($4,600 marginal maintenance per contract times five contracts). We had to invest an additional $2.8 million in order to meet our margins. The Crude oil futures margin account balance began at $38,500, found by multiply the initial maintenance $3,850 per contract, and we signed on for 10 contracts of the crude oil futures. As for...

Words: 352 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Futures and Options

...Sources of Short-term Finance And Its Comparative Analysis There are a number of sources of short-term finance which are listed below: 1. Trade credit 2. Bank credit – Loans and advances – Cash credit – Overdraft – Discounting of bills 3. Customers’ advances 4. Installment credit 5. Loans from co-operatives ------------------------------------------------- 1 . Trade Credit Trade credit refers to credit granted to manufactures and traders by the Suppliers of raw material, finished goods, components, etc. Usually business enterprises buy supplies on a 30 to 90 days credit. This means that the goods are delivered but payments are not made until the expiry of period of credit. This type of credit does not make the funds available in cash but it facilitates purchases without making immediate payment. This is quite a popular source of finance. ------------------------------------------------- 2 . Bank Credit Commercial banks grant short-term finance to business firms which is known as bank credit. When bank credit is granted, the borrower gets a right to draw the amount of credit at one time or in instalments as and when needed. Bank credit may be granted by way of loans, cash credit, overdraft and discounted bills. ( i ) Loans When a certain amount is advanced by a bank repayable after a specified period, it is known as bank loan. Such advance is credited to a separate loan account and the borrower has to pay interest on the whole amount of loan irrespective of...

Words: 3045 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

The Future Options Fair Case Study

...very comfortable and familiar with being in leadership positions and providing community service. Therefore, an opportunity such as the Honors Leadership Development Scholarship is exactly what I have been searching for. In the past, I have participated in a plethora of leadership and community service activities, such as volunteering at Mercy Hospital, Villari’s Self Defense, and with the Cumberland County Sheriff’s Office. However, I would like to highlight two instances of being in leadership positions, which accentuate my energy, passion, and drive. These involvements were with my high school’s Future Options Fair committee and with my high school’s chapter of the National Honor Society....

Words: 557 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Outline Future Options for Melbourne’s Water Resource

...Outline future options for Melbourne’s water resource Abstract Melbourne’s water reserves in the past 10 years have been exhausted; meanwhile climate change predictions indicate the pressure of water lack will be increasingly serious (Howe et.al 2005). This problem is not just for Melbourne, Australia and many other parts of the world also face to the water shortage problem. Since there is a grave water shortage in Melbourne, the policy of sustainable water management is becoming very important. In order to prevent further deterioration of water shortage in the future, the Victorian Government made a series of countermeasures. There are several projects to solve the scarcity of water problem in the future and work out Melbourne’s future water supply needs, such as water restriction in Melbourne; spending nearly 2 billion dollars to build one of the world’s biggest water desalination plants at South Melbourne; building catchment to collect and feed rain into eight of Melbourne’s reservoirs and protecting the water catchment area; establishing two large sewage treatment plants in east and west Melbourne. The other countries also did a lot to protect water resource such as Singapore used nearly half of the national area to build water reservoir; Moscow had developed high technology for Sewage treatment system. The Victorian Government dedicated in long-term water management to protect water security and in responding to Victoria's...

Words: 1948 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Solution to Chap 20

...------------------------------------------------- Chapter 20 Decision Trees, Real Options, and Other Capital Budgeting Topics ------------------------------------------------- ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 20-1 a. Real options occur when managers can influence the size and risk of a project’s cash flows by taking different actions during the project’s life. They are referred to as real options because they deal with real as opposed to financial assets. They are also called managerial options because they give opportunities to managers to respond to changing market conditions. Sometimes they are called strategic options because they often deal with strategic issues. Finally, they are also called embedded options because they are a part of another project. b. Investment timing options give companies the option to delay a project rather than implement it immediately. This option to wait allows a company to reduce the uncertainty of market conditions before it decides to implement the project. Growth options allow a company to expand if market demand is higher than expected. This includes the opportunity to expand into different geographic markets and the opportunity to introduce complementary or second-generation products. It also includes the option (an abandonment option) to abandon a project if market conditions deteriorate too much. Flexibility options allow a company to have flexibility in their operations, such as the flexibility...

Words: 5210 - Pages: 21

Premium Essay

Best Financial Inc.

...to the critical issue. keep asking why. 2) Increase services available so Best can increase clients and retain current clients, and 3 )Have the ability to increase number of client load to ensure growth of company. Analysis In order for a business to meet goals and reach targets, it needs to have a business plan in place which clearly outlines what they are. Best has no business plan, because the owner has not had time to create one. This is a critical issue, because although employees of Best may be working very hard, they need to have goals in mind and measurable targets that they can achieve in order to stay current and adapt and grow with the industry changes. The financial planning industry is expected to grow in the near future, and in order to deal with the baby boomers retiring and taking their money out of investments, as outlined in the Exhibit 2, SWOT Analysis, there needs to be plan to ensure that the business can continue on once their target audience moves towards retirement. At the loss of one major client, Best is facing serious repercussions. It was heavily reliant on a In order to make your service argument convincing, I would point, any a competitive few largely invest clients to...

Words: 2260 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Kataby

...Explain how the option pricing formula developed by black and scholes can be used for common stock and bond valuation. Include in your discussion the consequences of using variance applied over the option instead of actual variance. Its generally known that Black and Scholes model became a standard in option pricing methods , with almost everything from corporate liabilities and debt instruments can be viewed as option (except some complicated instruments), we can modify the fundamental formula in order to fit the specifications of the instrument that will be valued. An argument done by Black and Scholes which was based on the past proposition of Miller and Modigliani a well as assuming some ideal conditions, States that value of the firm is a sum of total value of debt plus the total value of common stock. As well as the fact that in the absence of taxes, the value of the firm is independent of its leverage and the change of debt has no effect on the firm value. V = E + Dm V: value of the firm. E: shareholders right (common stock values). Dm: market value of the debt. As the above equation impose that Equity (common stock values) can be viewed as a call option on the firm value (due to the shareholders limited liability and with consideration that firm debt can be represent as a zero-coupon bond), where exercising the option means that equity holders buy the firm at the face value of debt (which is in this case will be the exercise price of the option), on the liquidation...

Words: 1396 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Real Options

...Options Theory Applied to Alternative Energy Industry Christina Clowdus Bus: 630 March 20, 2012 Dr. Shaw Introduction In life, you always have options. It is no different in capital investment. In today's unpredictable business world, managers recognize how risky the most valuable investment opportunities often are, and how useful a flexible strategy can be. That's why they want to know all their options. Yet many current financial assessment tools fail to identify what investors can do to capitalize on future uncertain events. “Managerial flexibility to adapt and revise future decisions in order to capitalize on favorable future opportunities or to limit losses has proven vital to long-term corporate success in an uncertain and changing marketplace” (Brennan, M.J. and E.S. Schwartz 1985, p. 15). Utilizing a real options strategy allows businesses to capture the value of managerial flexibility in adapting decisions in response to unexpected market developments. When used as a conceptual tool, real options allow management to characterize and communicate the strategic value of an investment project (Bjerksund, P. and S. Ekern 1990). Traditional methods (e.g. net present value, discounted cash flow) fail to accurately capture the economic value of investments in an environment of widespread uncertainty and rapid change. Using real options theory, managers can more effectively target crucial opportunities to redeploy, delay, modify, or even abandon capital-intensive projects...

Words: 2529 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Finc 5000

...Question #1: A “real option” is a choice that becomes available with a business investment opportunity. Real options can include opportunities to expand and cease projects if certain conditions arise. They are referred to as "real" because they usually pertain to tangible assets such as capital equipment, rather than financial instruments. Real options differ from financial options in that with financial options usually an underlying asset such as a stock is traded. Taking into account real options can greatly affect the valuation of potential investments. It does not obligate the owner to take any action, it just gives the right to buy or sell an asset. Examples of real options include developing new products expanding an existing product line, entry to a new geographical area as well as abandoning certain operations. There are several tools and techniques that are available for managers to analyze the profitability of a project. There is the discounted cash flows method which would ignore the option and calculate the net present value. There is a qualitative assessment that shows the value of the option increases is the project is risky or there is a long time that is needed to wait before exercising the option. The decision tree analysis is a tree like model that shows probable outcomes of the different decisions. Using the existing model for corresponding financial options, this resembles a financial call option. It is basically a call option with an expiration date ...

Words: 1427 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Stock Trac

...David Rossi & Dhiraj Thakker Investments – Professor Flaherty Stock- Trak Portfolio Report The stock trak game was a great opportunity to gain first-hand experience with making trades in the stock market. The experience we gained through the game gave us the ability to manage large sums of money, giving us the opportunity to recognize the importance of preparing and utilizing portfolios in the career development process, to be aware of the component parts that make your portfolio effective, and to understand how to compile and present your portfolio in a professional manner. The initial round of investments to our portfolio was comprised of seven domestic stocks. The main goal was to acquire stable, well-known companies that would pose low risk. These stocks were selected with minimal analysis due to their market capitalizations and the associated company’s reputations. We selected several Blue chip stocks, because they appeared to match our goals of stability and minimizing risk. Since these companies are very large, well established corporations, we understood that the possibility of significant growth in equity is unlikely due to the established maturity of the companies. For this reason, we did not expect to earn our largest return in this area of our portfolio, but instead we were hoping for small growth, while collecting dividends. The first stock purchased was Microsoft (MSFT). Microsoft is a large cap computer software...

Words: 3952 - Pages: 16

Premium Essay

Arundel Case

...Assignment 10 1. Read and study “Introduction to Real Options” 2. Read and study CH 17 from McDonald: “Real Options” 3. Read and study CH33 from Hull: “Real Options” 4. Case: Arundel Partners: The Sequel Project Answer the following questions: a. What makes Arundel think it can make money by buying a package of sequel rights? Is the profit opportunity, if it exists, likely to be sustainable? Arundel can make money selling the rights to a higher bid. Another option to make money is by producing the sequel exercising its rights but this will depend on if the net present value of the production movies is higher than the amount of buying the rights. If the future positive cashflows are undervalued Arundel can seek an arbitrage opportunity and buy the rights at the market price. b. Why would the studios be interested in raising money in this fashion? Why not raise the money in more traditional ways? The studio can not raise money in a traditional way because they don´t know when the movie will be popular o not so they don’t have regular cashflows. They also think that the business of movies production can be profitable by selling sequel rights ( this can be perform as an option). If a movie performs with positive cashflows they can invest in the movie production and have profits. The risk here is lower because they don´t have the same risk than the traditional ways of raise money like an asset. c. Why should Arundel pay anything for the sequel rights? The...

Words: 700 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Financial

...Chapter 01 The Investment Environment 1. The material wealth of a society is a function of A. all financial assets. B. all real assets. C. all financial and real assets. D. all physical assets. 2. _______ are real assets. A. Land B. Machines C. Stocks and bonds D. Knowledge E. Land, machines, and knowledge 3. The means by which individuals hold their claims on real assets in a well-developed economy are A. investment assets. B. depository assets. C. derivative assets. D. financial assets. E. exchange-driven assets. 4. _______ are financial assets. A. Bonds B. Machines C. Stocks D. Bonds and stocks E. Bonds, machines, and stocks 5. _________ financial asset(s). A. Buildings are B. Land is a C. Derivatives are D. U.S. agency bonds are E. Derivatives and U.S. agency bonds are 6. Financial assets A. directly contribute to the country's productive capacity. B. indirectly contribute to the country's productive capacity. C. contribute to the country's productive capacity both directly and indirectly. D. do not contribute to the country's productive capacity either directly or indirectly. E. are of no value to anyone. 7. In 2012, ____________ was the most significant real asset of U.S. households in terms of total value. A. consumer durables B. automobiles C. real estate D. mutual fund shares E. bank loans 8. In 2012, ____________ was the least significant financial asset of U.S. households...

Words: 2136 - Pages: 9