Free Essay

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson

In:

Submitted By sarcoma68
Words 4569
Pages 19
A TRIBUTE TO OLIVER WILLIAMSON:

Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

Rui J. P. de Figueiredo, Jr.

liver Williamson is best known for his contributions to economics, and particularly to our understanding of how private firms are defined, operate, and change. Williamson’s primary application addressed the question of why some economic transactions were organized within a private firm, while others took place outside of a firm, in the market. Despite this focus, Williamson’s reach and impact has extended far beyond the domain of private firms and markets. Certainly suitable for a scholar who has been so vocally interdisciplinary in his approach to the study of institutions and organizations, Williamson’s work has also made critical contributions to the understanding of political institutions specifically, and politics more generally.

O

From Transaction Cost Economics to Transaction Cost Politics
At its heart, Williamson’s deep analysis of organization through the “lens of contract” is not restricted to private firms competing for economic profits. The theory and empirical analysis outlined and developed by Williamson, and those working through the framework he provides, focus on issues of governance more broadly: how activities, exchanges, or transactions are appropriately (or at times inappropriately) organized to minimize transaction costs. Put another way, one of Williamson’s signal contributions was to note that the way in which social activity is organized has an impact on the outcomes of those activities. In this sense, Williamson’s work extends far beyond the profit-maximizing firm. An understanding of governance, institutions, and organization is critical to other realms of (or transactions in) society: families, volunteer associations, and (yes)

CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

123

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

government organizations are also ruled by the same principles that Williamson develops for economic organization. The recognition of the broad reach of Williamson’s insights has led to application in other fields. Perhaps one of the most well developed is the realm of public organization—what has come to be known as transaction cost politics. As Dixit notes, “Transaction-cost politics views . . . policy-making as a political process constrained by asymmetric information and limited commitment possibilities.”1 Many of the ideas, concepts, and frameworks developed by Williamson are directly applicable to the study of policy-making and policy-executing organizations. As with applications to economics, transaction cost logic applied to politics also focuses on (bilateral) dependencies between actors engaged in political transactions—whether they be governments or firms.2 In a political world where third-party enforcement of agreements is not always possible (consider how nations may enforce international agreements) and where organizational Rui J. P. de Figueiredo, Jr. is an Associate Profesoptions may be constrained (consider the sor at the Haas School of Business and in the Department of Political Science at the University types of financial incentives that may be of California at Berkeley. provided to civil servants versus employees of private companies), problems of incomplete contracting (the inability to write down and enforce completely specified agreements to govern transactions, economic or political) and credible commitments (the importance of institutions that limit post-agreement renegotiation and opportunism) become both severe and unique. This in turn suggests that political organization may be governed by the same principles outlined by transaction cost logic, but with broader implications than for private firms. Notably, Williamson’s approach for understanding political organization goes beyond normative and positive questions of public policy and the design of public institutions. In the realm of economics, Williamson’s approach has had foundational contributions to the study of firm, which in turn has provided important prescriptions in the field of strategy, for scholars and practitioners alike. As Salomon notes, “Transaction cost economics is a central theory in the field of strategy. It addresses questions about why firms exist in the first place . . . , how firms define their boundaries, and how they ought to govern operations.”3 In the same way, Williamson’s contributions to the study of public organization also have important implications and guidelines for scholars and executives attempting to gain traction on questions of non-market strategy. In contrast to voluntary economic exchange, which characterizes the market environment of firms, the non-market environment encompasses the political, social, and legal context in which the firm operates.4 In many settings, how firms influence and interact with their non-market environment—their non-market strategy—can have substantial implications for both the effectiveness of their market strategy and the creation of firm value. This is particularly easy to see in the wake of the recent financial crisis: pick up the Wall Street Journal on any given day and, in all likelihood, there will be headlines relat-

124

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

ing how government action is at the forefront of many firms’ strategic agendas. This attention is paid not just to fiscal and monetary policy, but also to economic regulation. Firms in health care, financial services, and telecommunications have had and will have their opportunities and threats fundamentally defined by the nature of government activity in these areas. Given the importance of non-market strategy to many firms’ livelihoods, Williamson’s contributions to this domain should not be ignored. Indeed, while less well-developed than the market applications of Williamson’s transaction cost approach, it may in the end be of equal importance to managers and analysts alike. Williamson’s focus on the transaction provides both scholars and practitioners of non-market strategy with two vital inputs for strategy formulation: a framework for prediction of non-market activity such as the actions of governments (which provides an important basis for identifying the opportunities and threats facing a particular firm); and a framework for prescriptions for a firm’s non-market action (how a firm may fruitfully shape and influence its nonmarket environment). Following are examples of how Williamson’s logic can be applied to understanding the nature of the non-market environment of firms.

The Organization of Regulation
Casual observers of the regulatory apparatus commonly note that government bureaucracy appears very “inefficient.” This observation is often made by comparing the performance of government agencies to private firms. But how is one to evaluate such a claim? Williamson and others, through the lens of transaction cost analysis, provide an answer. Williamson’s primary point of departure is that to understand public organization, one must understand the nature of the transactions that these organizations undertake, or are charged with executing. When one takes this approach, one immediately recognizes that there may be a selection effect in the nature of public versus private transactions. As a simple example, consider the extension of the traditional make-versus-buy decision within firms. Williamson points out that depending on the degree of transactional hazards—i.e., the degree to which the market may fail to efficiently execute a transaction that parties view as mutually beneficial due to transaction costs—it may be more efficient to organize the high-transaction cost transactions within a firm and remove it form the market; whereas those transactions that have lower costs may be more fruitfully pursued between firms in the (open) market. Consider the application of this idea to the next stage: What happens when the firm itself is not able to efficiently mitigate the transactional hazards (or is not adapted to deal with them)? In these cases, the most appropriate organization may be the public organization—government agencies, for example. To apply Williamson’s logic more fully requires an appreciation for two dimensions in which activities of public and private organization may differ. The first is the degree of transactional hazards as traditionally viewed. In Dixit’s terms—the degree to which there are information asymmetries and bilateral

CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

125

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

dependencies may make even the private firm unworkable as an appropriate way to organize a transaction. The second is the transactional hazards actually faced. One that Williamson points to, for example, is “probity”—in which the value of a transaction depends as much on procedure as it does on the ultimate instrumental outcome.5 What this means is that the nature of the activities that “flow” to the government may be fundamentally different than those that are taken in the private sector. An easy way to see the power of this approach is to work back from those things that are “obviously” housed in government. Foreign affairs and justice are both dominated by the public sector. Why? While issues of bilateral dependency and information asymmetries may be important, most would agree that the primary reason is so-called probity—the requirements for procedural integrity, as much as the outcome, dictates public organization of these activities. However, as we move away from these extreme cases, what happens? Is it more efficient for government to produce itself (own), regulate, or leave to the free market the disposition of financial services? What about health insurance? As we move from one activity to another, we see that the activities separate themselves into those—based on the nature of the transaction—best done privately, publicly, or by some hybrid.6 This allows Williamson to provide a useful answer to the question of “Why is government bureaucracy so inefficient?” An answer is: because the things is it is charged with doing may make it so. Unless we can organize an activity more efficiently outside the public agency—or without regulation—it is nothing but a thought exercise to compare it to some unattainable benchmark.7 This is the essence of what Williamson refers to as the “remediableness” standard—namely, that we should only evaluate the so called “efficiency” of a particular activity relative to other feasible forms of organizing the activity, and not to an ideal that may not exist in the real world. Williamson’s insights about the design and assessment of government organizations have a number of important implications for the non-market strategy firms may pursue. On the one hand, considering how an activity may be most efficiently organized—arm’s-length market exchange versus private firm versus regulated firm versus government-owned enterprise—provides predictions about the form of organization. On the other hand, understanding feasibility may also provide active prescriptions or strategies by which firms can influence their non-market environment most effectively.

Transaction Cost Politics: Predicting Environmental Policy
A prime example of the predictive power of Williamson’s approach is environmental regulation. Williamson’s logic of transaction costs provides predictions about how particular types of potentially harmful environmental activity will be governed. The environmental movement in the United States dates back to the days of Teddy Roosevelt, but it really gained its modern forcefulness in the late 1960s and early 1970s. The question that faced both policy makers and firms at the

126

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

time was how best to respond on the rising demands for environmental considerations. Here, Williamson provides an answer. Could firms (even through self-regulation) or the market solve these problems at the time? The answer in many domains was “no.” The reason was that the twin problems of opportunism and probity dictated a public apparatus to prosecute environmental protection. On the one hand, the potential for opportunism in environmental behavior abounds. Given that much environmentally harmful activity is hidden, firms who strike agreements to curb environmentally damaging behavior have an ability to shirk after the fact. The degree of this problem is so severe, it suggests the need for some external enforcement. However, this need creates even further potential for opportunism if firms or industries are left to entirely self-regulate. If given the charge of self-enforcement, firms may turn environmental self-regulation to gain private advantage in the market place.8 If firms and industries cannot fully self-regulate, the alternative in the Williamsonian framework becomes government regulation. This is precisely what unfolded in the late 1960s and early 1970s in the United States. The newly empowered environmental movement in the United States (and globally) pushed hard in that period for the creation of a regulatory apparatus to manage environmental externalities created by firms. In the United States, for example, through a series of legislative acts—exemplified by the passage of the Air Quality Act, National Environmental Policy Act, Water Quality Improvement Act, and subsequent follow-on legislation—the United States Congress created a complex federal structure for regulating environmental quality. This legislative period saw the creation of a regulatory body, the Environmental Protection Agency, charged with determining standards (rule making) and enforcing them. The roll-out of this regulation was critical to the firms in a range of industries from chemicals to steel to automobiles. More recently, the nature of transaction hazards and the apparatus for governing them has evolved in certain areas. The ability to measure and monitor certain emissions—particularly carbon dioxide (CO2)—has improved greatly. This has changed the nature of opportunism, reducing the ability to “game” self-regulation. In this context, many polities around the globe have adopted alternative governance for CO2 regulation—tradable permits and so-called “cap and trade” systems. In the U.S., the creation of the Chicago Climate Exchange (a pilot, voluntary program earlier this decade) is an example of such a system. As monitoring became easier, the progressive adaptation of environmental policy from top-down, command-and-control regulation, EPA-style to more market based systems could be predicted by the transaction costs approach plied by Williamson. For firms seeking to position themselves to take advantage of their non-market environment, this has meant shifting non-market activity from a sole focus of predicting and managing their regulators (from the federal EPA to local air and water quality boards) to understanding and positioning their property rights for carbon emissions.9

CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

127

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

Remediableness and Political Feasibility in Occupational Health and Safety Regulation
Moving from the realm of prediction and reaction to influence, Williamsonian remediableness also helps managers think through what strategy they should pursue in the politics of regulation. As Williamson points out, thinking about the feasibility of solutions to political hazards encompasses a broad range of considerations, including political ones. An important example is how firms manage and influence reform processes. In many cases, firms fight reforms. However, in some cases putting up a fight may be less useful than to try to coopt them. A classic case of such a strategy is described in Moe’s analysis of the origins of the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA). As Moe recounts, knowing that standing to block the OSHA legislation would be fruitless, business interests instead pursued a strategy of compromise—in particular, they gave up their fight in exchange for some say over the design of the future agency and its policy-making and enforcement processes. As Moe notes, “If business firms were allowed to help design OSHA, they would structure it in a way that it could not do its job. They would try to cripple it. This is not a hypothetical case. Interest groups representing business actually did participate in the design of OSHA . . . [and] OSHA is an administrative nightmare, in large measure because some of its institutional designers intended to endow it with structures that would not work.”10

Credible Commitments and International Business
One of the areas where Williamson’s approach has had the greatest and most obvious impact is in the field of international business. Firms attempting to enter foreign markets must consider the non-market environment as an essential strategic consideration: how the political, social and legal environment of the country or countries they may enter will affect the outcomes they enjoy in the market; and what is the best strategy they can pursue to shape that environment to enhance their chances of success. Consider how a firm in a regulated industry may pursue international expansion. Williamson’s work implies that it is important for these firms to evaluate the degree of credible commitment to particular regulatory structures and policies in a candidate market. This is particularly true in a situation where the cross-national system is one of anarchy, in the sense that there is very limited ability—short of war or sanctions—for home nations to enforce agreements. In practice, given that these actions are very costly and will only be credible in a small set of cases, firms must rely on the domestic foreign institutions to establish commitment. Here, the theory and evidence applying Williamson’s approach to institutional analysis is compelling. Consider the case of public utilities regulation. As Levy and Spiller note, public utilities are characterized by a trio of common features: large fixed costs leading to scale and (possibly) scope economies; highly

128

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

specific assets, which are very costly (or possibly even impossible) to redeploy; and competing interests over pricing and supply decisions, which may lead to political wrangling and intervention.11 This trio of features leads to significant contracting hazards for potential entrants. Why? The first and second features create the foundations for the problem of commitment that Williamson introduced in transaction cost theory: namely, having sunk large fixed costs, utilities were at the whim of regulators to renegotiate terms with little bargaining power after the fact. While the first two problems create the means for opportunistic recontracting by public officials, the third feature creates the motive. Because utility regulation is highly contested by various interest groups in any polity, and political control in any environment is transitory (particularly when elections are fully democratic), regulated utilities are likely to encounter a political environment in the future where new constituent interests hold sway. Firms in this environment have to be wary of what the future will hold as they negotiate market concessions in the face of price regulation. How can transaction costs be mitigated for firms pursuing international scope? The key, as Williamson would put it, is governance: in particular, the degree to which domestic political institutions can overcome transactional hazards for firms entering particular national markets. Two aspects of domestic political institutions may ameliorate the problem of regulatory (or political) opportunism. On the one hand, a strong and independent judiciary may act as a check on arbitrary regulatory action. Levy and Spiller highlight the role of the judiciary in their comparative analysis of six countries' telecommunications policy:
“The existence of an independent judiciary with a reputation for impartiality, and whose decisions are enforced, is a necessary condition for making these credible commitments . . . Countries with a well-functioning judiciary face difficulties in the short term in developing a regulatory system capable of sustaining efficient levels of private participation and investment, and there is little reason for them to devote substantial scarce resources in to such an effort. Instead, alternative mechanisms of securing commitment (like international guarantees) will be necessary.”12

The second feature that alleviates the commitment problem for regulated utilities is the structure of policy making. If the policy-making apparatus—between executives, legislators, and agencies—cedes control and discretion to regulators, or any one political actor for that matter, the likelihood of regulatory arbitrariness increases dramatically. Alternatively, when political institutions demonstrate two conditions—multiple veto points and electoral systems that distribute those veto points broadly across interests—they are more likely to sustain regulatory bargains between firms and regulators.13 Put differently, when these two conditions prevail, the status quo (in this case the regulatory agreements under which a firm may enter a market) becomes very difficult to change. For entering firms, this form of gridlock is good. It means the chances they will be expropriated by political actors are vastly reduced. Taken together then, the transaction cost framework provides a lens by which we can understand how

CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

129

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

to analyze the political risk facing globalizing firms: commitment is achieved by mitigating the ability of public officials to change the terms of an agreement (enhanced through multiple and distributed veto players) and by ensuring enforcement by a strong and independent judiciary. The implication for firms preparing entry strategies should be clear. Firms that face transactional hazards should rely on comparative institutional analysis to determine how likely regulatory expropriation is to occur. Investors who ignore institutional features do so at great risk. As Levy and Spiller explain in the vivid case-in-point of Argentina’s privatization of their telephone system in the early 1990s:
“In 1990 Argentina’s main state-owned telecommunications company, ENTel, was split and was later sold to two separate private consortia—one headed by Telefonica of Spain and the second headed by France Cable and Radio and Stet of Italy. The rules under which the private companies were to operate have repeatedly been changed, with pricing a vivid example: one set of pricing rules were announced when private investors were invited to bid for ENTel; these rules were changed during negotiations with the bidders; were changed twice more in 191 when the initial agreements came into conflict with broader macroeconomic polices; and were renegotiated yet again in late 1992.”14

Conclusion
Oliver Williamson’s Nobel Prize in Economics does not imply that his impact has been limited to a single field. Indeed, Olly has insisted that his colleagues, students, and most of all he himself must “be disciplined, be interdisciplinary, and have an active mind.” This is a message that has had a great impact not just on the field of economics, but the broader social sciences. Take my own case as an example: my intellectual field of view since arriving at Berkeley—and being mentored by Olly—has expanded significantly beyond any self-imposed and narrowly defined disciplinary boundaries I may have operated under previously. The implication of this ruthless search to break boundaries has meant that Olly’s contributions to economics—which are impressive—are augmented by the impact he has had in other realms of inquiry. Perhaps most obvious among them is the influence Olly has had on scholars and managers interested in understanding how the legal, social, and political environment shapes and is shaped by firms. Notes
1. Avinash Dixit, “Some Lessons from Transaction-Cost Politics for less-Developed Countries,” Economics and Politics, 15/2 (2003): 107-133. 2. Witold Henisz and Bennet A. Zelner, “Explicating Political Hazards and Safeguards: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 13/6 (2004): 901-915. 3. Robert Salomon, 2009, see .

130

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

A Tribute to Oliver Williamson—Institutions, Politics, and Non-Market Strategy

4. David Baron, “Integrated Strategy: Market and Non-Market Components,” California Management Review, 37/2 (Winter 1995): 47-65; David Baron, Business and Its Environment, 5th Edition (New York, NY: Prentice Hall, 2006). 5. Oliver E. Williamson, "Public and Private Bureaucracies: A Transaction Cost Economics Perspective," Journal of Law, Economics and Organizatrion, 15/1 (1999): 306-342. As Williamson (p. 322) puts it himself, “Where by probity I refer to the loyalty and rectitude with which the . . . transaction is discharged.” 6. An interesting example of Williamson’s logic about public organization is the recent theory on the jurisdictions of government bureaucracies. In my own work with Jason Snyder, along with that of Ting, the allocation of tasks, or policies, to agencies is explored. The basic idea of this analysis is that grouping policies together or assigning them to separate organizations—in other words, how policies or tasks are organized—has implications for how those tasks are performed. There are two main conclusions of this work. First, following Williamson, it explains why some activities—those in which the ability to provide higher powered incentives is limited—may be more tightly or “bureaucratically” controlled from the top, and thus may “flow” to the public sector. Second, it shows how the allocation of tasks to the bureaucracy may be strategic. The most stark example of this is the result that assignment of jurisdiction over policies may be driven more by the incentive to distract attention from legacy policies (that public officials do not support but cannot remove) than to ensure implementation of new policies. Indeed, work by Florentino-Cuellar et al. provides an interesting empirical example in which the design of the U.S. Department of Homeland Security reflected this type of strategic logic. Rui J. P. de Figueiredo and Jason Snyder, “A Theory of the Political Firm: A Multi-Task Model of Bureaucratic Jurisdictions,” University of California at Berkeley working paper, 2001; Michel Ting, “A Theory of Jurisdictional Assignments in Bureaucracies,” American Journal of Political Science, 46/2 (2002): 364-378; Dara Kay Cohen, Mariano Florentino-Cuellar, and Barry R. Weingast, “Crisis Bureaucracy: Homeland Security and the Political Design of Legal Mandates,” Stanford Law Review, 59/3 (2006): 673724. 7. Williamson (1999), op. cit., p. 328. 8. We will see an example of such activity in the example of occupational health and safety regulation in the following discussion. 9. Baron (2006), op. cit., pp. 366-383. 10. Terry M. Moe, “The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy,” in Oliver Williamson, ed., Organization Theory (New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1990); cited in Oliver Williamson, The Mechanisms of Governance (New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1996). 11. Brian Levy and Pablo T. Spiller, “The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment: A Comparative Analysis of Telecommunications Regulation,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 10/2 (1994): 201-244; Brian Levy and Pablo T. Spiller, eds., Regulations, Institutions and Commitment: Comparative Studies of Telecommunications (New York, NY: Cambridge University Press, 1996). 12. Levy and Spiller (1994), op. cit., pp. 209-210 [emphasis added]. 13. See Levy and Spiller (1994) and (1996), op. cit. Also, see Witold J. Henisz, “The Institutional Environment for Economic Development,” Economics and Politics, 12/1 (2000): 1-31. 14. Levy and Spiller (1994), op. cit., p. 237. Indeed, in a broader scale data analysis, Henisz and Zelner find that the higher the degree of regulatory commitment, the greater the investment by private firms. As they summarize their results, “[Variation in] checks and balances on executive discretion . . . created by . . . political structures and party systems affects relative rates of basic telecommunications infrastructure deployment in 147 countries during the period 1960-1994.” Witold J. Henisz and Bennet A. Zelner, “The Institutional Environment for Telecommunications Investment,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 10/1 (2001): 123.

CALIFORNIA MANAGEMENT REVIEW VOL. 52, NO. 2 WINTER 2010

CMR.BERKELEY.EDU

131

Copyright of California Management Review is the property of California Management Review and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Anyfileanytime

...Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness Author(s): Mark Granovetter Source: American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 91, No. 3 (Nov., 1985), pp. 481-510 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2780199 . Accessed: 18/10/2013 11:39 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Sociology. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 158.143.192.135 on Fri, 18 Oct 2013 11:39:24 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness' Mark Granovetter State University of New York at Stony Brook How behavior and institutions are affected by social relations is one of the classic questions of social theory. This paper concerns the extent to which economic action is embedded in structures of social relations, in modern industrial society. Although the usual neoclassical...

Words: 14338 - Pages: 58

Premium Essay

Bas Bhat

...prominent authority for many years in the fields of comparative law, procedural law, evidence, international criminal law and Continental legal history. Professor Damaška’s work is renowned for providing new frameworks for understanding different legal traditions. To celebrate the depth and richness of his work and discuss its implications for the future, the editors have brought together an impressive range of leading scholars from different jurisdictions in the fields of comparative and international law, evidence and criminal law and procedure. Using Professor Damaška’s work as a backdrop, the essays make a substantial contribution to the development of comparative law, procedure and evidence. After an introduction by the editors and a tribute by Harold Koh, Dean of Yale Law School, the book is divided into four parts. The first part considers contemporary trends in national criminal procedure, examining cross-fertilisation and the extent to which these trends are resulting in converging practices across national jurisdictions. The second part explores the epistemological environment of rules of evidence and procedure. The third part analyses human rights standards and the phenomenon of hybridisation in transnational and international criminal law. The final part of the book assesses Professor Damaška’s contribution to comparative law and the challenges faced by comparative law in the twenty first century. Crime, Procedure and Evidence in a Comparative and International Context ...

Words: 195907 - Pages: 784

Free Essay

Living History

...___________________________ LIVING HISTORY Hillary Rodham Clinton Simon & Schuster New York • London • Toronto • Sydney • Singapore To my parents, my husband, my daughter and all the good souls around the world whose inspiration, prayers, support and love blessed my heart and sustained me in the years of living history. AUTHOR’S NOTE In 1959, I wrote my autobiography for an assignment in sixth grade. In twenty-nine pages, most half-filled with earnest scrawl, I described my parents, brothers, pets, house, hobbies, school, sports and plans for the future. Forty-two years later, I began writing another memoir, this one about the eight years I spent in the White House living history with Bill Clinton. I quickly realized that I couldn’t explain my life as First Lady without going back to the beginning―how I became the woman I was that first day I walked into the White House on January 20, 1993, to take on a new role and experiences that would test and transform me in unexpected ways. By the time I crossed the threshold of the White House, I had been shaped by my family upbringing, education, religious faith and all that I had learned before―as the daughter of a staunch conservative father and a more liberal mother, a student activist, an advocate for children, a lawyer, Bill’s wife and Chelsea’s mom. For each chapter, there were more ideas I wanted to discuss than space allowed; more people to include than could be named; more places visited than could be described...

Words: 217937 - Pages: 872

Free Essay

Bloodlines of the Illuminati

...Bloodlines of Illuminati by: Fritz Springmeier, 1995 Introduction: I am pleased & honored to present this book to those in the world who love the truth. This is a book for lovers of the Truth. This is a book for those who are already familiar with my past writings. An Illuminati Grand Master once said that the world is a stage and we are all actors. Of course this was not an original thought, but it certainly is a way of describing the Illuminati view of how the world works. The people of the world are an audience to which the Illuminati entertain with propaganda. Just one of the thousands of recent examples of this type of acting done for the public was President Bill Clinton’s 1995 State of the Union address. The speech was designed to push all of the warm fuzzy buttons of his listening audience that he could. All the green lights for acceptance were systematically pushed by the President’s speech with the help of a controlled congressional audience. The truth on the other hand doesn’t always tickle the ear and warm the ego of its listeners. The light of truth in this book will be too bright for some people who will want to return to the safe comfort of their darkness. I am not a conspiracy theorist. I deal with real facts, not theory. Some of the people I write about, I have met. Some of the people I expose are alive and very dangerous. The darkness has never liked the light. Yet, many of the secrets of the Illuminati are locked up tightly simply because secrecy is a way...

Words: 206477 - Pages: 826

Premium Essay

Manu 2013

...Use these links to rapidly review the document TABLE OF CONTENTS Index to Consolidated financial statements Table of Contents UNITED STATES SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20549 FORM 20-F (Mark One) o REGISTRATION STATEMENT PURSUANT TO SECTION 12(b) OR (g) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 OR  ANNUAL REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 For the fiscal year ended 30 June 2013 OR o TRANSITION REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 OR o SHELL COMPANY REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 Commission File Number 001-35627 MANCHESTER UNITED plc (Exact name of Registrant as specified in its charter) Not Applicable (Translation of Company's name into English) Cayman Islands (Jurisdiction of incorporation or organization) Sir Matt Busby Way, Old Trafford, Manchester, England, M16 0RA (Address of principal executive offices) Edward Woodward Executive Vice Chairman Sir Matt Busby Way, Old Trafford, Manchester, England, M16 0RA Telephone No. 011 44 (0) 161 868 8000 E-mail: ir@manutd.co.uk (Name, Telephone, E-mail and/or Facsimile number and Address of Company Contact Person) Securities registered or to be registered pursuant to Section 12(b) of the Act. Title of each class Class A ordinary shares, par value $0.0005 per share Name of each exchange on which registered New York Stock Exchange Securities...

Words: 196454 - Pages: 786

Free Essay

Gggg

...Page No. 2 Index Swachh Bharat Mission FEB & MARCH, 2015 AUGUST, 2012 Page No. 4 Insurance Sector In India Page No. 5 Bharat Ratna Award Designed by: Chandan Kumar “Raja” For Advertisement Contact at : 9958790414 Join us at Facebook: https://www.facebook.com/iasexamportal Follow us at Twitter: https://twitter.com/iasexamportal CURRENT AFFAIRS National Issues International Issues India & the World Economy Science and Technology Sports Awards & Prizes In The News 6 14 20 23 39 51 58 64 Disclaimer: Editor and Publisher are not responsible for any view, data, figure etc. expressed in the articles by the author(s). Maps are notational . All Disputes are subject to the exclusive jurisdiction of competent courts and fourms in Delhi/New Delhi only. Selected Articles from Various Newspapers & Journals Page No. 67 91 Cyberspace Page No. 93 Regional Rural Banks The Mauryan Empire Model Paper G.S. Paper I 94 117 Join Online Coaching For IAS Pre & Mains Exams http://iasexamportal.com/civilservices/courses Project Mausam and Maritime Silk Route SWACHH BHARAT MISSION Throughout the world around 2.5 billion people do not have toilets to use, out of those 250 crore people 65 crore live in India alone. In order to solve this big challenge government of India has launched “Swachh Bharat Mission” on the birth anniversary of Mahatma Gandhi and former Prime Minister Lal Bahadur Shastri...

Words: 80076 - Pages: 321

Free Essay

Phsychology

...Educational Psychology: Developing Learners This is a protected document. Please enter your ANGEL username and password. Username: Password: Login Need assistance logging in? Click here! If you experience any technical difficulty or have any technical questions, please contact technical support during the following hours: M-F, 6am-12am MST or Sat-Sun, 7am-12am MST by phone at (800) 800-9776 ext. 7200 or submit a ticket online by visiting http://help.gcu.edu. Doc ID: 1009-0001-191D-0000191E DEVELOPING LEARNERS JEANNE ELLIS ORMROD Professor Emerita, University of Northern Colorado EIGHTH EDITION ISBN 1-256-96292-9 Boston Columbus Indianapolis New York San Francisco Upper Saddle River Amsterdam Cape Town Dubai London Madrid Milan Munich Paris Montreal Toronto Delhi Mexico City São Paulo Sydney Hong Kong Seoul Singapore Taipei Tokyo Educational Psychology: Developing Learners, Eighth Edition, by Jeanne Ellis Ormrod. Published by Pearson. Copyright © 2014 by Pearson Education, Inc. Vice President and Editorial Director: Jeffery W.  Johnston Vice President and Publisher: Kevin Davis Editorial Assistant: Lauren Carlson Development Editor: Christina Robb Vice President, Director of Marketing: Margaret Waples Marketing Manager: Joanna Sabella Senior Managing Editor: Pamela D. Bennett Project Manager: Kerry Rubadue Senior Operations Supervisor: Matthew Ottenweller Senior Art Director: Diane Lorenzo Text Designer: Candace Rowley Cover Designer:...

Words: 244561 - Pages: 979

Free Essay

History of Accounting

...DEVELOPMENT OF CONCEPTS OF CAPITAL AND INCOME IN FINANCIAL REPORTING IN THE NINETEENTH CENTURY Calculation, Context and Consequence THOMAS REGINALD (Tom) ROWLES B.Ec (Hons), Dip.Ed (Monash) A THESIS SUBMITED FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY IN THE SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING AND LAW OF RMIT UNIVERSITY, MELBOURNE, VICTORIA, AUSTRALIA ii DECLARATION I certify that: Except where due acknowledgement has been made, this thesis is mine alone; and The work has not been submitted previously, in whole or part, to qualify for any other academic award; and The content of the thesis is the result of work that has been carried out since the official commencement date of the approved research programme. THOMAS R. ROWLES iii TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter Introduction 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 Introduction Purpose of the Study Sombart’s Hypothesis An Alternative Model; Entrepreneurial Decision-making Context: The Industrial Revolution and ‘Profit’ The Changing Nature of ‘Investment’ The Great Depression of 1873-96 Intellectual Introspection Irving Fisher and the Conception of Capital and Income 17 17 17 23 25 26 30 32 34 34 35 36 38 38 38 39 43 46 49 50 51 54 55 1.10 Research Issues Identified 1.11 Summary Derivation of Research Issues 2.1 2.2 Introduction Evidence from Extant Accounts 2.2.1 Fixed Assets in Mercantile Accounting 2.2.2 The East India Company 2.2.3 Fixed Assets and Early Industrial Accounting 2.2.4 Capital Asset Accounting After 1870...

Words: 130630 - Pages: 523

Free Essay

Test2

...62118 0/nm 1/n1 2/nm 3/nm 4/nm 5/nm 6/nm 7/nm 8/nm 9/nm 1990s 0th/pt 1st/p 1th/tc 2nd/p 2th/tc 3rd/p 3th/tc 4th/pt 5th/pt 6th/pt 7th/pt 8th/pt 9th/pt 0s/pt a A AA AAA Aachen/M aardvark/SM Aaren/M Aarhus/M Aarika/M Aaron/M AB aback abacus/SM abaft Abagael/M Abagail/M abalone/SM abandoner/M abandon/LGDRS abandonment/SM abase/LGDSR abasement/S abaser/M abashed/UY abashment/MS abash/SDLG abate/DSRLG abated/U abatement/MS abater/M abattoir/SM Abba/M Abbe/M abbé/S abbess/SM Abbey/M abbey/MS Abbie/M Abbi/M Abbot/M abbot/MS Abbott/M abbr abbrev abbreviated/UA abbreviates/A abbreviate/XDSNG abbreviating/A abbreviation/M Abbye/M Abby/M ABC/M Abdel/M abdicate/NGDSX abdication/M abdomen/SM abdominal/YS abduct/DGS abduction/SM abductor/SM Abdul/M ab/DY abeam Abelard/M Abel/M Abelson/M Abe/M Aberdeen/M Abernathy/M aberrant/YS aberrational aberration/SM abet/S abetted abetting abettor/SM Abeu/M abeyance/MS abeyant Abey/M abhorred abhorrence/MS abhorrent/Y abhorrer/M abhorring abhor/S abidance/MS abide/JGSR abider/M abiding/Y Abidjan/M Abie/M Abigael/M Abigail/M Abigale/M Abilene/M ability/IMES abjection/MS abjectness/SM abject/SGPDY abjuration/SM abjuratory abjurer/M abjure/ZGSRD ablate/VGNSDX ablation/M ablative/SY ablaze abler/E ables/E ablest able/U abloom ablution/MS Ab/M ABM/S abnegate/NGSDX abnegation/M Abner/M abnormality/SM abnormal/SY aboard ...

Words: 113589 - Pages: 455

Premium Essay

Critical Thinking

...fourth EDItION fourth EDItION This clear, learner-friendly text helps today’s students bridge the gap between Its comprehensiveness allows instructors to tailor the material to their individual teaching styles, resulting in an exceptionally versatile text. Highlights of the Fourth Edition: Additional readings and essays in a new Appendix as well as in Chapters 7 and 8 nearly double the number of readings available for critical analysis and classroom discussion. An online chapter, available on the instructor portion of the book’s Web site, addresses critical reading, a vital skill for success in college and beyond. Visit www.mhhe.com/bassham4e for a wealth of additional student and instructor resources. Bassham I Irwin Nardone I Wallace New and updated exercises and examples throughout the text allow students to practice and apply what they learn. MD DALIM #1062017 12/13/09 CYAN MAG YELO BLK Chapter 12 features an expanded and reorganized discussion of evaluating Internet sources. Critical Thinking thinking, using real-world examples and a proven step-by-step approach. A student ' s Introduction A student's Introduction everyday culture and critical thinking. It covers all the basics of critical Critical Thinking Ba ssha m I Irwin I Nardone I Wall ace CRITICAL THINKING A STUDENT’S INTRODUCTION FOURTH EDITION Gregory Bassham William Irwin Henry Nardone James M. Wallace King’s College TM bas07437_fm_i-xvi.indd i 11/24/09 9:53:56 AM TM Published by McGraw-Hill...

Words: 246535 - Pages: 987

Premium Essay

Marketing

...fourth EDItION Critical Thinking A student ' s Introduction Ba ssha m I I rwi n I N ardon e I Wal l ac e CRITICAL THINKING A STUDENT’S INTRODUCTION FOURTH EDITION Gregory Bassham William Irwin Henry Nardone James M. Wallace King’s College TM TM Published by McGraw-Hill, an imprint of The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 1221 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10020. Copyright © 2011, 2008, 2005, 2002. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written consent of The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., including, but not limited to, in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or broadcast for distance learning. This book is printed on acid-free paper. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 DOC/DOC 0 ISBN: 978-0-07-340743-2 MHID: 0-07-340743-7 Vice President, Editorial: Michael Ryan Director, Editorial: Beth Mejia Sponsoring Editor: Mark Georgiev Marketing Manager: Pam Cooper Managing Editor: Nicole Bridge Developmental Editor: Phil Butcher Project Manager: Lindsay Burt Manuscript Editor: Maura P. Brown Design Manager: Margarite Reynolds Cover Designer: Laurie Entringer Production Supervisor: Louis Swaim Composition: 11/12.5 Bembo by MPS Limited, A Macmillan Company Printing: 45# New Era Matte, R. R. Donnelley & Sons Cover Image: © Brand X/JupiterImages Credits: The credits section for this book begins on page C-1 and is considered...

Words: 240232 - Pages: 961