Free Essay

For a Sociology of Worth

In:

Submitted By marceletroger
Words 8730
Pages 35
For a Sociology of Worth

David Stark Columbia University and the Santa Fe Institute

Department of Sociology Columbia University 1180 Amsterdam Ave New York, NY 10027 dcs36@columbia.edu

Forthcoming in Vando Borghi and Tommaso Vitale, editors, Le convenzioni del lavoro, il lavoro delle convenzioni, numero monografico di Sociologia del Lavoro, n. 102, Milano: Franco Angeli.

For a Sociology of Worth
David Stark Columbia University and the Santa Fe Institute

Parsons’ Pact Arguably, the founding moment of the field of economic sociology took place more than a half-century ago at Harvard, where Talcott Parsons was developing his grand designs for sociology. Parsons’ ambitions were imperial, but there was one field that Parsons maneuvered around instead of claiming outright. That field was hegemonic in his time and is considerably hegemonic still – the discipline of economics. Parsons, therefore, made overt signals to his colleagues in the Economics Department at Harvard alerting them to his ambitious plans and assuring them that he had no designs on their terrain (see Camic 1987). Basically, Parsons made a pact: in my gloss – you, economists, study value; we, the sociologists, will study values. You will have claim on the economy; we will stake our claim on the social relations in which economies are embedded. What have been the effects of Parsons’ Pact? First, by limiting its range, this jurisdictional division of the social sciences placed constraints on sociology. But those constraints were enabling constraints: by delimiting a legitimate object of study – society, though not the economy – it ensured that the discipline would flourish in the great postwar expansion of the social sciences. Parsons’ Pact also had another effect, for it specifically established the conditions for economic sociology. Recall the terms: economists study value, economic sociologists study values; they claim the economy, we claim the social relations in which economies are embedded. In fact, Parsons’ Pact is still operative today because the terms of the treaty continue to structure much of the field of economic sociology. Although the treaty has been fruitful, it is now time to reconsider its terms. We did not sign it, and we should no longer be bound by its terms. To realize the actual potential of economic sociology will require that we do our work under new terms.

Economy/Embedded Social Relations Take first the economy/society divide: economic relations on one side, embedded social relations on the other. One can scarcely think of a more fruitful concept for economic sociology than that of embeddedness – reintroduced from Polanyi by Granovetter (1984), and elaborated and developed by him and many others. Central to the embeddedness framework is the dichotomy of calculation versus trust. At its core is the Durkheimian notion of the precontractual basis of contract, and with it the idea that instead of calculation we should be examining the social relations the generate trust.

2

These are valuable insights and even economists are beginning to cite economic sociologists on these concepts. But we would simply be spinning our wheels if we leave the analysis of markets and of economic relations to economists while focusing our efforts on the social relations in which they are embedded. We should break out of Parsons’ Pact. One of the proofs that we can do so is found in the work of Harrison White (1981, 2001). White has basically turned the tables on the terms of the pact. Markets, he argues, are not simply embedded in social relations, they are social relations. Instead of accepting the economists’ conception of markets, he has developed a sociological theory of markets.

Value/Values Let’s turn next to the other pair of terms in the jurisdictional divide: value on the economists’ side, values on the sociological side. On this issue, the formative insight for economic sociology came from the organizational ecologists. Whereas economists look at how firms differ in terms of the efficiency in allocation of resources, the organizational ecologists wondered how firms (or organizations more generally) differed in terms of their access to resources. One of their important conclusions was that legitimation matters. They made legitimacy a variable, and found that firms (or organizations more generally) that were more legitimate have better access to resources. The sociological institutionalists (Meyer, DiMaggio, Powell and others) elaborated and developed these ideas. Like the embeddedness opposition of calculation versus trust, they worked with the opposition efficiency versus legitimacy. An economic system based on value is embedded in institutions, cultural and legal systems based on values and norms. This school of sociological institutionalism has produced an impressive body of work. We can and should do more work along these lines; but we should be clear that so long as we accept this value/values dichotomy, we’re basically running on the Parsonsian track. Here too, as with Harrison White’s transgression and transcendence of the markets/social relations dichotomy, we can point to promising avenues of escape from Parsons’ Pact. I think especially of a group of French economic sociologists whose work is collectively labeled “the economics of convention,” and, in particular, of the work of Luc Boltanski and Laurent Thévenot (1991) in their book De la justification: Les economies de la grandeur (On Justification: The Economies of Worth). Risk and Uncertainty Whereas the American institutionalists start with the division of efficiency versus legitimacy, the French conventionalists can bee seen to start with Frank Knight’s problem of risk and uncertainty. Uncertainty and risk are both shaped by the fact that the future is unknown. In circumstances of risk, chances are calculable; that is, the distribution of outcomes can be expressed in some probabilistic terms. Uncertainty, however, lacks calculation: “All bets are off.” 3

Neoclassical economics, of course, reduces all cases to risk – because theirs is a world of calculation, not of judgment.1 By contrast to this neo-classical view, Knight argued that a world of generalized probabilistic knowledge of the future leaves no place for the entrepreneur, and as a consequence, no place for profit. For Knight, profit is a particular residual revenue because it is not susceptible to measure ex ante – as distinct from rents that constitute contractualizable residual revenue. Properly speaking, the entrepreneur is not rewarded for risk-taking but, instead, is rewarded for an ability to exploit uncertainty. I return to this point about entrepreneurship (however, with a twist) below. But before doing so I need to show how the conventions school has broken the treaty – you, the economists, study value, we sociologists study values. Just as Harrison White has developed a sociological theory of markets, Boltanski and Therenot are developing a sociological theory of value. Their first move is to demonstrate that there is not just one way of making value but that modern economies comprise multiple principles of evaluation (or as they say, multiple orders of worth). One might object that this is not an escape from Parsons’ Pact. After all, as soon as you make a plural out of value, you get values. But orders of worth of the French school are in fact very different from the cultural systems of the Parsonian institutionalists. For my American institutionalist colleagues, values are counterpoised to calculation, they are outside and distant from calculation. More precisely, if values are the embeddings for value that somehow makes calculation possible, it is precisely because values are a kind of anti-matter to calculation. For my French conventionalist colleagues, on the other hand, orders of worth are not values counterpoised to value but are constitutive of value, they are the very fabric of calculation, of rationality, of value. As principles of evaluation they involve systematic associations of ideas – and thus have some similarity to culturalist notions – but they go beyond that similarity to show how each of the multiple principles of evaluation entails discrete metrics, measuring “instruments,” and proofs of worth objectified in artifacts and objects in the material world (see also Callon and Muniesa 2005). As such, I interpret their work as suggesting an entirely different way to understand Simon’s phrase “bounded rationality” – certainty different from its appropriation by Williamson. Whereas we conventionally think about bounded rationality as the cognitive limits on rationality, in Boltanski and Thevenot’s work rationality is only possible insofar as it takes place within the boundaries and through the social technologies of particular

1

It is as if, from the polysemic opening turn of Wittgenstein’s (1922/1999) treatise which begins with the question “What is the case?” they squeeze out the ambiguity and reduce every situation to the question “What is this a case of?” since the problem is simply to find how that case conforms to some category or type about which statistical or probabilistic knowledge exists or can be constructed. Missing in neo-classical economics is the operation of judgment – making a case for…

4

orders of worth. In this latter sense we should probably speak – and with a very different meaning – of bounded rationalities.2

Entrepreneurship as the Exploitation of Ambiguity Returning to the problem of risk and uncertainty, the French conventionalists would respond that conventions are a way of dealing with uncertainty. They are technologies, engines, for turning situations into calculative problems. Orders of worth can be considered as means to transform uncertainty into risk. The limitation of this view – and here is my point of departure – is that it does not give adequate attention to the problem that orders of worth cannot eliminate uncertainty. In particular, they cannot eliminate the possibility of uncertainty about which order or convention is operative in a given situation. Taking this into account, we are in a position to restate the insight of Knight, but now in new terms: it is precisely this uncertainty that entrepreneurship exploits. Entrepreneurship is the ability to keep multiple orders of worth in play and to exploit the resulting overlap. This conception of entrepreneurship can be further distinguished from notions of entrepreneurship as brokerage. In that view, the enterpreneur exploits “holes” in the social field, strategically locating gaps and profiting from the ability to broker among units that are otherwise disconnected (e.g., Burt 1995). In the approach developed here, by contrast, entrepreneurship occurs not at the gap but through the productive friction at the overlap of evaluative frameworks. As an ability to promote productive friction, entrepreneurship is not the property of an individual – it is not, for example, the personality trait of tolerating ambiguity. Instead, it has an organizational basis. That is, organizational forms will differ in their capacity to sustain an ongoing rivalry among coexisting principles of evaluation. I use the term “heterarchy” to refer to the organizational forms with this reflexive capacity.

Heterarchy: Distributed Intelligence and the Organization of Diversity Heterarchy represents a new mode of organizing that is neither market nor hierarchy: whereas hierarchies involve relations of dependence and markets involve relations of independence, heterarchies involve relations of interdependence. As the term suggests, heterarchies are characterized by minimal hierarchy (lateral accountability) and by organizational heterogeneity (diversity of evaluative principles).

Boltanski and Thevenot’s study suggests that I would be mistaken to say that I “live in a market economy.” Markets are, indeed, one of the organizing principles of the U.S. economy. But, as they show in their study of the domain of the corporation, in addition to a market rationality, that economy also has a technological rationality, another organized around a civic logic, and still others according to principles of loyalty, inspiration, and fame.

2

5

Heterarchy’s twinned features are a response to the firm’s increasingly complex foresight horizons (Lane and Maxfield 1996), where dislocations can be anticipated in general but are unpredictable in their specific contours. To cope with radical uncertainties, instead of concentrating its resources for strategic planning among a narrow set of senior executives or delegating that function to a specialized department, heterarchical firms embark on a radical decentralization in which virtually every unit becomes engaged in innovation. That is, in place of specialized search routines in which some departments are dedicated to exploration while others are confined to exploiting existing knowledge, the functions of exploration are generalized throughout the organization. These developments increase interdependencies between divisions, departments, and work teams within the firm. But because of the greater complexity of these feedback loops, coordination cannot be engineered, controlled, or managed hierarchically. The results of interdependence are to increase the autonomy of work units from central management. Yet at the same time, more complex interdependence heightens the need for fine-grained coordination across the increasingly autonomous units. These pressures are magnified by dramatic changes in the sequencing of activities within production relations. Like the production of “B movies” in which filming begins before the script is completed, successful strategies integrate conception and execution, with significant aspects of the production process beginning even before design is finalized. In such concurrent design, the various project teams engage in an ongoing mutual monitoring, as innovations produce multiple, sometimes competing, proposals for improving the overall design. Under circumstances of simultaneous engineering3 where the very parameters of a project are subject to deliberation and change across units, authority is no longer delegated vertically but rather emerges laterally. As one symptom of these changes, managers socialized in an earlier regime frequently express their puzzlement to researchers: "There’s one thing I can’t figure out. Who’s my boss?" Under conditions of distributed authority, managers might still "report to" their superiors; but increasingly, they are accountable to other work teams. Success at simultaneous engineering thus depends on learning by mutual monitoring within relations of lateral accountability. Management becomes the art of facilitating organizations that can reorganize themselves. This capacity for self-redefinition is grounded in the organizational heterogeneity that characterizes heterarchies. Heterarchies are complex adaptive systems because they interweave a multiplicity of organizing principles. That is, heterarchies are not simply non-bureaucratic: The new organizational forms are heterarchical not only because they have flattened hierarchy, but also because they are the sites of competing and coexisting value systems. The greater interdependence of increasingly autonomous work teams results in a proliferation of performance criteria. Distributed authority not only implies
3

On simultaneous engineering see Dorf and Sabel (1998). Conventional design is sequential, with subsystems that are presumed to be central designed in detail first, setting the boundary conditions for the design of lower-ranking components. In simultaneous engineering, by contrast, separate project teams develop all the subsystems concurrently.

6

that units will be accountable to each other, but also that each will be held to accountings in multiple registers. A robust, lateral collaboration flattens hierarchy without flattening diversity. Heterarchies create wealth by inviting more than one way of evaluating worth. Organizational ecologists have long held that adaptability is promoted by the diversity of organizations within a population (e.g., Hannan 1986). The perspective adopted here, by contrast, is that adaptability is promoted by the organization of diversity4 within an enterprise. The adaptive potential of organizational diversity may be most fully realized when different organizational principles co-exist in an active rivalry5 within the firm. By rivalry, I do not refer to competing camps and factions, but to co-existing logics and frames of action. The organization of diversity is an active and sustained engagement in which there is more than one way to organize, label, interpret, and evaluate the same or similar activity. Rivalry of evaluative principles produces creative friction (Brown and Duguid 1998) and fosters cross-fertilization.6 It increases the possibilities of long-term adaptability by better search because the complexity that it promotes and the lack of simple coherence that it tolerates increase the diversity of options. The challenge of the organization of diversity is to find solutions that promote constructive organizational reflexivity – the ability to redefine and recombine resources. Heterarchical organizations are perpetually poised to pursue innovation. They are not only capable of learning but are also capable of suspending accepted knowledge and established procedures to redraw cognitive categories and reconfigure relational boundaries – both at the level of the products and services produced by the firm and at the level of the working practices and production processes within the firm. They innovate in ways that allow them to re-cognize, redefine, recombine, and redeploy resources for further innovation. These organizations “invest in forms” (Thevenot 1984) that allow for reconfiguration and hence minimize the costs of “divestment” or reorganization. Such capacities for organizational innovation go beyond the discovery of new means to carry out existing functions more effectively and efficiently. Under conditions of radical uncertainty, organizations that simply improve their adaptive fit to the current environment risk sacrificing adaptability in subsequent dislocations (Grabher and Stark 1997).

4

“[T]he sphere of complexity is that of organized diversity, of the organization of diversity” (Morin 1974:558). On rivalry, see especially Grabher (1997).

5

“Recombination plays a key role in the discovery process, generating plausible new rules from parts of tested rules” (Holland 1992:26). “Novelties come from previously unseen association of old material. To create is to recombine” (Jacob 1977: 1163). Or, in Harrison White’s (1993) terminology, “values mate to change.”

6

7

Multiple Accounts of Worth in a Silicon Alley Startup I turn now to briefly summarize two case studies of heterarchical organizations in which multiple evaluative criteria are at play. The first is that of a new media startup in Manhattan’s Silicon Alley where Monique Girard and I conducted ethnographic field research from 1999-2001 (Girard and Stark 2002). Pseudonymous NetKnowHow was a website development and consulting company with about 125 employees at the height of the internet boom. The challenge of relentless innovation. Every new media firm that was in the business of constructing websites had to cope not only with the problem that the field was in flux but also that every successful innovation in carving a niche, creating a new product, defining a new business model, or introducing a new technology could be replicated by competitors. Unlike high tech firms in fields such as biotechnology where patents could protect intellectual property, in the new media field innovations were not likely to yield a stream of rents. Under circumstances of low barriers to entry (because innovations – in genre, technology, and organization – could be easily assimilated), firms were forced to be relentlessly innovative. Thus, firms could not prosper simply by learning from their construction projects. It was not enough to master the project form, to codify, routinize, or even perfect what they had been doing. If you locked-in to what you had done previously, regardless of how much you improved performance by your existing criterion, you would be locked out of markets that were changing rapidly. On the other side, if you spent all your organizational resources searching for new products and processes, always and everywhere exploring for new opportunities, you would never be able to exploit your existing knowledge. For the new media companies, March’s (1991) problem of “exploration versus exploitation” could be rephrased as the problem of staying ahead of the curve without getting behind on your deadlines. The distributed intelligence of collaborative engineering. The process of designing and building a website at NetKnowHow, as in new media firms generally, takes the organizational form of a project. A project is not a permanent construct but is a temporary ensemble whose players had been working on other projects before and will move to other projects after its conclusion. Some projects last no more than a month. Some, whether because of their innate complexity or because of indecision or insolvency on the client side, can last five or six months. The typically sophisticated project runs 60-90 days, and this extraordinarily compressed time to market is an important factor in project dynamics. The participants in a project include business strategists, interactive designers, programmers and other technologists, information architects (IA), and merchandising specialists. The challenge for the website developers is to build a site in which the activities of the end user are seamlessly linked to the various other computers to which the site is interfaced. The performance of the website critically depends on the performance of an actor – the user – whose actions might be anticipated but cannot be controlled. It is this

8

interdependence that most dramatically increases the interdependencies among the website construction crew. A programmer can design a beautiful interface between the website and the suppliers, but she needs to make sure that it doesn’t interfere with how the information architect is thinking about navigational issues for the interface to the user. The more the site is truly interactive, the more the various parts of the team must interact. A change in the categories of the database, for example, can change parameters for the graphic designers and vice versa. The more the intelligence of the site is distributed – including, most critically, the user’s intelligence7 – the more the construction site must use a distributed intelligence among the team in collective problem solving. When graphic designers and database programmers speak, the phrase “being on the same page” can refer to an injunction to focus on the same problem, a request to consider how an action will have consequences in another sphere, an opportunity to bring each other upto-date on new methods, applications, functions, and reporting systems as well as quite literally being on the same page of code. The more they must take into account how their actions will shape the parameters of others, the more the web developers must increase the lines of lateral accountability. As a young programmer explained to us in an apt epigram for collaborative engineering: “In this company, I’m accountable to everybody who counts on me.” Multiple performance criteria. The directionality of accountabilities in heterarchical organizations such as NetKnowHow is lateral. But these accountabilities are not of a singular logic. These are sites where evaluative principles operate in multiple registers. If collaborative engineering involves the pragmatic activity of figuring out how everything fits together, it also involves the discursive activity of evaluating how it performs. You build a website that works. But, as more websites get built, you cannot make a distinction between yours and others’ simply on the grounds that yours works. You say that yours performs better. But then immediately you must begin to articulate your performance criteria.8 You cannot silence the talk about evaluative principles and point to a purely pragmatic frame since your claim that you are making a valuable product raises the question not only of what is its value but why. Questions of value – the value of work and the value of the product of work – are central to a web project. At NetKnowHow, some criteria of worth are shared across all communities. Formal credentials are unimportant; actual skills are critical. Not surprisingly, in this project-based organization, an ability to work well with others is highly valued. This trait has several components. First, an ability to get along with others in an extraordinarily stressful and fast-pace environment. Knowing the subtle cues for when and how you can interrupt is one of the skills relevant in this area. Second, an ability to convey knowledge (whether explicit or tacit) to others. Finally, and most
7

See Neff and Stark (2003) for a discussion of efforts to bring the user into the design process. See Hennion (1997) for a fascinating analysis of performance criteria in the field of music.

8

9

ubiquitous, an ability to figure things out quickly. As important as (and for some even more important than) one’s absolute or relative knowledge is the rate of acquiring new skills and knowledge as well as being talented in being able to re-think a problem so that it can be solved. “Picking things up quickly” is highly valued whether within a community of practice or across them.9 However, not all criteria of worth are shared. The different communities of practice at NewKnowHow differ in their conceptions of value and in their measures of performance: For programmers, a good programmer is above all logical, and a good site must be judged by the same criterion. When she performs well, she does so with speed, efficiency, and accuracy; and a good website must do the same. A good programmer can translate – express a functionality in the language of a computer code that is categorical and hierarchical. A good programmer understands the deep structure as well as the quirks and idiosyncracies of the program. When she speaks it is not simply on behalf of other programmers but on behalf of the program. The legitimate tests and proofs of worth are Quality Assurance tests and other instruments that measure the speed, efficiency, security, and reliability of the site. For designers, a valuable designer must be knowledgeable about processes of perception, and a good website must use graphic cues that conform to these processes. When he performs well, he does so with creativity, and the results will be exciting and stimulating. A good designer is also a translator – into a language that is visual, intuitive, and interactive. At work he engages in a visual dialogue with other designers, the client, and users. When this work of translation is successful it makes links to the imagination because both the client and the user live not only in a real world and a virtual world but also in imaginary worlds. The designer’s translation creates multiple links among all these – in the process, making connections between the self-image of the client and that of the user. Exploiting interactive as well as visual features, he creates the overall “look and feel” through which the site achieves the desired effects/affects and conveys a branding experience. If necessary, he has authority to argue with the client provided he speaks as an advocate of the brand. Winning clients, winning audiences, and winning competitions are legitimate proofs of worth. For information architects, a good information architect must be knowledgeable about principles of cognition. A site that successfully applies these principles will be characterized by clarity, ease, and above all usability. A good website conveys information by creating navigable pathways that conform to cognitive pathways. An information architect’s activities are
9

In 2000 NetKnowHow initiated a formal evaluation process for all employees. Each employee was able to choose five co-workers to write evaluations. “Picking things up quickly” was one of the most frequently mentioned positive traits. The summary statements below draw from these evaluations, as well as from our field interviews and observations.

10

valuable because they are based on studies that use statistics to understand user behavior. In discussions with other members of the project, including the client, the information architect is an advocate of the user. The user lives in a world of information that is accessed through tools some of which are more and some of which are less appropriate for the tasks that the user attempts to perform. “Conversion rates” and other statistical metrics of user activities are legitimate tests of a website’s performance. For merchandising specialists, a good website is one that moves product. To do so, a good online merchandiser exploits powers of suggestion. Because the shopper lives in a world of desire, she is open to suggestion. Playfulness takes precedence over information, surprise takes precedence over search, product placement takes precedence over navigation, and pleasurability takes precedence over usability. Proofs of value are metrics that measure how product is moving in relation to inventories. The various communities of practice at NetKnowHow were articulate and adamant about their respective performance criteria. “We yell and scream” was a repeated refrain in conversations when we talked about this friendly rivalry. Discussions could be heated, especially when proofs of worth were not immediately recognized outside of the frames that made them seem so obvious to their proponents. The statistical studies on user behavior produced by the leading information architect, for example, were characterized by a leading designer as “arbitrary,” provoking the counter-charge that this was yet another instance in which he, the designer, was being “irrational.” Despite occasional flare-ups, the temperature stayed cool since the dominant mode was persuasion rather than denunciation. Because every community of practice was a minority view, each attempted to enlist or enroll others in recognizing the legitimacy of their performance criteria. In this process of ongoing realignment (Latour 1986), people spoke openly about seeking allies. We saw this process at work, for example, in a dispute over competing claims about who could speak on behalf of “the user” that ranged for many months at NetKnowHow and was still ongoing when we concluded our field work. This development was triggered by the information architects who thought that they had a special claim on knowledge about the user. Their hope was that every group would start focusing on the user’s performance and that by, maintaining their special definition, they could raise their own performance criteria to a special status to which all groups gave credence. The information architects’ strategy was initially successful: as references to “the user” indeed circulated through the company, we could hear this theme more and more frequently in discussions, formal and informal. But the strategy also had consequences unintended by the information architects: instead of deferring to the information architects, each of the disciplines began to articulate their own definitions of the user consistent with their value systems and metrics of performance. That is, each community developed its own distinctive claims to represent

11

the user. The merchandizing specialists, who had previously seemed to be speaking on behalf of the merchandiser, offered seminars in which they presented their view of the user as “shopper” and mobilized an alternative set of findings. Similarly, the firm’s leading designer, who was genuinely most attentive to the studies of the information architects, came to the defense of the designer who had derided them as “arbitrary,” pointing out that these statistical studies were of limited value because they were conducted at a particular stage of the development of the web. In a variety of settings, he suggested new directions in the evolution of the web that could make these findings obsolete. And, more quietly but quite forcefully in their individual interactions with the other communities, even the programmers began to articulate their own representation of the user. Disputes such as this were vital for firms like NetKnowHow. If the firm locked-in to a single performance criteria, it could not be positioned to move with flexibility as the industry changed and the web evolved. Thus, even the principle we have not yet mentioned – profitability – was not itself an evaluative principle that trumped all others since continuing profitability was itself based on the ability to anticipate new developments and re-cognize new performance criteria for evaluating well-designed and well-functioning websites. Tolerating, even encouraging, such friendly rivalry was a source of innovation to navigate the search for value within the young industry. Collaborative engineering is a discursive pragmatics. It is, at once, an ongoing conversation and an intensely practical activity. I present to you accounts of my work so that you can take my problems and goals into account in yours. We do what works to make it work. We need to talk to get the job done, but to get the job done we need to stop talking and get to work. We give reasons, we explain the rationale, but we use different rationalities. We do not end disputation so much as suspend it. To build sites, we make settlements. For the members of web projects, the process of building websites has the result that things settle down, people settle in. They work out ways of dividing tasks and managing the relationships across their professional boundaries. On many issues they reach agreement. But frequently, instead of reaching an agreement, they reach a settlement. Like the term itself with its connotations of law and locality, our informants at NetKnowHow reach settlements 1) by judicious appeals to other actors who are outside the dispute, and 2) through their highly localized practices. When the incommensurable systems of value come into conflict in a project they are sometimes settled by contingent compromises (often through appeals to the project lead) and by “relativization” (through appeals to the client). In relativization (Boltanski and Thevenot 1991), the parties to the disagreement can maintain their principled position; they merely agree to accede to whatever outcome is chosen by the “outsider.” “So, it’s settled, right?” The highly localized practices of the project, so confined in space and time, further contribute to temporary settlements. Working in such tight quarters creates a forced intimacy and a heightened tolerance. Where everything is overheard and everyone is monitoring not only what is said but also the tone of voice, project team members are on the alert for a pitch of voice that signals an unproductive impasse. “Ok, let’s settle this and get back to

12

work.” Deadlines have a way of settling disagreements. Not surprisingly like those on the landscape of the web, these settlements are more provisional than permanent. Limited in time, localized in space, a project is a provisional settlement. The provisional character of project settlements is an expression of discursive pragmatism. Pragmatic, because provisional settlements make it possible to get the job done. Discursive, because provisional settlements are open to reinterpretation when the project is concluded and the next begun. Our understanding of collaboration in heterarchical organizations is thus more complex than coordination within a project. A frictionless coordination, in which everyone shared the same performance criteria, might make life smooth for project managers; but it would lose the creative abrasions (Brown and Duguid 1998) that are the source of ongoing vitality. Settlements facilitate coordination within projects; the unsettling activity of ongoing disputation makes it possible to adapt to the changing topography of the web across projects in time. Friction promotes reflection, exposing variation from multiple perspectives. Friction can be bountiful because complex coordination is a function not only of the values we share or of the language we have in common but also of our creative misunderstandings.

Searching for Value in an Arbitrage Trading Room In a second case study, Daniel Beunza and I conducted ethnographic field research in the Wall Street trading room of a major international investment bank (Beunza and Stark 2004). Pseudonymous International Securities is a global bank with headquarters outside the United States. It has a large office in New York, located in the World Financial Center in Lower Manhattan with about 160 traders in its arbitrage unit. The challenge of arbitrage. Arbitrageurs locate value by making associations among securities. At the sophisticated level of trading at International Securities there is a sharp premium on making novel, unexpected, and innovative associations. Arbitrage is a distinctive form of entrepreneurial activity that exploits not only gaps across markets but also the overlaps among multiple evaluative principles. Arbitrageurs profit not by having developed a superior way of deriving value but by exploiting opportunities exposed when different evaluative devices yield discrepant pricings at myriad points throughout the economy. As with value and momentum investors, arbitrageurs need to find an opportunity, an instance of disagreement with the market’s pricing of a security. They find it by making associations. Instead of claiming a superior ability to process and aggregate information about intrinsic assets (as value investors do) or better information on what other investors are doing (as momentum traders do), the arbitrage trader tests ideas about the correspondence between two securities. Confronted by a stock with a market price, the arbitrageur seeks some other security – or bond, or synthetic security such as an index composed of a group of stocks, etc. – that can be related to it, and prices one in terms of

13

the other. The posited relationship can be highly abstract.10 The two securities have to be similar enough so that their prices change in related ways, but different enough so that other traders have not perceived the correspondence before. The tenuous or uncertain strength of the posited similarity or co-variation reduces the number of traders that can play a trade, hence increasing its potential profitability. In short, arbitrage hinges on the possibility of interpreting securities in multiple ways. Like a striking literary metaphor, an arbitrage trade reaches out and associates the value of a stock to some other, previously unidentified security. By associating one security to another, the trader highlights different properties (qualities) of the property he is dealing with. As Daniel and I studied how the room is organized for this process of discovery, we came to see that the trading room is a kind of laboratory in which traders are engaged in a process of search and experimentation. They use instruments to test the markets. At one level it would seem that their search is straightforward: they are searching for value. And it would seem that the means for this search are similarly obvious: use channels of high speed connectivity to gather as much timely information as possible and take advantage of sophisticated mathematical formulae to process that information. At the very elite of the profession, however, these means, in themselves, do not give advantage. You must have them to be a player, but your competitors are likely to have them as well. That is, the more that timely information is available simultaneously to all market actors, the more advantage shifts from economies of information to processes of interpretation. Moreover, what seems straightforward, value, is exactly what is at issue. The challenge of search and experimentation must thus be re-specified: how do you recognize an opportunity that your competitors have not already identified? At the extreme, therefore, you are searching for something that is not yet named and categorized. The problem confronting our traders, then, is a problem fundamental to innovation in any setting: how do you search – when you don’t know what you’re looking for but will recognize it when you find it? The challenge for the arbitrage traders at International Securities is, thus, similar to that facing the website developers at NetKnowHow: How to exploit the knowledge they had (to recognize patterns that it had identified) while also exploring for new opportunities (if you like, re-cognizing properties)? Pattern recognition at the desks. The trading room is equipped to meet this twin challenge of exploiting knowledge (pattern recognition) while simultaneously exploring for new knowledge (practices of re-cognition). Each desk (e.g., merger arbitrage, index arbitrage, etc.) is organized around a distinctive evaluative principle and its corresponding cognitive frames, metrics, “optics,” and other specialized instrumentation for pattern recognition (Hutchins, 1995). That is, the trading room is the site of diverse,
10

Arbitrage goes far beyond traditional notions of property to exploring for the underlying properties of securities in such abstract qualities as the volatility of a security, or its liquidity, its convertibility, its indexability, and so on.

14

indeed rivalrous, principles of valuation. heterogeneity that generates innovation.

And it is the interaction across this

The basic organizational unit of the trading room is a “desk,” and it is here that the organization of diversity in the trading room begins by demarcating specialized functions. The term “desk” not only denotes the actual piece of furniture where traders sit, but also the actual team of traders – as in “Tim from the equity loan desk.” Such identification of the animate with the inanimate is due to the fact that a team is never scattered across different desks. In this localization, the different traders in the room are divided into teams according to the financial instrument they use to create equivalencies in arbitrage. Each desk has developed its own way of looking at the market, based on the principle of equivalence that it uses to calculate value and the financial instrument that enacts its particular style of arbitrage trade. Merger arbitrage traders, for example, keen on finding out the degree of commitment of two merging companies, look for a progressive approximation in the stock prices of two companies. They probe commitment to a merger by plotting the “spread” (difference in price) between acquiring and target companies over time. Convertible bond arbitrageurs, by contrast, do not obsess about whether the spread between two merging companies is widening or narrowing. Instead, they specialize in information about stocks that would typically interest bondholders, such as their liquidity and likelihood of default. At yet another desk, index arbitrageurs, in their attempt to exploit minuscule and rapidly vanishing misalignments between S&P 500 futures and the underlying securities, specialize in technology to trade in high volume and at a high speed. Thus, within each team there is a marked consistency between its arbitrage strategy, its evaluative principle, its visual displays, its mathematical formulae and its trading tools. To be opportunistic, you must be attached to a principle. Re-cognition across principles. The desk, in our view, is a unit organized around a dominant evaluative principle and its arrayed financial instruments (devices for measuring, testing, probing, cutting). This principle is its coin; if you like, its specie. But the trading room is composed of multiple species. It is an ecology of evaluative principles. Complex trades take advantage of the interaction among these species. To be able to commit to what counts, to be true to your principle of evaluation, each desk must take into account the principles and tools of other desks. Shaping a trade involves disassociating some qualities in order to give salience to the ones to which your desk is attached. To identify the relevant categories along which exposure will be limited, shaping a trade therefore involves active association among desks. Co-location, the proximity of desks, facilitates the connections needed to do the cutting. To see opportunities, traders use the mathematics and the machines of market instruments. We can think of traders as putting on the financial equivalent of infrared goggles that provide them with the trader’s equivalent of night-vision. The traders’ reliance on such specialized instruments, however, entails a serious risk. In bringing some information into sharp attention, the software and the graphic representations on their screens also obscure. In order to be devices that magnify and focus, they are also blinders. The danger is that distributing calculation across their instruments amounts to

15

inscribing their sensors with their own beliefs. As we have seen, in order to recognize opportunities, the trader needs special tools that allow him to see what others cannot. But the fact that the tool has been shaped by his theories means that his sharpened perceptions can sometimes be highly magnified misperceptions, perhaps disastrously so. For an academic economist who presents his models as accurate representations of the world, a faulty model might prove an embarrassment at a conference or seminar. For the trader, however, a faulty model can lead to massive losses. There is, however, no option not to model: no tools, no trade. What the layout of the trading room – with its interactions of different kinds of traders and its juxtaposition of different principles of trading – accomplishes is the continual, almost minute-by-minute, reminder that the trader should never confuse representation for reality. Just as Latour (1987) defined a laboratory as “a place that gathers one or several instruments together,” trading rooms can be understood as places that gather diverse market instruments together. Seen in this light, the move from traditional to modern finance can be considered as an enlargement in the number of instruments in the room, from one to several. The best scientific laboratories maximize cross-fertilization across disciplines and instruments. For example, the Radar Lab at MIT in the 1940s made breakthroughs by bringing together the competing principles of physicists and engineers (Galison 1996). Similarly, the best trading rooms bring together heterogeneous value frameworks for creative recombination. We saw such processes of re-cognition at work in the case of an announced merger between two financial firms. Through close contact with the merger arbitrage desk and the equity loan desk, the traders were able to construct a new arbitrage trade, an “election trade,” that recombined in an innovative way two previously existing strategies, merger arbitrage and equity loan (for details of this interaction, see Beunza and Stark 2004:.386-389).

Conclusion: From the Sociology of Business to the Sociology of Worth An economic sociology that breaks with Parsons’ Pact will be free to abandon the dualisms of value versus values and economy versus embedded social relations. That is, we will no longer be locked into either side of these dichotomies. In this realignment, the object of study for a new economic sociology becomes the sociology of worth. The polysemic character of the term – worth – signals that economic sociology is concerned with fundamental problems of value while recognizing that all economies have a moral component. From the static fixtures of value and values it focuses instead on the ongoing processes of valuation whether in assessing the value of firms under conditions of competing metrics of performance or in studying incomensurable assessments in everyday life. “What are you worth?” is a question that can be unambiguous when constrained by context (as, for example, when applying at a bank for a mortgage). But the question in an art gallery “Yes, but what is it worth?” already suggests that value might be different from price. And from the question among two friends, “Honey, do you really think he’s worth it?” we know that several, opposed, evaluative criteria have been brought into play. Social life is a place of perplexity and sometimes wonder precisely because of these problems of incommensurability. Political life, similarly, is

16

rich not simply in competition over worthiness but in contention over the very criteria to assess it.11 Thus, although our case studies come from the field of business, the sociology of worth should not be limited to that domain. Just as economics does not claim to study “the economy,” preferring instead labels such as the “science of decision-making under conditions of scarcity,” so economic sociology should claim that its object of study is a general problem instead of a specific domain. By focusing on problems of worth in whatever domain (firms, projects, households, the arts, personal relationships), we can avoid the tendency for economic sociology to become defined as the sociology of business. To analyze the processes of evaluation that are central to the problem of worth, we must further explore a concept of accounts. Etymologically rich, the term simultaneously connotes bookkeeping and narration. Both dimensions entail evaluative judgments, and each implies the other: Accountants prepare story lines according to established formulae, and in the accountings of a good storyteller we know what counts. In everyday life, we are all bookkeepers and storytellers. We keep accounts and we give accounts, and most importantly, we can be called to account for our actions. It is always within accounts that we "size up the situation," for not every form of worth can be made to apply and not every asset is in a form mobilizable for a given situation (Stark 1990, 1996). We evaluate the situation by maneuvering to use scales that measure some types of worth and not others, thereby acting to validate some accounts and discredit others. How am I accountable? What counts? Who counts? Can you be counted on? Will you credit my account? By which accounting?

11

See Girard and Stark (forthcoming) for an account of multiple evaluative frameworks in public deliberations over rebuilding Lower Manhattan after September 11th. Stark and Bruszt (1988, esp. pp. 188-201) develop these issues in the analysis of political reform programs. Similarly, Bach and Stark (2002) explore these concepts in the study of civic associations in Eastern Europe.

17

References Bach, Jonathan and David Stark. 2002. “Innovative Ambiguities: NGOs’ Use of Interactive Technologies in Eastern Europe.” Studies in Comparative International Development 37(2):3-23. Beunza, Daniel, and David Stark. 2004. “Tools of the Trade: The Socio-Technology of Arbitrage in a Wall Street Trading Room.” Industrial and Corporate Change, 13(1):369-401. Boltanski, Luc and Laurent Thévenot. 1991. De la justification: Les economies de la grandeur. Paris: Paris: Gallimard. Burt, Ronald. 1995. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Callon, Michel and Fabian Muniesa. 2005. "Economic markets as calculative collective devices." Organization Studies 26(8): 1229-1250. Camic, Charles. 1987. “The Making of a Method: A Historical Reinterpretation of the Early Parsons,” American Sociological Review 52(4):421-39. Dorf, Michael C. and Charles F. Sabel. 1998. "A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism" Columbia Law Review 98(2): 267-529. Eymard-Duvernay, F. (1994), ‘Coordination des exchanges par l’entreprise et qualite des biens.’ In A. Orlean (ed.), Analyse Economique des Conventions. PUF: Paris. Favereau, O., O. Biencourt and F. Eymard-Duvernay (2001), ‘Where do markets come from? From (quality) conventions.’ Manuscript, INSEAD, Paris. Galison, Peter L. 1997. Image and Logic: A Material Culture of Microphysics. University of Chicago Press: Chicago, Ill. Girard, Monique and David Stark. 2002. ‘Distributing intelligence and organizing diversity in new media projects,’ Environment and Planning A, 34:1927-49. --. forthcoming. “Socio-technologies of Assembly: Sense-making and Demonstration in Rebuilding Lower Manhattan.” In David Lazer and Viktor Mayer-Schoenberger, eds., Governance and Information: The Rewiring of Governing and Deliberation in the 21st Century. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Grabher, Gernot. 1997. “Adaptation at the Cost of Adaptability? Restructuring the Eastern German Regional Economy.” Pp. 107-134 in Restructuring Networks: Legacies,

18

Linkages, and Localities in Postsocialism, edited by Gernot Grabher and David Stark. London and New York: Oxford University Press. Grabher, Gernot and David Stark. 1997. "Organizing Diversity: Evolutionary Theory, Network Analysis, and the Postsocialist Transformations." Regional Studies 31(5):533-544. Granovetter, Mark S. (1985), ‘Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness,’ American Journal of Sociology, 19:481-510. Hannan, Michael T. 1986. “Uncertainty, Diversity, and Organizational Change.” Pp. 73-94 in Behavioral and social sciences : fifty years of discovery : in commemoration of the fiftieth anniversary of the "Ogburn report", edited by Neil J. Smelser and Dean R. Gerstein. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press. Hennion, Antoine. 1997. “Baroque and rock: Music, mediators and musical taste.” Poetics 24:415-435. Holland, John. 1992. “Complex Adaptive Systems.” Daedalus 121(1):17-30. Hutchins, Edwin. 1995. Cognition in the wild. MIT Press: Cambridge, Mass. Jacob, Francois. 1977. “Evolution and Tinkering.” Science Vol. 196, number 4295 (10 June):1161-66. Knight, Frank H. 1921. Boston, Mass. Risk, uncertainty and profit. Houghton Mifflin Company:

Lane, David and Robert Maxfield. 1996. ‘Strategy under complexity: Fostering generative relationships,’ Long Range Planning, 29:215-31. Latour, Bruno. 1986. “Powers of Association.” Pp. 264-80 in John Law, ed. Power, Action, and Belief: A New Sociology of Knowledge. London: Routledge. March, James G. 1991. ‘Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning.’ Organization Science, 2:71-87. Morin, Edgar. 1974. “Complexity.” International Social Science Journal, 26(4):555-82. Neff, Gina and David Stark. 2003. “Permanently Beta: Responsive Organization in the Internet Era.” Pp. 173-188 in Philip E.N. Howard and Steve Jones, eds., Society Online: The Internet In Context. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

19

Sabel, Charles. 1990. “Moebius-Strip Organizations and Open Labor Markets: Some Consequences of the Reintegration of Conception and Execution in a Volatile Economy.” Pp. 23-54 in Social Theory for a Changing Society, ed. Pierre Bourdieu and James Coleman. Boulder, Colo., and New York: Westview Press and the Russell Sage Foundation. Stark, David. 1990. “Work, Worth, and Justice.” Published as “La valeur du travail et sa rétribution en Hongrie." Actes de la Recherche en Sciences Sociales (Paris) #85, November pp. 3-19. Available in English online at http://www.sociology.columbia.edu/fac-bios/stark/faculty.html --. 1996. "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism." American Journal of Sociology 101: 993-110. Stark, David and Laszlo Bruszt. 1998. Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Thévenot, Laurent. 1984. “Rules and Instruments: Investment in Forms.” Social Science Information 23(1):1-45. --. 2001. “Organized Complexity: Conventions of Coordination and the Composition of Economic Arrangements. European Journal of Social Theory 4 (4): 405-425.

White, Harrison. 1981. “Where Do Markets Come From?” American Journal of Sociology 81:730-380. --. 1993. ““Values Come in Styles, Which Mate to Change.” Pp. 63-91 in The Origins of Value, edited by Michael Hechter, Lynn Nadel, and Richard E. Michod. New York: Aldine de Gruyter. 2001. Markets from Networks: Socioeconomic Models of Production, Princeton University Press.

--.

Wittgenstein, Ludwig. 1999. Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus, C. K. Ogden Trans. Mineola, New York: Dover Publications, Inc.

20

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Social Exchange Theory

...Social Exchange Theory Social exchange theory is a social psychological and sociological perspective that explains social change and stability as a process of negotiated exchanges between parties. Social exchange theory posits that human relationships are formed by the use of a subjective cost-benefit analysis and the comparison of alternatives. The theory has roots in economics, psychology and sociology. Social exchange theory features many of the main assumptions found in rational choice theory and structuralism. Social exchange theory was introduced in 1958 by the sociologist George Homans with the publication of his work "Social Behavior as Exchange". He defined social exchange as the exchange of activity, tangible or intangible, and more or less rewarding or costly, between at least two persons. After Homans founded the theory, other theorists continued to write about it, particularly Peter M. Blau and Richard M. Emerson, who in addition to Homans are generally thought of as the major developers of the exchange perspective within sociology. Homans' work emphasized the individual behavior of actors in interaction with one another. Although there are various modes of exchange, Homans centered his studies on dyadic exchange John Thibaut and Harold Kelly are recognized for focusing their studies within the theory on the psychological concepts, the dyad and small group. Lévi-Strauss is recognized for contributing to the emergence of this theoretical perspective from his work...

Words: 845 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Social Exchange Theory

...Powell Warren Tillson Social Exchange Theory Social exchange theory is a social psychological and sociological perspective that explains social change and stability as a process of negotiated exchanges between parties. Social exchange theory posits that human relationships are formed by the use of a subjective cost-benefit analysis and the comparison of alternatives. The theory has roots in economics, psychology and sociology. Social exchange theory features many of the main assumptions found in rational choice theory and structuralism. Social exchange theory was introduced in 1958 by the sociologist George Homans with the publication of his work "Social Behavior as Exchange". He defined social exchange as the exchange of activity, tangible or intangible, and more or less rewarding or costly, between at least two persons. After Homans founded the theory, other theorists continued to write about it, particularly Peter M. Blau and Richard M. Emerson, who in addition to Homans are generally thought of as the major developers of the exchange perspective within sociology. Homans' work emphasized the individual behavior of actors in interaction with one another. Although there are various modes of exchange, Homans centered his studies on dyadic exchange John Thibaut and Harold Kelly are recognized for focusing their studies within the theory on the psychological concepts, the dyad and small group. Lévi-Strauss is recognized for contributing to the emergence of this theoretical perspective...

Words: 723 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Durkheim Did Not Say “Normlessness”

...SOUTHERN RURAL SOCIOLOGY, 24(1), 2009, pp. 200–222. Copyright © by the Southern Rural Sociological Association DURKHEIM DID NOT SAY “NORMLESSNESS”: THE CONCEPT OF ANOMIC SUICIDE FOR INTRODUCTORY SOCIOLOGY COURSES PHYLLIS PUFFER BIG SANDY COMMUNITY AND TECHNICAL COLLEGE ABSTRACT The definitions of anomic suicide presented in introductory sociology textbooks from 1996 to 2007 were compared with the definition given by Durkheim in his own writings both in the original French and the English translation. It was found that only one textbook correctly gave Durkheim’s own definition while the other definitions showed little or no relationship to the original concept. The original concept was based on an analysis of the economy, more particularly the business cycle, and refers only to the structure of society and not to the mental state of the individual. An attempt is made to discover the source of such a widespread and well-accepted error. All of us are concerned about the introductory course in sociology, no matter the august reaches of academe we might have attained. Nearly all of us have taught it at least once, if only as teaching assistants during our graduate school days. Some of us always teach it. The rest depend on it as a basis for their advanced courses, for a supply of research assistants, and ultimately to build public appreciation and support for the field. If we think of the number of students who take introductory sociology in just one small...

Words: 8240 - Pages: 33

Free Essay

Soc 100 Assignment 3 Obesity in America

...SOC 100 Assignment 3 Obesity in America Click Link Below To Buy: http://hwcampus.com/shop/soc-100-assignment-3-obesity-in-america/ Due Week 9 and worth 65 points Obesity in America is considered an epidemic. There are many contributing factors to obesity (both childhood and adult), such as biological, environmental, social, or economic factors. Review the information on obesity on pages 383 to 385 in the textbook. You may also use the Internet or Strayer Library to research obesity and its causes. Suggested Reading: • “What Are the Health Risks of Overweight and Obesity?” located at http://www.nhlbi.nih.gov/health/health-topics/topics/obe/risks.html Write a one to two page (1-2) page essay in which you: 1. Describe the effect that obesity (childhood and / or adult) has had on you personally or your community. 2. Select one (1) contributing factor to childhood or adult obesity. Recommend two (2) preventative measures related to the selected factor that people can take in order to reduce their chance of becoming obese. 3. Discuss one (1) sociological theory that relates to the selected contributing factor to obesity. Your assignment must follow these formatting requirements: • Be typed, double spaced, using Times New Roman font (size 12), with one-inch margins on all sides. Check with your professor for any additional instructions. • To keep this essay short and manageable, your only sources for the essay should be the article from the National Heart, Lung...

Words: 348 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Sociology and the Study of Society

...Sept 20th Sociology Readings (Week 1) Chapters 1 (Sociology and the study of Society) In The Chapter - What is sociology and is it worth studying - What do we mean by "society" - How do sociologists actually study social behaviour? - Why are there different and sometimes conflicting theories about how societies work? Notes - The social world affects us in all behaviours including the most personal and private of human behaviours, suicide. - Sociologists foccus on general patterns or regulatories in certain behaviours in which my be caused or cause things. - Sociogists observe statistics and base theories off such stats - Society is the term generally used as the term that describes are social structure - To have a society there are certain structures that are found that include higher and lower ranks - There are many different social groups found in societies (cool kids, nerds, jocks, fashion, sports ext...O) - A Major goal of sociology is to study past patterns to detect the current strains, and within limits, to predict the future direction of social change - Frenchmen Auguste Comte was one of the earliest social theorists to try and apply scientific principles to social analysis. He laid out many of the basic tenets for the social science that remain valid to the present day. - Sociologists believe that all information should be examined by the critical eye. It is always wise to consider where the information came from, what methods were used, how...

Words: 742 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Finance

...evaluation process, although as per the theoretical view DCF analysis may give more benefit to the organization. However successful completion of a project mainly depends on the selection criteria adopted while choosing the project in the initial phases itself and the choice of a project must be based on a sound financial assessment and not based on impression. DCF techniques are being widely used in both public and private sector. This is the method recommended for evaluating investment proposals. In this method, the incremental cost and benefits of proposals are discounted by a required rate of return in order to obtain the net present value of the proposal. Read more: http://www.ukessays.com/essays/sociology/net-present-value-is-the-most-realistic-technique-for-evaluation-sociology-essay.php#ixzz338dcUR5X Due to the following reasons, DCF method is identified as a best method for Investment appraisal processes, • They give due weight to timing and size of cash flow • Thy take the whole life of the project in to irregular cash flows do not invalidate the result obtained. • Estimate of risk and uncertainty can be incorporated • Use of discounting methods may lead to move accurate estimating and • They rank projects correctly in order of profitability and give better criteria for acceptance or rejection of projects than other method. Read...

Words: 1156 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Should Cannot and Should Not Be a Science

...Science relating to sociology is based upon the debate of how society should be studied. There two perspectives, Positivism and Interpretivism. Positivists such as Emile Durkheim believed that society can be studied with the same methods as all other natural sciences as Sociology is known as a social science. Interpretivists such as Weber argue that knowledge is based upon people's interpretations of things. Positivist sociologists argue that the methods used to study and research natural sciences can be used to study people within society, and that by doing this research problems within society can be resolved and social progress can be attained. Positivists believe that reality does exist and not is a figment of individuals minds which means it can objectively be studied and give factual results. Positivists prefer to use methods of research which will give them easily quantifiable results which they can then use to observe patterns and new laws within society. Positivists aim to find these patterns within society as they can then make general statements about society works. Comte believed that sociology was a science as it shared the same basics with sociology of trying to find cause and effects, and that by applying these scientific methods true objectivity would be able to attained. The view a positivist would take is that reality is not random but is made up of patterns allowing us to research it quantifiably. And that this quantifiable data would allow for sociologists...

Words: 1400 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Janune

...University of Tennessee: Department of Sociology Sociology 110: Social Problems/Social Justice Tuesday, Thursday: 8:10AM-9:25AM College of Nursing, Room 105 Instructor: Holly Ningard Office Hours: Tuesday, Thursday 9:25AM-10:25AM, or by appointment. Office: 243 Greve Hall Email: hningard@vols.utk.edu COURSE DESCRIPTION Welcome to Social Problems/Social Justice! Sociology, broadly speaking, is the scientific study of the development, structure, and processes of human society. This course is designed to provide an introduction to the sociological approach to social justice in modern society. What you learn in this classroom will help you to gain an understanding of the issues that are happening today, right now, everywhere you look. That's what's so exciting about this field! It is the goal of this course not simply to discuss current issues such as globalization, poverty, and inequality, but to be able to use the sociological perspective to understand the history, theory, and broader social forces behind these issues. With successful completion of this course, you will leave not only with an understanding of elements of social structure and the organization of society, but with the knowledge of how to apply the sociological perspective to analyze social problems and issues in the contemporary world. REQUIRED TEXTBOOKS Readings in Social Justice (2nd Edition), R. Scott Frey, ed. ISBN: 978-1-4652-1290-0 Additional readings will...

Words: 1730 - Pages: 7

Free Essay

Captialism & Socialism

...Latisha Pena 07/12/2013 Assignment 06 SO115 Essentials of Sociology Compare & Contrast Capitalism & Socialism Capitalism and Socialism both have their differences and their similarities. Capitalism is known to come from socialists from the mid-nineteenth century and is also known as Pure Capitalism which is another name for Laissez-Faire. The United States, Canada, and Great Britain are countries whose economies are driven by the principles of Capitalism. The vital features for Capitalism is private ownership, for example you own your own property such as housing and land. The second is market competition which means competing with one another, third is the pursuit of profit, which in this case can mean individuals selling items for more than what they are worth and what they paid for themselves . Capitalism has been criticized for leading to social inequality. Another is that the tiny top layer wields vast political power. Capitalists believe that he only purpose of a government is to protect its citizens from force or fraud. In a capitalist society all people can start any kind of business they want. From a purely economic view a capitalist is a person who buys in order to sell for profit. Socialism is quite different compared to capitalism, almost like an exact opposite Instead of the ownership...

Words: 458 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Value Theory

...Early philosophical investigations sought to understand good and evil and the concept of "the good". Today much of value theory is scientifically empirical; recording what people do value and attempting to understand why they value it in the context of psychology, sociology, and economics. At the general level, there is a difference between moral and natural goods. Moral goods are those that have to do with the conduct of persons, usually leading to praise or blame. Natural goods, on the other hand, have to do with objects, not persons. For example, to say that "Mary is a morally good person" might involve a different sense of "good" than the one used in the sentence "Wow, that was some good food". Ethics tend to be focused on moral goods rather than natural goods, while economics tends to be interested in the opposite. However, both moral and natural goods are equally relevant to goodness and value theory, which is more general in scope. Contents [hide] 1 Sociology 2 Economics 3 Ethics and Axiology 3.1 Intrinsic and instrumental value 3.2 Pragmatism and contributory goodness 3.3 Kant: hypothetical and categorical goods 4 See also [edit]Sociology Main article: Value (personal and cultural) In sociology, value theory is concerned with personal values which are popularly held by a community, and how those values might change under particular conditions. Different groups of people may hold or prioritize different kinds of values influencing social behavior. Major...

Words: 1568 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Popular Culture Analysis

...Some minsters have touted this connection as the mixing of the sacred and the profane. This realization has peaked my interest in the areas of the sociology of religion, as well as how religion can not only be influenced by popular culture, but also how certain facets, such as film and music, can function as a religion for some people. In support of my study of the sociology of religion and the classification of religion, I have read and studied the books and articles composed by Johnathan Z. Smith. Despite my own research, it was not enough to satisfy the questions that I had. Therefore, I knew that I had to take my education to the post-secondary level, to provide myself with a better opportunity to find the answers to my...

Words: 895 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Role of Sociology in Criminal Justice

...The Role of Sociology in Criminal Justice A person cannot avoid the experience of making decisions from a list full of options and choices in this life. The choices that an individual makes are vital in determining the shape his or her later life will take. Making the choice to attend or not to attend college is one of the choices a high school graduate has to make. It is essential for an individual standing at the cross roads after high school to be visionary in making a decision to join a college. Attending college is worth it because the knowledge obtained cannot be taken away from you. College education contributes significantly to the person development. College learning is both inside and outside classroom. The college experiences are a reminder that adulthood comes with more responsibility. In addition, it instills in a person the virtue that it is essential to work hard for one to succeed. There exist studies that support the need for a student to attend college. In a survey investigating the importance of college education today as compared to high school education, it was found that almost 90% of the respondents admitted that college education is important. The presentation of this paper agrees with these findings. With the changing societal needs, college education has become important like high school education. Therefore, the perception toward college education makes it important. There are other ways in which attending a college is important. First, college...

Words: 1770 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Soc 312 Week 3 Discussion 1

...questions: 1. According to Heatherington, which group is most impacted by divorce? 2. Compared to research examining single parent mothers, _________ research has been done on children being raised by single-parent fathers. 3. Rules, patterns, or standards that express cultural values and reflect how individuals are supposed to behave are called 4. According to your text, the technical definition of marriage is 5. Interdependent relations, social responsibility, and the well-being of the group are emphasized in _________. 6. Which of the following is not a dimension of temperament? 7. Miller (1989) found that, in day care centers, _________ varied according to the socioeconomic status of the center Sociology - General Sociology 1. Question : Separation anxiety is characterized by a sense of apprehensiveness towards strange people or places. Student Answer: True False Instructor Explanation: The answer can be found in Section 3.3 Self-esteem. Points Received: 1 of 1 Comments: 2. Question : A value is defined as an individual’s positive or negative response to people, objects, places, or situations. ...

Words: 264 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Marketing and Sociology Hand in Hand

...Sociology and Marketing Hand in Hand Written By Yomna, Aiman, Anaa To excel in business, you need more than a solid grasp of math and economics. Business requires an understanding of people -- large populations in particular. Sociology provides the educational background needed for managers to understand their employees and customers. Business leaders that understand sociology are able to anticipate customer needs and respond to employee problems in ways others cannot. What is Sociology?  Sociology is the study of human social relationships and institution. Sociology is a subject that differentiate the alternating matter of society like from race to crime, family to social class, beliefs of similar culture and it talks about the social stability to radical change in the whole societies. The study of sociology helps the individual to understand how human act and realization both shape and shaped by the surrounding culture and social structure. Sociology is an exciting and helpful field to study that evaluates and explains the important matter in our personal live, our communities and the world. For our personal lives sociology studies the social cause and consequences of things like racial and gender identity, family conflict, aging and religious. As for the society level, sociology examines and explains matters like for example prejudice and discrimination, poverty and wealth, crime and law, school and education and social movements. With the help of the 4 main...

Words: 1930 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Consider Emile Durkheim’s Approach to the Study of Suicide. Why Does He Associate Egoistic Suicide with Modern Society and Altruistic Suicide with Pre-Modern Suicide?

...different countries. Durkheim goes on to discuss the different reasons why people may commit suicide. These include people been over- integrated into society or altruistic suicide, under integrated into society or egotistic suicide, having too much moral regulation or fatalistic suicide and having too little moral regulation or anomic suicide. This assignment will discuss all these different factors and will comment on why Durkheim associates different types of suicide to different types of suicide. Durkheim defines suicide as “The term suicide is applied to all cases of death resulting directly or indirectly from a positive or a negative act of the victim himself, which he knows will produce this result” (E. Durkheim, suicide: A Study in Sociology, pg 214). A positive action like shooting or stabbing oneself is the same as refusing to eat food knowing that you will die as a direct result of your actions or non actions. There are exceptions to this definition. Durkheim takes the influence away from individual cases and concentrates on the individual in society. He looks at how certain influences in society can influence a person in society. He does not consider the emotional side of suicide but he looks at the details and quotas of “voluntary deaths” that are posted by each country. This is the reason he...

Words: 1319 - Pages: 6