Free Essay

Azda

In:

Submitted By hsnmhmud
Words 8018
Pages 33
John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series

When Does Gender Matter in Negotiation?
Hannah Riley and Kathleen L. McGinn September 2002 RWP02-036

The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or Harvard University. All works posted here are owned and copyrighted by the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only.

1

When Does Gender Matter in Negotiation?

Hannah Riley John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University 79 JFK Street, Cambridge, MA 02138 (617) 496-4717

Kathleen L. McGinn Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University Soldiers Field, Boston, MA 02163 (617) 495-6901

The authors thank Linda Babcock, Max Bazerman, Jim Sebenius and the reviewers of the 2002 Academy of Management meeting for their helpful comments on this paper.

2

3 Abstract We propose that two situational dimensions moderate gender effects in negotiation. Structural ambiguity refers to potential variation in a party’s perception of the bargaining range and appropriate standards for agreement. Gender triggers are situational factors that make gender salient and relevant to behavior or expectations. Based on a review of field and experimental data and social psychological theory on individual difference, we explain how structural ambiguity and gender triggers make negotiations ripe for gender effects.

4 Gender often appears to have economically material implications in negotiations in organizations and markets. But researchers’ attempts to tie the phenomenon down in the lab have produced a tangled web of largely contradictory results. By the mid-1980s, the leading experimental researchers in negotiation had tossed the gender variable into a heap of discarded individual difference predictors—ranging from race to authoritarianism—which had failed over scores of tests to produce consistent results. “From what is known now,” one review concluded, “it does not appear that there is any single personality type or characteristic [including gender] that is directly and clearly linked to success in negotiation” (Lewicki & Litterer, 1985: 276). Contemporary feminist ideals of minimalist sex differences further reinforced this perspective. Much of the relevant feminist research of that era sought “to shatter stereotypes about women’s characteristics and change people’s attitudes by proving that women and men are essentially equivalent in their personalities, behavioral tendencies, and intellectual abilities” (Eagly, 1995: 149). By the 1990s most of the negotiation field had wandered away, politically correct and seemingly empty handed, from the investigation of gender effects. There remained, however, recurrent indications from the field that gender could materially affect negotiations. Take, for example, the experiences of men and women entrepreneurs. In 1999, women entrepreneurs in the U.S. started 40% of new businesses, yet made only 9% of total investment deals, and garnered a mere 2.3% of investment dollars (Almer, 2000; Rosenthal & Rodrigues, 2000). There are multiple explanations offered for the gender gap in venture funding, ranging from quality of life choices to ownership preferences (Prakash, 2000). However, some with direct experience point to differences in the way men and women entrepreneurs have approached their negotiations with prospective investors. Joanna Rees Gallanter, a veteran of the venture capital community, conjectured:

5 Men and women are fundamentally different creatures. Swagger paves the way to successful venture capital deals [and]…women are often not comfortable talking about what they are worth. They'll go in to pitch a project and naturally put a lower value on it than men do (Almer, 2000). Kay Koplovitz, chairwoman of the National Women's Business Council, also has argued that the gender gap in venture funding is related to women’s relative unwillingness to self-promote: "I don't think women are as boastful and bald-faced about their business as men” (Thomas, 2000). Perhaps for related reasons, salary negotiations are another arena in which gender gaps are well documented (Gerhart & Rynes, 1991; Kolb & Putnam, 1995; Stevens, Bavetta, & Gist, 1993). Laboratory and field studies suggest that women tend to enter salary negotiations with lower pay expectations, which are then ultimately fulfilled (Major & Konar, 1984; Major, Vanderslice, & McFarlin, 1984b; Stevens et al., 1993). One field study of MBA salary negotiations found that males negotiated significantly higher increases on initial salary offers than did female peers (Gerhart & Rynes, 1991: 256). Other studies suggest that many men and women assume that gender differences in negotiation exist and that they act consciously or unconsciously upon that assumption. One experiment based on a single-offer bargaining simulation (“ultimatum game”) showed that, when the bidders knew their partner’s gender from a simple name cue, both males and females made significantly lower (more competitive) offers to female respondents (Solnick, 2001). Business Week publicized the conclusion from this study that, “despite significant increases in women's relative wages in recent decades, both sexes may still feel that women will accept lower pay than men and that women are more malleable in a bargaining situation” (Koretz, 2001). Gender-based offer behavior have been observed in other non-salary-related contexts.

6 Similar results to the ultimatum game experiment were obtained in a separate study based on a “trust game,” in which parties may withhold or exchange back and forth a growing pot of money. When the initial passing party, whether male or female, knew the receiving party was male, the money was passed significantly more often than when the receiver was female (Croson & Buchan, 1999). In another recent study of MBA classroom negotiations over a real-estate sale, male and female sellers reported setting significantly higher intended initial offers when assigned to negotiate with female as opposed to male buyers (Riley, 2000). Similarly, field investigations of car sale negotiations have demonstrated that, controlling for the buyers’ appearance (e.g., attractiveness, indicators of SES) and bargaining script, male and female dealers made higher first and final offers to female than to male buyers (Ayres, 1991). How can it be that gender differences seem so pronounced in certain domains and invisible in others? Findings from gender research mirror the inductive conclusions one is likely to draw from daily experience: men do not consistently act one way and women another— sometimes gender matters, and sometimes it does not. The objective of this article is to propose an overarching theoretical framework for studying the conditions that foster, shape or suppress the effects of gender on negotiation expectations and performance. PREVIOUS APPROACHES TO THE STUDY OF GENDER IN NEGOTIATION There have been two major streams of research on gender in negotiation. The first surged and largely subsided with trends in psychological research on individual differences in the 1970s and 1980s. The second emerged as a feminist critique of the negotiation field in the 1990s. The original wave of psychological research on gender as an individual difference in negotiation rested on the premise that gender would be a stable and reliable predictor of bargaining behavior and performance. Consistent with social stereotypes of the “communal”

7 female and “agentic” male (Bakan, 1966), researchers tested whether female negotiators would be more cooperative and less self-interested than their male peers (e.g., Calhoun & Smith, 1999; Dawes, McTavish, & Shaklee, 1977; Eckel & Grossman, Forthcoming; Elliott, Hayward, & Canon, 1998; Kimmel, Pruitt, Magenau, Konar-Goldband, & Carnevale, 1980; Mason, Phillips, & Redington, 1991; Meeker, 1983; Sell, 1997; Walters, Stuhlmacher, & Meyer, 1998). These studies and numerous others produced an assortment of seemingly contradictory findings (Rubin & Brown, 1975; Thompson, 1990; Walters et al., 1998; Watson, 1994). The two most extensive cross-study evaluations of gender and negotiator behavior were Rubin and Brown’s (1975) literature review and Walters et al.’s (1998) meta-analysis. Both investigations suggested that to the extent that gender differences did emerge, they were on average small and seemed to hold only under particular circumstances. Female negotiators tended to be more cooperative than male negotiators, but also more responsive to the behavior of their negotiating partner. Meta-analytic results indicated, for instance, that females were significantly more competitive than males when their partners played tit-for-tat strategies in prisoner’s dilemma (PD) game structures (Walters et al., 1998). Rubin and Brown (1975) similarly observed that females appeared to be less forgiving of defection in repeated PD play. Because the effects of gender and other individual differences on negotiation were likely to interact in complex ways with situational factors, Thompson proposed that “a contingency approach may have more predictive validity than a direct-effects model” (1990: 530). However, in the absence of a comprehensive theory, she argued, such situational interactions would be difficult to identify. Lacking an overarching theory or clear-cut results, most experimentalists within the negotiation field discarded gender effects as spurious (Bazerman, Curhan, & Moore, 2000; Lewicki & Litterer, 1985; Thompson, 1990).

8 In the 1990s, leading feminists within the negotiation field offered an alternative conceptualization of the role of gender as “a belief system that structures and gives meaning to social interactions” (Kolb & Putnam, 1995: 7). Feminist scholars critiqued the discourse of negotiation analysis for its stereotypically masculine characterization of negotiators as boundedly rational, utility-maximizing individuals or agents who are engaged in competitive, transactional interaction (Gray, 1994; Kolb & Putnam, 1995). They argued that this “androcentrism” (Bem, 1993) perpetuated a hierarchical relationship by “which male experience becomes the norm and feminine is seen as different” (Kolb & Putnam, 1995: 7). By reifying the masculine image of the negotiator, what is feminine, by definition, fails to fit the model for success (Ely & Meyerson, 2000). Another deeply contextual, qualitative stream of feminist analysis presented an alternative perspective on conflict and negotiation, which de-emphasized the transactional elements of negotiation and brought social and relational dynamics to the fore (Gwartney-Gibbs, 1994; Kolb, 1992; Kolb & Coolidge, 1991; Putnam & Kolb, 2000; Taylor & Beinstein Miller, 1994). The feminist literature has enriched the field by challenging scholars and practitioners to reevaluate taken-for-granted views of negotiation, but this work has not provided a theoretical basis for advancing the empirical investigation of gender effects. A SITUATIONAL PERSPECTIVE ON GENDER IN NEGOTIATION We propose a conceptualization of the role of gender in negotiation that is distinct from previous characterizations of gender as a stable individual trait or de-individualized social construct. We propose a situational perspective on gender in negotiation, which starts with the fundamental Lewinian premise that social behavior is the product of the individual in interaction with the situation (Lewin, 1936). We propose that there are predictable (as opposed to stable) gender differences in negotiation, which are systematically contingent upon the presence or

9 absence of particular situational cues. Consistent with Deaux and Major’s (1987) interactive model of gender in social behavior, we expect the effects of gender to vary across negotiating situations, and we aim to identify the conditions that elicit, alter or suppress gender effects. Situational Moderators of Gender Differences: Ambiguity and Precipitating Situations There is a great deal of evidence to suggest that gender differences in social behavior stem not only from the “hard-wired” propensities of one sex versus the other, but also from the fulfillment of stereotypic gender roles (Eagly, 1987; Eagly & Wood, 1991; Towson, Zanna, & MacDonald, 1989) and performance expectations (Beyer & Bowden, 1997; Steele, 1997). In order to predict when gender is most likely to affect social behavior, we should identify those situations that foster or suppress the emergence of individual differences, in general, and those situations that trigger gender-based behavior and performance expectations, in particular. Below, we introduce two fundamental situational moderators that have been shown to influence the extent to which individual difference predicts social behavior. The first is the psychological strength of the situation (Mischel, 1977) and the second is the presence of precipitating factors (Snyder & Ickes, 1985). We later adapt these ideas to the negotiation context. According to Mischel (1977), the psychological strength of a situation is measured by the extent to which it is uniformly encoded, it induces uniform expectancies as to the appropriate pattern of response, it provides incentives to engage in the expected response pattern, and the skills required to engage in the response pattern are generally held. Snyder and Ickes explain, because psychologically strong situations “provide salient cues to guide behavior and have a fairly high degree of structure and definition,” they suppress reliance on individual differences. Because weak situations, in contrast, “do not offer salient cues to guide behavior and are relatively unstructured and ambiguous,” they foster the potential for individual differences to

10 influence social behavior (1985: 904). Gender and other individual differences have more influence in ambiguous situations because the actors are required to improvise rather than follow a clearly prescribed script (Dykman, Abramson, Alloy, & Hartlage, 1989; Eysenck, Mogg, May, Richards, & Mathews, 1991; Hock, Krohne, & Kaiser, 1996; Lambert & Wedell, 1991; MacLeod & Cohen, 1993; Monson, Hesley, & Chernick, 1981). Improvisation requires the actor to draw upon internal cues, such as attitudes, traits, values (Duval & Wicklund, 1972; Snyder & Ickes, 1985) and/or cognitive schema (Dykman et al., 1989) to guide behavioral responses. (See Snyder and Ickes [1985] for a discussion of situational strength and social role theory.) Studies of gender differences in communication style provide a particularly intuitive illustration of this principle. Communication researchers observe no gender differences in routine, well-scripted interactions, such as requests for information at a booth or in the sale of train tickets (Aries, 1987; Brouwer, Gerritsen, & De Haan, 1979; Crosby & Nyquist, 1977), but they do observe significant divergence in the expressive styles of males and females in private and unstructured conversational contexts (Aries, 1987; Edelsky, 1981; Soskin & Joh, 1963). Experimental social psychologists have tested directly the effects of situational ambiguity on the emergence of gender differences in social interaction. Dovidio and colleagues demonstrated that the manipulation of information predictive of performance on an interactive task (viz., expertise or resources) moderated the effect of gender on nonverbal behavior in mixed-sex pairs (Dovidio, Ellyson, Keating, & Heltman, 1988). In the absence of any information predictive of task performance, “visual dominance” (i.e., the ratio of looking when speaking to looking when listening) was positively correlated with gender. Males’ nonverbal behavior toward female counterparts was significantly more visually dominating than the females’ nonverbal behavior toward male counterparts. When the experimenters created a clear

11 expertise or resource asymmetry within the pair, “visual dominance” was positively correlated with having relatively greater expertise or resources for the task and unrelated to gender. Wood and Karten (1986) produced similar results in a mixed-gender groupdecisionmaking experiment in which information about task competence was experimentally manipulated by providing (false) positive or negative feedback on a test. In a control condition where the experimenters provided no external assessments of task competence, competence perceptions and social behavior were correlated with sex. Males (as compared to females) were perceived to be more competent and engaged in more task behavior and less social behavior. When the participants received test scores indicating asymmetric levels of task competence within the group, measures of perceived competence and task-oriented social behavior were correlated with test scores and unrelated to gender. Brenda Major and colleagues’ investigations of the entitlement effect in compensation fit the same pattern of interaction between situational ambiguity and gender. In the absence of clear compensation standards, females (as compared to males) reward themselves less for equivalent labor (Callahan-Levy & Messe, 1979), work harder and with fewer errors for equivalent pay (Major, McFarlin, & Gagnon, 1984a), and have lower career-entry and career-peak pay expectations (Major & Konar, 1984). However, in the presence of unambiguous wage comparison information (Major et al., 1984a) or explicit performance feedback (Bylsma & Major, 1992), this gender gap in entitlement disappears. Ambiguity is also characteristic of those situations in which stereotypes are most virulent, because ambiguity is breeding ground for biased judgments of the self and others (Babcock & Loewenstein, 1997; Dunning, Meyerowitz, & Holzberg, 1989; Fiske & Taylor, 1991). Metaanalytic research on sex biases in work evaluations shows that sex biases are positively

12 associated with the amount of subjective inference required by the evaluator (Heilman, 1995; Nieva & Gutek, 1980). Experimental researchers have demonstrated that the more clearly observable, job-relevant information there is available, the less likely it is that sex will be used as a source of information in hiring decisions (Heilman, 1984; Heilman, Martell, & Simon, 1988; Tosi & Einbender, 1985) and performance evaluations (Foddy & Smithson, 1999; Heilman, 1995; Lenney, Mitchell, & Browning, 1983; Pheterson, Kiesler, & Goldberg, 1971). Sociological field studies indicate that statistical discrimination in wages is greater where job market information is limited (Chang, 2000) and job performance is difficult to evaluate (Pfeffer, 1977). While “strong” situations are likely to suppress gender differences (Mischel, 1977), it is not sufficient that a situation be ambiguous for gender differences to emerge. If gender is not salient and relevant to behavior or performance expectations within the situation, then there is little reason to expect behavior or performance to correlate with gender. Snyder and Ickes (1985) explain that, in precipitating situations, the individual difference variable is relevant and salient and guides the response pattern. Precipitating situations are those in which there are cues, sometimes blatant and other times subtle, for men and women to enact distinct gender roles and/or to fulfill sex-based performance stereotypes. Gender roles are societal norms that prescribe what are attractive or appropriate situational responses, based on the actor’s socially identified gender (Eagly, 1987). Sex-based performance stereotypes shape people’s expectations about the skills and abilities of men and women. Neither social roles nor stereotypes need to be embraced or internalized to influence behavior (Eagly, 1987; Steele, 1997). A commonplace example of a precipitating situation is a sex-segregated workplace. Occupations dominated numerically by one sex or the other tend to be imbued with correspondingly masculine or feminine attributes for success (Cejka & Eagly, 1999). The more

13 identifiable the organizational role or echelon is with one sex category or the other, the more salient and relevant gender becomes to social judgments in the workplace (Lee, 2001). The smaller the percentage of women occupying an organizational position, the greater is the likelihood that women in that position will become the targets of negative stereotypes (Heilman, 1995; Kanter, 1977), receive unfavorable performance evaluations (Heilman, 1995; Sackett, DuBois, & Noe, 1991), and fail to get jobs or promotions (Cohen, Broschak, & Haveman, 1998; Heilman, 1980). In such settings, gender roles are clear, and women who defy the social rules of the situation are likely to be negatively sanctioned for their incongruent behavior. Although there is some evidence that both males and females are rated more favorably when fulfilling gender congruent roles (Heilman, 1995), there appears to be more of a penalty for counter-stereotypic behavior by females in the workplace than by males (Eagly, Makhijani, & Klonsky, 1992; Rudman & Glick, 1999). Communal behavior (e.g., self-effacement, participatory leadership) by men does not tend to be evaluated more harshly than communal behavior by women (Eagly et al., 1992; Rudman, 1998; Rudman & Glick, 1999). Females who act in an agentic manner (e.g., self-promotion, directive leadership) do, however, tend to be evaluated more harshly than male peers behaving in a similar manner (Eagly et al., 1992; Rudman, 1998). Perhaps in anticipation of negative social sanction, women (as compared to men) tend to approach traditionally male-identified roles and tasks with less motivation (Pratch & Jacobowitz, 1996) and less confidence in their performance ability (Beyer, 1990; Beyer & Bowden, 1997; Heilman, 1995; Lenney, 1981). Claude Steele’s work on “stereotype threat” demonstrates how situational factors can heighten the relevance and salience of identity-based performance stereotypes and, thereby, influence the performance of stereotyped groups (Steele, 1997). In one particularly illuminating

14 test of this theory, Shih, Pittinsky and Ambady (1999) primed Asian females to either their gender or Asian identity before giving them a math test (i.e., implicitly cuing them to the stereotypes that “women are bad at math” or “Asians are good at math”). Shi and colleagues found that the women performed significantly better when their Asian as opposed to gender identity was heightened. This research on stereotype threat reveals the potentially “strictly situational” (Steele, 1997) influence of stereotypes on expectations and performance. In sum, there are two main categories of situational characteristics that moderate the effects of gender on social behavior. One is the “strength” of the situation (Mischel, 1977) and the other is the salience and relevance of gender to behavior or performance expectations (Snyder & Ickes, 1985). In strong situations, the behavioral script is uniformly encoded and enacted and there is little room for gender differences to emerge. In weak situations, the behavioral cues are ambiguous and the actors must subjectively interpret and improvise their roles. It is under these circumstances—in which the actor is searching the environment and his or her past experience and mental schema for cues—that gender-based social roles and stereotypes are more likely to have an influence. Ambiguity is not sufficient for gender to influence social behavior; gender must be salient and relevant to the actors’ interpretation of the situation. Moderators of Gender Differences in Negotiation: Structural Ambiguity and Gender Triggers Motivated by the literature on gender in social behavior, the purpose of this article is to propose the conceptual underpinning for a parsimonious contingency theory of gender effects in negotiation. We apply the notions of “strong” (Mischel, 1977) and “precipitating” (Snyder & Ickes, 1985) situations to the study of gender in negotiations. Translated into the negotiation context, we conceptualize these constructs in terms of “structural ambiguity” and “gender triggers” and propose that they interact to moderate the effects of gender on negotiation.

15 Structural Ambiguity Parties’ perceptions of the economic structure of a negotiation strongly shape their behavior and performance expectations. The economic structure of a negotiation is a function of the pool of resources potentially available for distribution by the parties and the likely coordination points for agreement (Raiffa, 1982). The pool can be fixed, as in a single-issue price negotiation, or variable, as in a multiple-issue negotiation in which additional value can be created by trading on differences in preferences, expectations, etc (Lax & Sebenius, 1986). Focal points (e.g., a 50-50 split) and other standards for agreement (e.g., market values or social norms of fairness) help parties to coordinate on a specific agreement point out of the potentially infinite set of possibilities (Schelling, 1980). The term structural ambiguity refers to the degree of potential variation in a party’s interpretation of the economic structure of the negotiation. This notion of structural ambiguity differs from the game theoretic concepts of “‘structural uncertainty…surrounding the parameters of the game” or “‘strategic uncertainty…surrounding the purposeful behavior of the players” (Brandenburger, 1996:222). Uncertainty refers to situations in which probabilistic estimates are known. Ambiguity, in contrast, refers to situations in which the probabilities over alternatives, and even potentially the nature of the alternatives, are unknown (March, 1988). In a perfectly structurally unambiguous situation, both negotiators would know the dimensions of the pool of resources available and would mutually recognize a clear focal point for distribution of those resources. Consistent with Mischel’s (1977) definition of a “strong” situation, a structurally unambiguous negotiation would be uniformly encoded, it would induce uniform expectancies as to the appropriate response pattern, and the parties would have the ability and incentive to complete the mutually obvious transaction. For example, in a laboratory

16 study of negotiations as improvisations, McGinn and Keros (In press) found that price negotiations between friends involved almost no structural ambiguity. The pairs shared an understanding of the bargaining range and the preferred agreement was obvious to both (i.e., “an even split”). Under such circumstances, we would not predict gender differences to emerge. In a relatively structurally ambiguous negotiation, parties rely on cues from the negotiating context (e.g., the gender of their negotiating partner) and on their prior experience and preconceived notions (e.g., gender-based behavior or performance expectations) to inform their behavior and performance expectations for the negotiation. Other research has shown that heightened structural ambiguity increases the potential for cognitive biases to influence negotiators’ performance expectations and outcomes (Bazerman et al., 2000; Messick & Sentis, 1983; Roth & Murninghan, 1982; Thompson & Hrebec, 1996; Thompson & Loewenstein, 1992). We predict that when structural ambiguity is high, there will be greater potential for gender as well—if it is relevant and salient—to influence parties’ expectations and performance. In laboratory and classroom negotiations, participants typically are told who the parties are and what their own (and sometimes others’) interests are, the issues to be negotiated are clearly delineated to all parties, and the value of agreement options and the alternatives to negotiation are objectively known. This is helpful for eliciting measurable and comparable outcome data. In practice, however, such a low level of structural ambiguity is rare. It is more common in real-world negotiations that the parties have to estimate the available pool of resources and determine for themselves what constitutes an attractive or unacceptable offer. We suspect that variation in the degree of structural ambiguity across field and experimental negotiation contexts could help to explain some of the inconsistency in the research findings. Gender Triggers

17 Gender triggers are situational characteristics that make gender salient and relevant to behavior and/or performance expectations. If there is sufficient structural ambiguity to allow for subjective interpretation and individual improvisation, gender triggers can influence negotiators by effectively cuing them to fulfill gender-specific scripts. Potential gender triggers within negotiation are numerous and varied. The key is that they implicitly or explicitly heighten the parties’ awareness of gender as a social factor, not that they necessarily produce identical outcomes (e.g., “gender triggers” do not necessarily favor male over female negotiators). Gender-based social roles are one form of gender trigger. Gender roles have the potential to influence negotiators by placing constraints on what is viewed as attractive or appropriate negotiating behavior (Eagly, 1987). When gender roles are salient, a set of behaviors enacted by a man may be viewed differently than that same set of behaviors enacted by a woman (Eagly et al., 1992; Rudman, 1998). Gender-based performance stereotypes are another example. Stereotypes that are widely held or implicitly activated influence negotiation outcomes by creating a dynamic of fulfilled expectations about how well one negotiator (the self or other) is likely to perform based on his or her socially identified gender (Beyer & Bowden, 1997; Kray, Thompson, & Galinsky, 2001; Lenney, 1981). Explicitly activated stereotypes (e.g., a blunt insinuation of male superiority on a task) can have the opposite effect. Kray and colleagues found that exposure to explicit sex-stereotypes elicits a form of “reactance” (Brehm, 1966) that produces counterstereotypic negotiation results (Kray et al., 2001). The following section describes two examples of gender triggers and their predicted influence on negotiation outcomes. Economic structure of the negotiation: Fixed-sum v. variable sum payoffs. We propose that the consistency between the economic structure of the negotiation and stereotypes of

18 masculine versus feminine behavior is one potential gender trigger. According to the Bem SexRole Inventory (BSRI), being “masculine” is associated with being (among other things) analytical, assertive, competitive, dominant, forceful, individualistic, and willing to take a stand. Behaving in a “feminine” manner correlates with being (among other things) compassionate, sensitive to the needs of others, soft-spoken, sympathetic, understanding and yielding (Bem, 1974). Characterized by a dance of cooperative and competitive movements (Lax & Sebenius, 1986), negotiations with variable sum payoffs may call for a mix of these stereotypically masculine and feminine attributes. Competitive bargaining in a fixed-sum negotiation, in contrast, is a characteristically masculine form of interaction. Because of the alignment of competitive bargaining behavior with masculine norms of social behavior, parties in fixed-sum negotiations are likely to expect male negotiators to outperform female negotiators (Beyer, 1990; Lenney, 1981). In competitive bargaining, male negotiators are likely to have greater confidence in their negotiating ability, more optimistic performance expectations, and, as a result, claim more value than their female peers (Beyer & Bowden, 1997; Major & Forcey, 1985). Accordingly, much of the existing empirical evidence that gender influences negotiators’ offer behavior and individual bargaining performance comes from principally competitive negotiations, such as the ultimatum game (Solnick, 2001) and sale price (Ayres, 1991; Kray et al., 2001) and salary negotiations (Gerhart & Rynes, 1991; Stevens et al., 1993). Representation role: Promoting one’s own interests v. advocating the interests of others. Another potential gender trigger and moderator of the effect of gender in bargaining is representation role (i.e., negotiating for oneself versus negotiating for someone else). In the classic opposition of gender differences in social behavior, independence and the promotion of

19 self-interest characterize agency while solidarity and the protection of the interests of others characterize communality (Bakan, 1969). Negotiating for one’s own self-interest is stereotypically agentic, whereas negotiating on behalf of others fits the model of communal behavior. If representation role is a gender trigger in negotiation, its effects are more likely to be observed in women’s expectations and performances across roles than in men’s. Women are likely to exhibit more constraint when negotiating for themselves than when negotiating for others, because the former fulfills an agentic model while the latter is consistent with communal norms of behavior (Bakan, 1966; Beyer, 1990; Eagly, 1987; Eagly et al., 1992; Kanter, 1977; Lenney, 1981; Pratch & Jacobowitz, 1996; Rudman, 1998). Men, in contrast, would not necessarily experience a comparable role conflict. Representing one’s self-interest is agentic, and playing the role of an agent or advocate is not inconsistent with traditional norms of masculine behavior. Consistently, gender differences favoring males should be greater when negotiators are representing themselves as opposed to representing others in competitive negotiations. The Interaction: Structural Ambiguity and Gender Triggers In sum, we propose that the effects of gender on negotiation are contingent on two categories of situational factors: the degree of structural ambiguity and the presence of gender triggers. We predict that at relatively low levels of structural ambiguity, gender is unlikely to have a significant effect on negotiation expectations, behavior or performance. While we hypothesize that structural ambiguity is necessary for gender effects to emerge in negotiation, we do not predict that it will be sufficient to produce gender effects. At relatively high levels of structural ambiguity, we would not expect to observe gender differences unless gender was salient and relevant to the parties’ interpretation or enactment of the negotiation. Clearly, there is a wide range of gradation in the potential structural ambiguity of a given negotiating situation,

20 and there are a multitude of potential social cues within the environment that may heighten or offset the influence of gender. We propose this relatively simple conceptual framework as an organizing construct for the development of contingency theories of gender in negotiation. CONCLUSION The situational perspective on gender in negotiation that we have proposed advances our understanding of when gender is likely to matter in negotiation. As encouraged by Thompson (1990) and consistent with recent developments in the study of gender in negotiation (Gelfand, Smith-Major, Raver, & Nishii, 2000; Kray et al., 2001; Riley & Babcock, 2002), we argue for moving the investigation of gender in negotiation from direct-effects models to a contingency approach. The finding that gender differences are not consistent across negotiating contexts does not justify disregarding those situations in which gender is a significant factor. We should explore the implications of gender in context, and search for the omitted variables that account for the labile nature of its effects (Deaux & Major, 1987, 1990). The theory of the effects of structural ambiguity and gender triggers on gender differences in negotiation offers a conceptual framework for organizing and advancing the existing literature. The situational approach also has potential to contribute to the teaching and practice of negotiation. If we can sensitize individual negotiators to the pitfalls and opportunities embedded in particular negotiating situations, we might better advise them how to shape or frame negotiating circumstances to their advantage. So much of the negotiation literature focuses on how parties negotiate within a given bargaining structure. In broadest terms, our situational approach suggests that more systematic attention should be paid to how negotiators can change the game that is being played. Our aim ultimately is to generate prescriptions that improve negotiation performance in general, regardless of gender and other social roles.

21 References Almer, E. 2000. What women need to know about starting up, The New York Times: 9. New York, NY. Aries, E. 1987. Gender and communication. In P. Shaver, & C. Hendrick (Eds.), Sex and gender, Vol. 7: 149-176. Newbury Park: Sage Publications. Ayres, I. 1991. Fair driving: Gender and race discrimination in retail car negotiations. Harvard Law Review, 104: 817. Babcock, L., & Loewenstein, G. 1997. Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11 (1): 109-126. Bakan, D. 1966. The duality of human existence. Chicago: Rand McNally. Bazerman, M. H., Curhan, J. R., & Moore, D. M. 2000. The death and rebirth of social psychology in negotiation. In G. Fletcher, & M. Clark (Eds.), Blackwell Handbook of Social Psychology. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers. Bem, S. L. 1974. The measurement of psychological androgyny. Journal of Consulting and Clinical Psychology, 42 (2): 155-162. Bem, S. L. 1993. The lenses of gender: Transforming the debate on sexual inequality. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Beyer, S. 1990. Gender differences in the accuracy of self-evaluations of performance. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59: 960-970. Beyer, S., & Bowden, E. M. 1997. Gender differences in self-perceptions: Convergent evidence from three measures of accuracy and bias. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 23: 157-172. Brandenburger, A. M. 1996. Strategic and structural uncertainty in games. In R. J. Zeckhauser, R.

22 L. Keeney, & J. K. Sebenius (Eds.), Wise choices: Decisions, games, and negotiations: 221-232. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Brehm, J. W. 1966. A theory of psychological reactance. New York: Academic Press. Brouwer, P. H., Gerritsen, M. M., & De Haan, D. 1979. Speech differences between women and men: On the wrong track? Language in Society, 8: 33-50. Bylsma, W. H., & Major, B. 1992. Two routes to eliminating gender differences in personal entitlement: Social comparisons and performance evaluations. Psychology of Women Quarterly, 16 (2): 193-200. Calhoun, P. S., & Smith, W. P. 1999. Integrative bargaining: Does gender make a difference? International Journal of Conflict Management, 10 (3): 203-224. Callahan-Levy, C., & Messe, L. A. 1979. Sex differences in the allocation of pay. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 37 (3): 433-446. Cejka, M. A., & Eagly, A. H. 1999. Gender-stereotypic images of occupations correspond to the sex segregation of employment. Personality & Social Psychology Bulletin, 25 (4): 413423. Chang, P. M. Y. 2000. Discrimination by design: The effects of organizational design on the exercise of gender discrimination in denominational labor markets. Chesnut Hill, MA: Boston College. Cohen, L. E., Broschak, J. P., & Haveman, H. A. 1998. And then there were more? The effect of organizational sex composition on the hiring and promotion of managers. American Sociological Review, 63: 711-727. Crosby, F., & Nyquist, L. 1977. The female register: An empirical study of Lakoff's hypotheses. Language in Society, 6: 313-322.

23 Croson, R., & Buchan, N. 1999. Gender and culture: International experimental evidence from trust games. American Economic Review, 89 (2): 386-391. Dawes, R. M., McTavish, J., & Shaklee, H. 1977. Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people's behavior in a commons dilemma situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35 (1): 1-11. Deaux, K., & Major, B. 1987. Putting gender into context: An interactive model of genderrelated behavior. Psychological Review, 94 (3): 369-389. Deaux, K., & Major, B. 1990. A social-psychological model of gender. In D. L. Rhode (Ed.), Theoretical perspectives on sexual difference: 89-99. New Haven, CT. Dovidio, J. F., Ellyson, S. L., Keating, C. F., & Heltman, K. 1988. The relationship of social power to visual displays of dominance between men and women. Journal of Personality & Social Psychology, 54: 233-242. Dunning, D., Meyerowitz, J., & Holzberg, A. 1989. Ambiguity and self-evaluation: The role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving assessments of ability. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57: 1082-1090. Duval, S., & Wicklund, R. A. 1972. A theory of objective self-awareness. New York: Academic Press. Dykman, B. M., Abramson, L. Y., Alloy, L. B. A., & Hartlage, S. 1989. Processing of ambiguous and unambiguous feedback by depressed and nondepressed college students: Schematic biases and their implications for depressive realism. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 56 (3): 431-445. Eagly, A. H. 1987. Sex difference in social behavior: A social-role interpretation. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Publishers.

24 Eagly, A. H. 1995. The science and politics of comparing women and men. American Psychologist, 50 (3): 145-158. Eagly, A. H., Makhijani, M. G., & Klonsky, B. G. 1992. Gender and the evaluation of leaders: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 111 (1): 3-22. Eagly, A. H., & Wood, W. 1991. Explaining sex differences in social behavior: A meta-analytic perspective. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 17 (3): 306-315. Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. Forthcoming. Differences in the economic decisions of men and women: Experimental evidence, Handbook of experimental results. Edelsky, C. 1981. Who's got the floor? Language in Society, 10: 383-421. Elliott, C. S., Hayward, D. M., & Canon, S. 1998. Institutional framing: Some experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 35 (4): 455-464. Ely, R. J., & Meyerson, D. E. 2000. Theories of gender in organizations: A new approach to organizational analysis and change. Research in Organizational Behavior, 22: 105-153. Eysenck, M. W., Mogg, K., May, J., Richards, A., & Mathews, A. 1991. Bias in interpretation of ambiguous sentences related to threat in anxiety. Journal of Abnormal Psychology, 100 (2): 144-150. Fiske, S. T., & Taylor, S. E. 1991. Social cognition. New York: McGraw-Hill. Foddy, M., & Smithson, M. 1999. Can gender inequalities be eliminated? Social Psychology Quarterly, 62 (4): 307-324. Gelfand, M. J., Smith-Major, V., Raver, J., & Nishii, L. 2000. Gender, self, and negotiation: Implications of relational self-construals for negotiations: University of Maryland. Gerhart, B., & Rynes, S. 1991. Determinants and consequences of salary negotiations by male and female MBA graduates. Journal of Applied Psychology, 76 (2): 256-262.

25 Gray, B. 1994. The gender-based foundations of negotiation theory, Research on negotiations in organizations, Vol. 4: 3-36. Gwartney-Gibbs, P. A. 1994. Gender and workplace dispute resolution: A conceptual and theoretical model. Law & Society Review, 28 (2): 265-296. Heilman, M. 1995. Sex stereotypes and their effects in the workplace: What we know and what we don't know. Journal of Social Behavior and Personality, 10 (6): 3-26. Heilman, M. E. 1980. The impact of situational factors on personnel decisions concerning women: Varying the sex composition of the applicant pool. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 26 (3): 286-295. Heilman, M. E. 1984. Information as a deterrent against sex discrimination: The effects of applicant sex and information type on preliminary employment decisions. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 33 (2): 174-186. Heilman, M. E., Martell, R. F., & Simon, M. C. 1988. The vagaries of sex bias: Conditions regulating the undervaluation, equivaluation, and overvaluation of female job applicants. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 41 (1): 98-110. Hock, M., Krohne, H. W., & Kaiser, J. 1996. Coping dispositions and the processing of ambiguous stimuli. Journal of Personality & Social Psychology, 70 (5): 1052-1066. Kanter, R. M. 1977. Men and women of the corporation. New York: Basic Books. Kimmel, M. J., Pruitt, D. G., Magenau, J. M., Konar-Goldband, E., & Carnevale, P. J. D. 1980. Effects of trust, aspiration, and gender on negotiation tactics. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 38 (1): 9-22. Kolb, D. M. 1992. Women's work: Peacemaking in organizations. In D. M. Kolb, & J. M. Bartunek (Eds.), Hidden conflict in organizations: Uncovering behind-the-scenes

26 disputes: 63-91. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications. Kolb, D. M., & Coolidge, G. 1991. Her place at the table. In J. W. Breslin, & J. Z. Rubin (Eds.), Negotiation theory and practice. Cambridge, MA: Program on Negotiation at Harvard Law School. Kolb, D. M., & Putnam, L. L. 1995. Through the looking glass: Negotiation theory refracted through the lens of gender. Koretz, G. 2001. She's a woman, offer her less: A game sheds light on the pay gap, Business Week, Vol. May 7: 34. Kray, L. J., Thompson, L., & Galinsky, A. 2001. Battle of the sexes: Gender stereotype confirmation and reactance in negotiations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 80 (6): 942-958. Lambert, A. J., & Wedell, D. H. 1991. The self and social judgment: Effects of affective reaction and "own position" on judgments of unambiguous and ambiguous information about others. Journal of Personality & Social Psychology, 61 (6): 884-897. Lax, D., & Sebenius, J. 1986. The manager as negotiator: Bargaining for cooperation and competitive gain. New York: Free Press. Lee, L.-E. 2001. Feeling well-paid: The effect of labor market structure and social comparisons on pay evaluation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Lenney, E. 1981. What's fine for the gander isn't always good for the goose: Sex differences in self-confidence as a function of ability area and comparison with others. Sex Roles, 7: 905-923. Lenney, E., Mitchell, L., & Browning, C. 1983. The effect of clear evaluation criteria on sex bias in judgments of performance. Psychology of Women Quarterly, 7 (4): 313-328.

27 Lewicki, R., & Litterer, J. 1985. Negotiation. Homewood, IL: Irwin. Lewin, K. 1936. A dynamic theory of personality. New York: McGraw-Hill. MacLeod, C., & Cohen, I. L. 1993. Anxiety and the interpretation of ambiguity: A text comprehension study. Journal of Abnormal Psychology, 102 (2): 238-247. Major, B., & Forcey, B. 1985. Social comparisons and pay evaluations: Preferences for same-sex and same-job wage comparisons. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 21 (4): 393-405. Major, B., & Konar, E. 1984. An investigation of sex differences in pay expectations and their possible causes. Academy of Management Journal, 27 (4): 777-792. Major, B., McFarlin, D. B., & Gagnon, D. 1984a. Overworked and underpaid: On the nature of gender differences in personal entitlement. Journal of Personality & Social Psychology, 47: 1399-1412. Major, B., Vanderslice, V., & McFarlin, D. B. 1984b. Effects of pay expected on pay received: The confirmatory nature of initial expectations. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 14 (5): 399-412. March, J. G. 1988. Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering of choice. In D. E. Bell, H. Raiffa, & A. Tversky (Eds.), Decision making: Descriptive, normative, and prescriptive interactions: 33-57. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Mason, C. F., Phillips, O. R., & Redington, D. B. 1991. The role of gender in a non-cooperative game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 15 (2): 215-235. McGinn, K., & Keros, A. In press. Embeddedness, improvisation, and the logic of market exchange. Administrative Science Quarterly. Meeker, B. F. 1983. Cooperative orientation, trust, and reciprocity. Human Relations, 37 (3):

28 225-243. Messick, D. M., & Sentis, K. P. 1983. Fairness, preference, and fairness biases. In D. M. Messick, & K. S. Cook (Eds.), Equity theory: Psychological and sociological perspectives. New York: Praeger. Mischel, W. 1977. The interaction of person and situation. In D. Magnusson, & N. S. Endler (Eds.), Personality at the crossroads: Current issues in interactional psychology. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. Monson, T. C., Hesley, J. W., & Chernick, L. 1981. Specifying when personality traits can and cannot predict behavior: An alternative to abandoning the attempt to predict single-act criteria. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 43: 385-399. Nieva, V. F., & Gutek, B. A. 1980. Sex effects on evaluation. Academy of Management Review, 5 (2): 267-276. Pfeffer, J. 1977. Toward an examination of stratification in organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 22 (4): 553-567. Pheterson, G. I., Kiesler, S., & Goldberg, P. A. 1971. Evaluation of the performance of women as a function of their sex, achievement, and personal history. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 19: 114-118. Prakash, S. 2000. Women in business, Morning Edition. Washington, D.C.: National Public Radio. Pratch, L., & Jacobowitz, J. 1996. Gender, motivation, and coping in the evaluation of leadership effectiveness. Consulting Psychology Journal: Practice & Research, 48 (4): 203-222. Putnam, L. L., & Kolb, D. M. 2000. Rethinking negotiation: Feminist views of communication and exchange. In P. M. Buzzanell (Ed.), Rethinking organizational and managerial

29 communication from feminist perspectives: 1-52. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Raiffa, H. 1982. The art and science of negotiation. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. Riley, H. C. 2000. Expectations and gender in negotiation. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School. Riley, H. C., & Babcock, L. 2002. Gender as a situational phenomenon. Cambridge, MA: John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Rosenthal, B., & Rodrigues, M. 2000. Women-owned firms attract investors for business growth. Washington, D.C.: National Foundation for Women Business Owners. Roth, A. E., & Murninghan, J. K. 1982. The role of information in bargaining: An experimental study. Econometrica, 50: 1123-1142. Rubin, J. Z., & Brown, B. R. 1975. Bargainers as individuals, The social psychology of bargaining and negotiation: 157-196. New York: Academic Press. Rudman, L. A. 1998. Self-promotion as a risk factor for women: The costs and benefits of counterstereotypical impression management. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 74 (3): 629-645. Rudman, L. A., & Glick, P. 1999. Feminized management and backlash toward agentic women: The hidden costs to women of a kinder, gentler image of middle managers. Journal of Personality & Social Psychology, 77 (5): 1004-1010. Sackett, P. R., DuBois, C. L., & Noe, A. W. 1991. Tokenism in performance evaluation: The effects of work group representation on male-female and White-Black differences in performance ratings. Journal of Applied Psychology, 76 (2): 263-267.

30 Schelling, T. C. 1980. The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Sell, J. 1997. Gender, strategies, and contributions to public goods. Social Psychology Quarterly, 60 (3): 252-265. Shih, M., Pittinsky, T., & Ambady, N. 1999. Stereotype susceptibility: Identity salience and shifts in quantitative performance. Psychological Science, 10 (1): 80-83. Snyder, M., & Ickes, W. 1985. Personality and social behavior. In G. Lindzey, & E. Aronson (Eds.), Handbook of social psychology, 3rd ed., Vol. 2: 883-947. New York: Random House. Solnick, S. J. 2001. Gender differences in the ultimatum game. Economic Inquiry, 39 (2): 189200. Soskin, W. F., & Joh, V. P. 1963. The study of spontaneous talk. In R. Barker (Ed.), The stream of behavior: 228-281. New York: Appelton-Century-Crofts. Steele, C. M. 1997. A threat in the air: How stereotypes shape intellectual ability and performance. American Psychologist, 52: 613-629. Stevens, C. K., Bavetta, A. G., & Gist, M. E. 1993. Gender differences in the acquisition of salary negotiation skills: The role of goals, self-efficacy, and perceived control. Journal of Applied Psychology, 78 (5): 723-735. Taylor, A., & Beinstein Miller, J. (Eds.). 1994. Conflict and gender. Cresskill, NJ: Hampton Press, Inc. Thomas, P. 2000. Deals & deal makers: At this 'camp,' women learn how to pitch to investors, The Wall Street Journal. Dulles, VA. Thompson, L. 1990. Negotiation behavior and outcomes: Empirical evidence and theoretical issues. Psychological Bulletin, 108 (3): 515-532.

31 Thompson, L., & Hrebec, D. 1996. Lose-lose agreements in interdependent decision making. Psychological Bulletin, 120 (3): 396-409. Thompson, L., & Loewenstein, G. 1992. Egocentric interpretations of fairness and interpersonal conflict. Organizational Behavior & Human Decision Processes, 51: 176-197. Tosi, H. L., & Einbender, S. W. 1985. The effects of the type and amount of information in sex discrimination research: A meta-analysis. Academy of Management Journal, 28 (3): 712-723. Towson, S. M. J., Zanna, M. P., & MacDonald, G. 1989. Self-fulfilling prophecies: Sex role stereotypes as expectations for behavior. In R. K. Unger (Ed.), Representations: Social constructions of gender: 97-107. Amityville, NY: Baywood Publishing Co, Inc. Walters, A. E., Stuhlmacher, A. F., & Meyer, L. L. 1998. Gender and negotiator competitiveness: A meta-analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 76 (1): 129. Watson, C. 1994. Gender differences in negotiating behavior and outcomes: Fact or artifact? In A. Taylor, & J. Beinstein-Miller (Eds.), Conflict and gender. Cresskill, NJ: Hampton Press, Inc. Wood, W., & Karten, S. J. 1986. Sex differences in interaction style as a product of perceived sex differences in competence. Journal of Personality & Social Psychology, 50 (2): 341347.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Cost Accounting Case Study

...Table of Contents 1. The Raymond Group – An Introduction.............................................................................2 2. Applications ........................................................................................................................5 2.1. FLUCTUATIONS IN RAW MATERIAL PRICES..................................................5 2.2. DECISION REGARDING LOCATION...................................................................7 2.3. Fixing of SALE price using Break Even Point Analysis...........................................9 2.4. MAKE OR BUY DECISION – POWER ................................................................11 2.5. MANUFACTURING DECISION FOR RETAIL GARMENTS/SUITINGS ........13 2.6. Export Price Fixing ..................................................................................................15 3. Acknowledgements...........................................................................................................16 4. Bibliography .....................................................................................................................16 1. The Raymond Group – An Introduction The Raymond group was incorporated in 1925 and has now grown into a Rs.1400crore plus conglomerate with highly diversified business interests. The group businesses include Textiles, Readymade garments, Engineering files and tools, Prophylactics and Toiletries. The group is a leader in textiles, apparel and files and tools...

Words: 2613 - Pages: 11