Free Essay

The Tragedy of the Commons

In:

Submitted By stefyb14
Words 3295
Pages 14
Introduction
All over the world, the newspapers announce almost weekly a story about the threatened destruction of a valuable natural resource. In June of 1989, for example, a New York Times article focused on the problem of overfishing in the Georges Bank about 150 miles off the New England coast. The population of fish is now only a quarter of what it was during the 1960s. Although everyone knows what the problem is, those concerned cannot agree towards a solution. The main problem in this case -and in many others- is how best to limit the use of natural resources so as to ensure their long-term economic viability. Some people recommend that the state control most natural resources to prevent their destruction and overuse; others recommend that privatizing those resources will solve the problem. The reality is not that simple; the logic of the tragedy of the commons depends on a set of assumptions about human motivation, about the rules of governing the use of the commons, and about the character of the common resource. According to Elinor Ostrom, “neither the state nor the market is uniformly successful in enabling individuals to sustain long-term, productive use of natural resource systems”. This means that there isn’t just “one way” to solve problems concerning common resources. Aristotle observed that “what is common to the greatest number has the least care bestowed upon it. Everyone thinks chiefly of his own, hardly at all of the common interest”. The purpose of this paper is to present what the tragedy of the commons is and the approach of the study of self-governance; also, to give an overview of the commons in modern life.

The Tragedy of the Commons Professor Garret Hardin developed this idea in a well-known essay “The Tragedy of the Commons” (1968). He argued that commonly owned and freely accessible resources tend to become depleted when or if the population exploiting the resources is large enough; for example, a common grazing area that is made available for use to numerous ranchers will be overgrazed and its replenishment neglected. The tragedy of the commons occurs mainly because people pursue their goals with the means available to them; this idea has been most frequently and fruitfully applied to environmental concerns. Communal resources are available to everyone, so everyone has an economic incentive to use them, but no one has an equal incentive to husband the resources. Public realms, such as the atmosphere or ocean waters, have seen considerable overuse at the hands of various private parties. In democratic societies, the disposition of resources depends on the degree of concern for the resources or for the uses to which they can be put. There have been various suggestions to explain why the “commons remorselessly generates tragedy”. One frequently mentioned reason is human greed: beings will always take advantage of free resources beyond what would be wise and prudent. Yet, it is not necessary to posit greed or self-interest in order to understand the tragedy of the commons. It’s merely to understand that people tend to be dedicated to their various projects. As James E. Chesher puts it: “If an artist, scientist, merchant, or farmer is given the authority to make use of materials that supposedly all are entitled to use, it will by no means be necessary for such a person to be needlessly and even recklessly eager to gain wealth or other benefits in order to exploit them to the fullest possible extent”. What the real tragedy is about
The problem of the commons is not that people use the resources to which they have access, but that within that realm, there is no appropriate regulatory or coordinating mechanism that enables appropriate husbanding or maintenance of those resources. Nevertheless, there is a paradox concerning that individually rational strategies lead to collectively irrational outcomes. This premise seems to challenge a fundamental faith that rational human beings can achieve rational results. But, can we generalize over human behavior concerning collective action? The truth is that not only humans, but every-day situations are subject to unpredictable verdicts. Human action is an amalgam of different choices and decisions that lead to very different results; therefore, there can’t be a generalized rule or a unique way to solve the problems concerning common pool resources, for example. The tragedy of the Commons, like the prisoner’s dilemma and the logic of collective action, are closely related concepts in the models that have defined the accepted way of viewing many problems that individuals face when attempting to achieve collective benefits. The common denominator in these situations is free riding. Whenever a person cannot be excluded from the benefits that others provide, each person has an incentive not to contribute to the joint effort, but to free-ride on the efforts of others. The free-rider problem leads to a less than optimal level of provision of the collective benefit. Garret Hardin’s Tragedy of the Commons is intended to be an understandable problem and is framed in terms of the rationality of the agents and a more or less utilitarian assessment of the overall good. To mention an example, each herdsman asks him or herself: ʺWhat is the utility to me of adding one more animal to my herd? ʺ Under the assumption that the pasture provided by the village of the Commons is free, and each additional animal can be obtained at a cost that, together with labor and minor supply costs, is well below what the animal can later be sold for, it is clear that it is rational for the herdsman to add an animal. Afterwards, this reasoning is duplicated by others herdsman, eventually making all the herdsmen far worse off than they would be with relatively small herds. According to Tibor R. Machan in his book The Commons: Its Tragedies and other Follies (Ibid, p. 35), it is clear that for Hardin, the tragedy consists of individuals pursuing what is rational for each, only to have their separate and collective well-being greatly diminished by the fact of everyone’s pursuing this ʺrationalʺ strategy. Following this train of thought, the Tragedy of the Commons appears to be just an instance of the Prisoners Dilemma. Traditional solutions to the tragedy Generally, there are two different solutions to the Tragedy of the Commons. One is regulating, and the other is privatizing. The first option typically leads to state ownership, while the second tends to equalize mixed private-public condition that gives rise to the dilemma. However, many authors propose a third way which consists in the possibility that the herdsmen themselves will begin to cooperate. This could be trough agreements or arrangements grounded in clear, well-established property rights. Personally, I believe that just as some people attribute greed to human actions, cooperation is an almost inherent force that drives human beings to a better state. Although the benefits obtained from this scenario might not be maximized, they are optimal in the sense that they give the possibility of cooperation among rational agents, especially among those who regard themselves in some sense as ʺequalʺ human beings. In reference with public and private solutions, Ostrom again says:

Later in the same paragraph, the Nobel Laureate in Economic Sciences replies: ʺInstead of there being a single solution to a single problem, I argue that many solutions exist to cope with many different problems.ʺ Ostrom argues that institutions are rarely either private or public – ʺthe marketʺ or ʺthe stateʺ. Many successful CPR institutions are rich mixtures of ʺprivate-likeʺ and ʺpublic-likeʺ institutions. Users of Common Pool Resources (a natural or man-made resource system that is sufficiently large as to make it costly to exclude potential beneficiaries from obtaining benefits from its use ), have developed a wide diversity in their agreements, which are enforced by many mechanisms. Some of them are external government agencies, members of the user’s community who have been employed as monitors and enforcers, and the users themselves as their own monitors. A good example of this behavior is presented by Donald R. Leal concerning a fishery near Valensa, Brazil. Example in Valensa, Brazil
The estuary fishery near Valensa, illustrates how fishing communities can solve problems, yet the solution can break down when governments ignore the forces that led to success. The mixed-species fishery began nearly a century ago. At first, notes John Cordell (1972) , Valensa fishers fought over access to prime fishing spots. In addition, violence would often erupt when one type of gear became entangled with another, as when mobile nets run into stationary nets. Over time, local fishers came up with two harvesting arrangements to resolve these problems. To prevent one gear type from hampering another, they divided the estuary into different fishing zones, with only one gear allowed in each zone. They assigned fishing spots by drawing lots to determine the order in which each fisher could use a particular spot. After decades during which this arrangement operated successfully, the Brazilian government decided to "modernize" the Valensa fishery. The government made new nylon nets available to anyone who qualified for a bank loan arranged by the government. But local fishers did not qualify for the loan and did not have enough capital to purchase the nets on their own. A few wealthy individuals around Valensa did qualify for the loans, and purchased the nylon nets. They hired men who had never fished the estuary before to fish using the nylon nets. The local fishers' management system crumbled as old and new fishers fought over fishing spots, and eventually the fishery was overharvested and, ultimately, abandoned. Valensa provides an example of a self-governed common-property agreement in which the rules have been devised and modified by the participants themselves and also are monitored and enforced by them. Evidence from the real world suggests that the tragedy of the commons is not universal. In many places, local fishers manage fishing grounds, usually without much governmental interference, and they prevent overfishing. For the most part, these arrangements are "community-based, spontaneously developed and informally organized" (Jentoft and Kristoffersen 1989, 355). This type of CPRs institutional agreements have been well documented for many farmer-managed irrigation systems, communal forests, inshore fisheries, and grazing and hunting territories. There are, however, assertions against the imposition of private property rights such as how the attributes of the goods involved will be measured, who will pay for the costs of excluding non-owners from access, and how conflicts over rights will be adjudicated. After all, all theories have limits, and as I mentioned at the beginning of this paper, rules used in one physical environment with certain kind of people might work, while there may be vastly different results if used in a different environment. About self-governance and cooperation The inevitable question to ask in the midst of the previous information will be how a group of independent people can organize and govern themselves to obtain join benefits when there are incentives to free ride or act opportunistically? After researching on many different examples where self-governed CPRs took place (Nova Scotia's Port Lameron Harbor, Norway's Lofoten Fishery, grazing and forest institutions in Switzerland and Japan, and irrigation systems in Spain and the Philippines), I think is correct to conclude that this self-organization movements have aroused through trial and error. In the Theory of the Firm addressed by Ostrom, an entrepreneur recognizes an opportunity to increase the return that can be achieved when individuals are potentially involved in an interdependent, voluntary relationship. Formal and interpersonal ways of cooperation are actually integral parts of civilized life. Either by formal contracts, or non-formalized cooperative behaviors, we are better off. Sheldon Richman in an issue of The Freeman , states that: ʺ…I would guess that “social cooperation” (or “human cooperation”) is the second most-used phrase in Ludwig Von Misesʾs Human Action. First is probably “division of labor,” which is another way of saying “social cooperation.” Human Action is about social cooperation or it isn’t about anything at all. The first matter Mises takes up after his opening disquisition on the nature of action itself is … cooperation. He begins: ʽSociety is concerted action, cooperation…. It substitutes collaboration for the – at least conceivable – isolated life of individuals’ʺ According to Ostrom, this table shows the basic principles illustrated by long-enduring CPR institutions:
CONDITIONS EXHIBITED BY DURABLE CPR INSTITUTIONS:
1. Clearly defined boundaries: Individuals or households who have rights to withdraw resource units from the CPR must be clearly defined, as must the boundaries of the CPR itself.
2. Congruence between rules and local condition: Rules restricting time, place, technology, and/or quantity of resource units are related to local conditions. There should be a small set of simple rules related to the access and resource use patterns agreed upon by the appropriators, rules easy to learn, remember, use and transmit.*
3. Collective-choice arrangements: Most individuals affected by the operational rules can participate in modifying these operational rules. There is a need to remain adaptable, to be able to modify the rules with regard to membership, access to and use of the CPR and to remain responsive to rapid exogenous changes. *
4. Monitoring: Monitors, who actively audit CPR conditions and appropriator behaviors, are accountable to the appropriators or are the appropriators. The enforcement of the rules is shared by all appropriators sometimes assisted by "official" observers and enforcers. *
5. Graduated sanctions: Appropriators who violate operational rules are likely to be assessed graduated sanctions (depending on the seriousness and context of the offense) by other appropriators, by officials accountable to these appropriators, or by both.
6. Conflict-resolution mechanisms: Appropriators and their officials have rapid access to low-cost local arenas to resolve conflicts among appropriators or between appropriators and officials. There is also the need to adapt the rules to changing conditions and apply different rules to different problems and scales of problems. *
7. Minimal recognition of rights to organize: The rights of appropriators to devise their own institutions are not challenged by external governmental authorities. Appropriators must be able to legally sustain their ownership of the CPR.* Furthermore, their organization must be perceived as legitimate by the larger set of organizations in which it is nested. *
8. Nested enterprises: For CPRs that are part of a larger system, the appropriation, provision, monitoring, enforcement, conflict resolution, and governance activities are organized in multiple layers of nested enterprises
* See Ostrom, 1992

Many times, however, the costs of exploring and initializing CPR management options are high. Without a supportive procedure, crafting and exploring alternatives will prove too risky for small groups of individuals. De Young and Kaplan suggest another option called ʺadaptive muddling.ʺ People are empowered to apply local or personal knowledge to a situation creating a variety of potential solutions. According to these authors, it is just such enhanced and diverse creativity that is needed. Furthermore, as conceived, adaptive muddling contains a stability component that not only reduces the costs of failure for individuals but also makes highly improbable any unchecked and disorienting change and the widespread implementation of untested solutions.

According to Richard L. Stoup and Jane S. Shaw , private property rights and trade harness the narrow self interests of individuals towards goals desired by all who bear the costs. When private property rights are well-defined, well-protected, and transferable, all those in the economy tend to benefit for several reasons:
- The person who wants to use a product or resource must pay for it by outbidding others who want it. Thus, the creation of value is rewarded by those who, in their own judgment, will benefit.
- The cost of degrading a resource is paid by the one who degrades it.
- A person who degrades someone else’s property can be sued by the owner to stop the harm and to collect for damages already done. Both parties have an incentive to avoid or stop this situation. This system, with each paying the cost of what he or she does, provides incentives to conserve and to protect natural resources and to avoid environmental damage.
- The most important contrast between governmental and private control is the difference in the way each affects the future use of resources. Property rights provide long-term incentives for maximizing the value of what it owned.
- The diversification risk reduces the exposure of individuals in the society to dangers caused by inevitable human mistakes. In the private sector, this risks are diversified because, instead of all the resources in society being committed to a single, agree-upon course of action, there are many diverse ideas, all of which may be acted upon at the same time.

Conclusions
Again, it is important to mention that not all the commons can be privatized. Air and large bodies of water are unlikely to be privately owned. Under these situations, many examples have proved that cooperation and self-governance helps creating new grounds for the administration of large, common resources. After writing this paper, I can now say that the so called “Tragedy of the Commons” is not a tragedy after all. Real life examples all over the world have proven that organized individuals, who pursue a better state of life, can rearrange and manage this “tragedy” giving it a glimpse of something different: an opportunity. Further study on this proves that human beings are not selfish individuals who only care about what they do and what they have. We are more than that. We can be cooperative people in search of solutions to situations that appear to be complicated. This shows that individuals are and can be creative, innovative and courageous. This also proves that there are many people who dare to look for answers instead of waiting for an institution, or a government to solve them. If we have the freedom to make our own decisions and start new projects in favor of what is proper for us as individuals and human beings, then we have to make use of that liberty in creative ways that will advance and foster the human life. Charles de Gaulle once said: “History does not teach fatalism. There are moments when the will of a handful of free men breaks through determinism and opens up new roads.” After all, if you want to be incrementally better: be competitive. And if you want to be exponentially better: Be cooperative”. The Tragedy of the Commons is not a tragedy anymore; it’s an opportunity to out find that, through cooperation, human beings achieve better results than through coercive and corrupt systems.

Bilbiography:
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge.
Ostrom, Dietz, Dolsak, Stern, Stonich (2002). The Drama of the Commons. National Acadamy Press.
Aristotle. (Politics, Book II, Chapter 3).
Hardin,G. (1968). The Tragedy of the Commons. Science. PP. 1243-48
Machan,T. (2001). The Commons: Its Tragedies and other Follies. Hoover Institution
Chesher, J. (1999) The Business of Commerce: Examining an Honorable Profession. Hoover Institute Press
Donald R. Leal (1996). Free Market Environmentalism.
Cordell, John C. 1972. The developmental ecology of an estuarine canoe fishing system in northeast Brazil. Stanford University, Stanford, CA
Jentoft, Svein, and Trond Kristoffersen. 1989. Fishermen's co-management: The case of the Lofoten fishery. Human Organization 48(4): 355-65
The Goal Is Freedom | Sheldon Richman: Social Cooperation (The Freeman Online, August 12, 2011).
De Young, R. and S. Kaplan (2012). Adaptive muddling. In R. De Young and T. Princen
The Localization Reader: Adapting to the Coming Downshift. (Chapter 22, Pp. 287-298) Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. < Original 1988 Environmental Management journal article persistent archive URL = http://hdl.handle.net/2027.42/48163 >
Stoup, R. and Shaw, S. The Commons (2009). Hoover Institution Press

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Tragedy of the Commons

...Professor Richter Tragedy of the Commons Analysis The Tragedy of the Commons is an effective metaphor to understanding the exploitation of global property resources by private producers. Its flaws as a metaphor stems from the gross assumptions it makes on human behavior and motivations. When taken at face value, the metaphor can be used to explain broad resource issues that nations are still dealing with today, such as global climate change and the use of natural resources. However, when closely inspected, its generalization about the community-shared commons is not as accurate. Garret Hardin's article has received vast critical acclaim and is considered one of the finest works regarding natural resource issues. In his article, Hardin claims that all commonly owned resources are doomed to destruction. This is due to the fact that men are greedy, and instinctively pursue their own best interests. Given is an example involving a common pasture open to all, in which it is expected that every herdsman is going to try keep as many cattle on the commons as possible in-order to try make the most profit. However as the commons is overgrazed productivity goes down causing each herdsman to add more cattle in an attempt to bring their profits back up. It is in this desire for self-interest that the tragedy of the commons occurs. The Tragedy of the Commons metaphor is best understood when applied to large-scale resource issues. In order to do so, the community commons Hardin referred...

Words: 701 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Tragedy of the Commons

...TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS AND THE PROBLEM OF ANARCHY IN THE INTERNATIONAL COMMUNITY By: Ma. Hazel Joy M. Faco BA Political Science – 2 "Freedom in a common brings ruin to all." As proposed by Garrett Hardin, the “Tragedy of the Commons” is an inevitable result of the exploitation of a shared resource by rational and egoistic individuals who solely seek to maximize their own consumption. It is predicted that there will come a time when the supply of that resource will no longer be able to keep up with the rapidly growing demand. This is where the tragedy comes into the picture. This apathetic and nonchalant consumption will eventually lead to the irreversible depletion and degradation of that particular common resource. To avoid this ultimate tragedy, there is no technical solution that we can possibly adopt. No amount of science or technology can reverse this damage. The only way that we can possibly preclude this destruction is by undergoing a dramatic re-examination and transformation of our conscience and fundamental conceptions of ethics and morality. But the real question is this: Is that even possible? Hardin’s pessimistic parable is widely and almost universally accepted as an all-encompassing, catchall framework in explaining the ecological crisis that currently confronts commonly-held goods such as the earth’s atmosphere, fisheries, grasslands, water, forests, roads and even population growth. However, in this essay, I am going to analyze this tragedy by...

Words: 1143 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Tragedy And The Common Man

...In Arthur Miller’s article, “Tragedy and the Common Man,” he discusses the idea surrounding one’s position in society and the level of regard that is held around their death. According to Miller, people are becoming more skeptical about the idea of “heroes” existing, and only consider the demise of significant figures like kings to be “tragic.” But, he refutes this idea with an argument claiming that the common man can be held to the same standing. Using references to Greek mythology and Shakespeare, Miller asserts that anyone willing to sacrifice himself is to be considered a “tragic hero.” In addition, Miller states that “the underlying struggle is that of the individual attempting to gain a "rightful" position in his society,” essentially...

Words: 560 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Tragedy Of The Commons Essay

...What is the Tragedy of Commons? Who came up with the theory? The tragedy of the commons is the tendency of a shared, limited resource to become depleted because people act from self-interest for short-term gain. Garrett Hardin came up with the theory. Explain how the Tragedy of the Commons could apply to the ocean. The fishermen overfish marine animals from the ocean. It will cause the number of marine animals to decline quickly. It eventually will upset the balance of entire marine ecosystems What is an externality? Who pays for the costs of externalities? Describe one positive externality and one negative externality of living near the ocean. An externality is a cost or benefit of a good or service that is not included in the purchase price of the good or service. Human...

Words: 1680 - Pages: 7

Free Essay

Hardin's Tragedy of the Commons

...Environmental Science 09/11/15 Is “The Tragedy of the Commons” still relevant? The Tragedy of the Commons is an economic problem in which every person tries to benefit from a resource. “Commons” refers to resources that are shared, but not regulated, i.e. the atmosphere, oceans, rivers, etc. As the demand for the resource grows, and people overindulge in it, others are harmed because they do not receive enough. For example, if a village contains six families of four and one lake full of fish, if the villagers do not work together, then one family may get all of the fish while the others starve. The main focus of the Tragedy of the Commons is “supply and demand”, if the supply does not match the demand, then people go without. “The Tragedy of the Commons”, an article written by Garrett Hardin, focuses on the claim that there is no technical solution to some problems; a technical solution is one that requires “a change only in the techniques of the natural sciences, demanding little or nothing in the way of change in human values of ideas of morality.” (1243). Hardin calls upon Wiesner and York because they insisted that the solution to the problem, in this case, nuclear war, was not a technical solution. This article is still relevant today, even though the data is outdated. Hardin expresses his opinions using an example. “Picture a pasture open to all. It is expected that each herdsman will try to keep as many cattle as possible on the commons. Such an arrangement may work for...

Words: 871 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Revision of the Tragedy of the Commons

...REVISITING THE ”TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS” University Sciences Po Paris Semester: Fall 2011/2012 Student: Sönke-Timo Kisker Student – ID: 100033186 Course: Thinking and Acting the Environment Course-ID: 23811 Course Coordinaton: Florence Faucher-King; Thomas Léon Assignment: Mid-term paper Word-count: 2746 Date: 18.10.2011 | Agenda I. Introduction 2 II. Specifying a framework 2 a. Defining ‘global public good’ 2 b. Defining the “Tragedy,”within Game theory 3 III. Revisiting Hardin's main assumptions and argumentations 4 c. Variables influencing rational choices of Individuals 4 d. The concept value and ethics in decisionmaking 5 IV. Practical examples of dealing with the commons 6 e. Mc Evoy's findings of assigning responsibility 6 f. Co-Management 6 ...

Words: 3438 - Pages: 14

Free Essay

Casy Study of the Tragedy of Common

...Discussion on Tragedy of the Commons | This paper intends to discuss the basic theories within the scope of the tragedy of commons, especially from the ethics perspective. In addition, the paper also explicitly explores two possible ways to solve the tragedy of the commons, the free market solution and the socialism solution, and applies these ways to a real case of Euro’s Tragedy. In the end, referring to Elinor Ostrom’s theory in 2009, the paper recommends the collective agreement from the moral perspective to be the possible ideal solution to the tragedy of the commons. | | Contents 1. Introduction 1 2. Formation 2 2.1 Theoretical explain of the formation 2 2.2 Hardin’s grazing model 4 3. Ethics Involved 5 3.1 Ethical Egoism Theory 5 3.2 Utilitarian Theory 5 3.3 Moral Foundation Theory, Virtue Theory and Confucius 6 3.4 Right Theory 6 4. Solutions to the Tragedy 7 4.1 Free market solution 7 4.2 Socialism solution 9 4.3 Comparison of the Two Solutions 10 4.3.1 Attitude towards self-interest 11 4.3.2 Attitude towards common resources 11 4.3.3 Government Function 11 4.3.4 Incentive structures 11 4.3.5 Outcomes 12 5. Case of Euro’s Tragedy 12 5.1 How Euro’s Tragedy Happened 13 5.2 How it related to Tragedy of the Commons 14 5.3 Free Market Capitalism Solution and the Tragedy of Euro 14 5.4 Socialism Solution and the Tragedy of Euro 15 6. A Third Solution 17 6.1 Ethical Obligation 17 6.2 Cultivating Ethics 17 6.3 Elinor Ostrom’s Theory 18 ...

Words: 5411 - Pages: 22

Premium Essay

Tragedy Of The Common Research Paper

...decisions that are rational and/or for self-gain, because they believe someone else is and/or going to do the same, is called the Tragedy of the Commons. People usually feel that someone else is going to cheat or make a rational decision to benefit him or herself before they feel comfortable doing the same. In addition, if someone feels that the goal of the group begins to seem unattainable, they may make a rationally decision. When tragedy of the common happens, it is usually the cause of a failure of collective action. Although, to prevent the tragedy of common there must be a strong best interest in the group, but when this is not enough the government is required for policing and enforcement....

Words: 529 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Tragedy And The Common Man Essay

...In his essay “Tragedy and the Common Man” Arthur Miller attempts to redefine both the genre of tragedy and the tragic hero. According to Miller, a tragedy is defined as a man wrestling with how he defines himself in regards to his environment, and that above all, Miller believes that tragedies should be optimistic. Miller states that the “wound from which the inevitable events spiral is the wound of indignity… Tragedy, then, is the consequence of a man’s total compulsion to evaluate himself justly”. Miller is saying that all tragedies stem from an attack on the main characters dignity, and all tragedies are therefore a result of a man’s attempt to make sense of who he is after having been shamed. By using the word inevitable, Miller seems to...

Words: 1507 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

The Tragedy Of The Commons: Chapter Analysis

...The chapter starts off talking about making a decision and leads into what “the tragedy of the commons” is. It’s the idea that what is appropriate for one individual might not be so for many. He ties this into how this paradox applies to teaching when he says “there is a proper amount of any given approach to teaching. Things that may be very effective if done once in awhile can become ineffective if done too often.” Therefore, teachers need to differentiate and use different approaches on different days while allowing students to be on predictable ground. He says that the best approaches are the ones where students learn to the best of their ability. That means tailoring approaches to the kind of students a teacher has. The selection...

Words: 432 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

The Northern Cod Moratorium of 1992 and the Tragedy of the Commons

...The Northern Cod Moratorium of 1992 and the Tragedy of the Commons As defined by Garrett Hardin using the example of herdsmen who are all dependent on one open, common pasture, the tragedy of the commons refers to the phenomenon where there is a depletion of a shared resource, caused by individuals acting towards their own self-interests rather than thinking of the long term interests of the group (1968). This phenomenon can also relate to another theory known as the prisoner’s dilemma. First framed by Merrill Flood and Melvin Dresher, the prisoner’s dilemma is a situation in which two individuals, who have been accused of a crime, are taken in for questioning by the police (Dixit & Nalebuff, 1991). Furthermore, both individuals each have two options, either to accuse the other person or not to cooperate with the police. In most cases, the individuals choose a self-serving option in order to save themselves. However, this theory does not only have to apply to prisoners but can also apply in economics in regards to firms and their competition and how cooperation between companies can often lead to a greater good (Dixit & Nalebuff, 1991). These two theories occur often in day-to-day life and seem to reveal how humans are predisposed to think of themselves first before thinking about the good of others. This paper will examine the extent of these theories related to the overfishing of Northern Cod on the eastern cost of Canada and how...

Words: 1504 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Arthur, Miller, “Tragedy and Common Man” & Aristotle Poetics

... Miller, “Tragedy and Common man” & Aristotle Poetics A tragic hero according Aristotle’s Poetics, is an ideal noble man with a flaw. Oedipus fits into the context of a flawed man, a man with given stature, and catharsis that propel him into a tragic hero. Oedipus as a tragic hero is caring concerned king whom the people trusted and loved. However, his impulsive temper caused him to make mistakes. On, the other, hand, Willie Lowman was a tragic hero as he was ready to lay down his love for the love of his family. Miller gives the flawed sense of a tragic hero in the sense of personal dignity that Lowman is willing to fulfill even in his death. The characteristics that Miller offers in terms catharsis and stature fits Lowman, he involved himself in a car accident so that his son Biff could use the insurance money to start a business and become a successful person in the society. This paper will discuss Willie Lowman, and Oedipus, as tragic heroes based on the stature, tragic flaw, and catharsis in their respective stories. A tragic hero according to Miller is a common person as opposed to the belief that a tragic hero must be a form of a king. He says, “we are often held to be below tragedy or tragedy below us……… that tragedy fits only for the highly placed… where this admission is not made in so many words it is often implied.” A tragic hero, therefore, is a common and both a highly placed person in the society. The belief that tragedy does not affect a common forces Miller...

Words: 995 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Economics Decision Making

...analysis and rational decision making. The process of making economic decisions is complex as that of consumer decision making. When making decisions, businesses derive most of the critical choices from macroeconomics data, any of the choice made could mean the failure or success of their enterprise. The accuracy, reliability and validity of the information the business uses are of great importance (Tremmel, 2008). My aim in this paper, therefore, is to discuss and identify any decision-making processes. I will also consider incentives of stakeholders and how concepts such as equity, externalities, and efficiency influence the economy. I will achieve this objective by analyzing the Yasuni case, “A tragedy of commons”. Before I delve into Yasuni initiative, “A tragedy of commons”, it will be better if I highlight the steps of the decision-making process. A decision process has about...

Words: 1768 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Miss

...According to Miller why do some not consider tragedy a relevant genre for the modern age? According to Miller there are very few tragedies written in the modern age, this is because of the rareness of heroes among us. Miller believes that the ‘Modern man has had the blood drawn out of his organs of belief by the scepticism of science’. What Miller is meaning by this is that today the society is reserved and is unwilling to take risks resulting in very few tragedies being written. Miller concludes by saying that he believes that tragedies are seen as old fashioned in today’s society, he also believes that tragedies were only suitable for the ‘very highly placed’ such as the kings or kingly. Who does Miller think is a suitable subject for tragedy and how does he support his claim? Miller claims that the common man is a suitable subject for a tragedy meaning the masses or the working class. Miller supports his claim by saying that modern psychiatry does in fact base its analysis upon classic formulations, for example the Oedipus where he kills his father and Orestes which is the tragedy where he kills his mother and her lover to avenge his father’s murder. However even though these tragedies were acted by royal individuals; these similar emotional situations apply to everyone. So in other words the common man would be a suitable subject for a tragedy as the common man is likely to experience similar emotional situations. According to Miller what is it about the tragic figure...

Words: 1087 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Hamlet Tragedy

...Hamlet Essay Tragedies commonly involve disasters, horrible mishaps and death. The great Greek philosopher Aristotle believed that a tragedy must have action which is pushed along by the character flaw of a “great” man. This idea of a “great” man or a person of high ranking being the protagonist in a tragedy is perpetuated in all of Shakespeare’s work. This leaves to speculate on the average person. The average person is not completely safe from the misery of tragedy. A supporting character is just as likely as any main character to experience tragedy. According to Arthur Miller, the “common” person is just as suitable for tragedy as any “great” person. The ideas of Aristotle and Miller contrast each other however both elements are noticeable in the play Hamlet. When a “great person” or the main character goes through a tragedy, it is rather evident. Ophelia and her father Polonius are considered “common” characters in the play that also experience great tragedy. In Miller’s essay, he outlines three main aspects that a “common” person would exhibit in a tragedy which makes their circumstances tragic. Firstly is the presence of a character that is ready to lay down their life to secure their personal sense of dignity. Next is the fear of being displaced and torn away from ones chosen image of their self. Lastly is being capable of victory. Ophelia and Polonius have chosen images of themselves and what their lives should be like and are willing to lay down their lives for their...

Words: 353 - Pages: 2