Free Essay

Health Care Financing, Efficiency, and Equity

In:

Submitted By sieuquay9a1
Words 8614
Pages 35
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

HEALTH CARE FINANCING, EFFICIENCY, AND EQUITY Sherry A. Glied Working Paper 13881 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13881

NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 March 2008

I thank Courtney Ward for research assistance and participants at the conference on Exploring Social Insurance, held in Toronto, November 2006. A version of this paper is forthcoming as a chapter in Exploring Social Insurance: Can a Dose of Europe Cure Canadian Health Care Finance? Edited by C. M. Flood, M. Stabile and C. Hughes Tuohy (Kingston, Montreal: Queen's School of Policy Studies, McGill-Queen's University Press). The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peerreviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2008 by Sherry A. Glied. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

Health Care Financing, Efficiency, and Equity Sherry A. Glied NBER Working Paper No. 13881 March 2008 JEL No. H42,H51,I18 ABSTRACT This paper examines the efficiency and equity implications of alternative health care system financing strategies. Using data across the OECD, I find that almost all financing choices are compatible with efficiency in the delivery of health care, and that there has been no consistent and systematic relationship between financing and cost containment. Using data on expenditures and life expectancy by income quintile from the Canadian health care system, I find that universal, publicly-funded health insurance is modestly redistributive. Putting $1 of tax funds into the public health insurance system effectively channels between $0.23 and $0.26 toward the lowest income quintile people, and about $0.50 to the bottom two income quintiles. Finally, a review of the literature across the OECD suggests that the progressivity of financing of the health insurance system has limited implications for overall income inequality, particularly over time.

Sherry A. Glied Mailman School of Public Health Columbia University Department of Health Policy and Management 600 West 168th Street, Room 610 New York, NY 10032 and NBER sag1@columbia.edu

The most appropriate generalization of the financing of developed county health care systems is that they share no general characteristic. Few systems fall squarely into any single box and even systems that more-or-less do, have evolved in their financing over time. In 1960, the cost of health care in the OECD countries consumed just under 4% of their collective GDP. By 2000, it consumed twice as high a share of the GDP. This escalation in spending is nowhere accommodated without debate or modification. Most countries intend that their health care system -- and its several components – be financed in a manner that is both efficient and progressive. An efficient system minimizes the deadweight losses associated with raising and disbursing revenue. A progressive system redistributes resources from the rich toward the poor. This paper examines how alternative financing systems perform with respect to these two goals. This paper will focus on choices among general revenue, social insurance, private insurance, and private out-of-pocket financing in all or portions of a health care system. These choices have efficiency and equity implications both in the collection and the disbursal of funds. These implications arise at three levels. First, financing choices affect the efficiency with which the health care system produces and supplies health care services. Second, these choices have redistributive implications within the health sector. Finally, the choice of how to collect funds cannot be disentangled from the functioning of the social service sector and the economy as a whole. They have implications for the general efficiency and equity of society broadly.

1

1.

Defining Terms

The principal choices for financing a health care system are general revenues, social insurance financing, private insurance financing, and out-of-pocket payments. General revenue financing here refers to a system of revenue collection through a broadbased tax. All or a portion of this tax may be dedicated to the health care system (although this is generally just an accounting convention). General revenues may be raised at the federal, provincial/state, or local levels. Although often associated with progressive financing, general revenues can be raised through tax vehicles that are also more or less progressive – from a progressive income tax to a relatively regressive sales tax (or a highly regressive sin tax). General revenues are used to finance a portion of the health care system almost everywhere. In countries that rely primarily on social insurance, general revenue funds are often used to cover the costs of nonworkers. General revenue financing usually refers to a pay-as-you-go arrangement, where current revenues are used to finance current expenditures. There is no clear definition of social insurance financing. I use the term here to refer to a system in which some group of people, usually workers, is mandated to make contributions to a health care financing (or, for example, retirement) program 1 . Social insurance contributions are usually either regressive (a flat per capita mandate) or proportional (a flat payroll tax rate). Social insurance financing based on payroll taxation faces the problem that the tax base, which excludes non-labor income, may be

1

According to the United Nations System of National Accounts, 1993, Annex IV, para. 4.111 an insurance programme is designated as a social insurance programme if at least one of the following three conditions are met: · participation in the programme is compulsory either by law or by the conditions of employment; or · the programme is operated on behalf of a group and restricted to group members; or · an employer makes a contribution to the programme on behalf of an employee.

2

narrower than under broader scope general revenue financing (Amelung and Glied, 2003). Moreover, some social insurance systems cap the maximum contribution, reducing the progressivity of this financing mechanism. Contributions collected through the social insurance system should finance the full insured cost of the health program (or a pre-specified proportion of that cost). Thus, the contribution level or rate is tied to the cost of providing health insurance. Social insurance payments may vary with the choice of plan in a multi-plan system (as in Germany) or they may be fixed (as in the US Medicare program). Social insurance systems can employ pre-funding, building up “trust funds” to account for future expenses, but meaningful trust funds (that cannot be readily encroached) are rare. Private insurance financing may be individual (although this is rare except in highly regulated contexts) or operate through employers or other purchasing organizations. Except in highly regulated contexts or in employer-sponsored groups, the price of coverage is related to expected health expenditures – older, sicker people pay more for coverage and premiums rise as health expenditures rise. The concept of progressivity does not have a clear analogue in the private pay case. Under private coverage, people choose both how much to purchase and, by extension, how much to pay as a share of their income. Even in a situation without health insurance, however, health care utilization rises less than proportionately with income (the income elasticity of health care utilization is, at the micro level, less than one). The premiums paid by lower income people are only slightly lower than those charged to higher income people, a situation that would be viewed as regressive if the premiums were taxes. A special (and particularly regressive) complication of private financing occurs through the favorable

3

tax treatment of private employer-sponsored health insurance premiums, which exists in many countries including Canada (in all provinces except Quebec), the United States, the UK, Denmark, France, and Australia. Here, a tax subsidy is regressively distributed in the context of otherwise privately financed health insurance. Finally, virtually all observed private health insurance contracts are of short duration – almost always only one year. This makes it difficult to pre-fund care, except through savings mechanisms outside the health system. Out-of-pocket payments are those payments into the health care system that are made directly at the point of service. In this category, I include full payments (as in the case of pharmaceuticals or nursing home care for those without insurance coverage) as well as copayments and deductibles. A system with only out-of-pocket payment would (in a tax sense) finance health care regressively, since health service use rises less than proportionately with income. Note that the revenue-raising and benefit-disbursing components of these systems work differently over the lifecycle than they do at a point in time. At a point in time, income taxes tend to be more progressive than social insurance taxes which, in turn, are generally more progressive than consumption and VAT taxes. When costs and benefits are computed over the lifecycle, however, relative progressivity can change because higher income people generally live longer than do those with lower incomes. Consumption taxes are paid throughout life and reflect consumption (which generally exceeds income among older people). This means that survivors (who have higher lifetime incomes, on average) will pay more in lifetime consumption taxes than decedents (who have lower lifetime incomes), making this tax more progressive. Conversely,

4

income and particularly social insurance taxes appear less progressive in the lifecycle context. Younger people pay relatively higher taxes, but those with lower incomes may disproportionately fail to survive and collect benefits at older ages. Figure 1 illustrates the composition of health care financing across the OECD countries. In most countries, insurance covers about 80% of health care costs, with outof-pocket spending accounting for the remainder. The structure of out-of-pocket spending, however, varies substantially among countries. In the United States, which lacks universal insurance coverage for those under 65, a small number of individuals account for a large share of out-of-pocket costs. In some countries, certain services are excluded from public insurance coverage and out-of-pocket spending accounts for a large share of costs for these particular services. In other countries, a broader range of services is included in the health insurance package, but substantial copayments are required for all services. Private insurance accounts for a substantial share of health care costs only in the United States, and even in the United States, private insurance accounts for only about 1/3 of health spending. Outside the United States, the private insurance share varies between 0 and 16% (Canada ranks 4th at 11.5%). In some countries, private insurance plays a large role in the health care market, even though it finances only a small proportion of care. Indeed, the prevalence of private insurance (that is, the proportion of the population covered by some private insurance) is greater in France, Switzerland, and the Netherlands than in the United States (SourceOECD, 2006). Countries differ markedly in their use of general revenues and social insurance funds to finance the public share of expenditures. In the English-speaking countries, as

5

well as in Italy, Sweden, and Denmark, general revenues finance virtually all public health expenditures. At the other extreme, in France and the Netherlands, general revenues play an insignificant role and social insurance pays the bulk of health expenditures. Various combinations of general revenue and social insurance sources present different efficiency and equity tradeoffs. An assessment of the overall efficiency and progressivity of tax system usually requires complex modeling. Kessleman and Cheung summarize evidence on the progressivity of the Canadian tax system (2004). Unfortunately, the studies they studies are somewhat dated and do not reflect recent changes in tax structure. Overall, Kesselman and Cheung find that in Canada, those in the lowest income quintile pay an average tax rate of about 17% (mainly through consumption, corporate, and payroll taxes), while those the highest income quintile pays an average tax rate of about 43%, with personal income taxes accounting for the bulk of these taxes. Kesselman and Cheung also report average tax rates by age group and family status. Younger adults and single people pay much higher average taxes than do single parents, single earner families, or older people. Thus, the Canadian tax system is fairly progressive, but progressivity differs across groups. Financing systems also differ in the efficiency with which they raise funds. In general, financing systems are more efficient the less they distort individuals’ choices (around work, consumption, investment, etc.). In this sense, private insurance (without a tax subsidy) and out-of-pocket payments are fully efficient. Tax-based financing systems are less efficient, but their relative efficiency depends on the entire structure of the tax system. For the purposes of this paper, I will focus on how financing affects efficiency in

6

the operation of the health care system, rather than on the efficiency of the financing system itself.

2. System

Financing Choices and the Efficiency of the Operation of the Health Care

A health system operates in an economically efficient manner if health care resources cannot be reorganized in a way that would make all members of society better off. Technical efficiency occurs when health care system inputs are used optimally to address a particular health care need. As technical efficiency depends on the systems used to pay providers, any of the insurance financing systems is compatible with a range of provider payment mechanisms. For example, a general revenue financed system could pay providers using salaries (as in the UK), fee-for-service rates (as in Canada), case rates (DRGs) or capitated rates (as for primary care purchasers in the UK). In market competition, the invisible hand of the market determines optimal payment rates for goods and services providers. There are many reasons that this happy outcome may not occur in the health care system and the market may bid prices up too high. Provider monopoly power or other related payment inefficiencies, however, do not affect the choice of financing system. Payment rates may also, in theory, be established independent of the form of financing, although this may be practically difficult to achieve. For example, by using regulation, systems with decentralized revenue collection can achieve the same monopsony payment rates that centralized payment systems can, as was the case in the all payer rate setting systems that set uniform payment rates for all payers and all hospitals in several US states during the 1980s and early 1990s..

7

Moreover, large private purchasers (as exist in the US, Germany, and the Netherlands) may have enough market power to exert appropriate countervailing pressure in the provider marketplace. System efficiency begins to tie in to financing when consumer choices enter the health care system. The first place this occurs is in the decision to use care. The RAND health insurance experiment results (and common sense) suggest that systems with copayments or coinsurance will tend to reduce the use of services. As countless commentators have argued, there is no particular reason to believe that the decisions of uninformed consumers/patients to reduce their service utilization will be medically appropriate. There are, however, situations where requiring the consumer to face some cost consequences of specific decisions would improve the efficiency of the system. For example, consumers might be asked to make choices between initiating treatment with a less costly drug or initiating treatment with a more costly alternative. Requiring out-ofpocket payments in this context is compatible with any of the insurance financing arrangements. It may improve the efficiency of the system. The effects on equity depend on protections that are put in place for lower income people. A connection between efficiency and financing may also arise in the context of system fragmentation. The difficulty of defining and measuring health care services, the complexity of services that need to be organized, and the problem of hand-offs among services suggest that more aggregated forms of payment – including payment to health plans or provider groups –may be preferable to provider-specific payment arrangements. Organizing care into multiple health plans (including plans with integrated delivery) paid risk-adjusted capitated rates may (in principle) improve the efficiency of care. Once a

8

system is divided into multiple distinct delivery systems, however, consumers/patients must either be compelled or be provided with incentives to make an appropriate selection and stick with it. Consumers can be induced to choose efficient plans by allowing (risk-adjusted) premiums to vary among plans and requiring consumers to pay more for more costly plan choices (as in the Netherlands and Germany). Even in this case, however, any source of financing can be used to make the basic plan payment, and additional payments would be out-of-pocket. Moreover, efficient choice of plans can also be accomplished by paying plans risk-adjusted equivalent rates per capita, and then permitting plans to compete only on the scope of services included in the plan. The options above suggest that achieving the goal of efficiency within the health care sector is fundamentally compatible with any form of general financing. Another element of efficiency, however, is choosing the appropriate size of the health care sector relative to spending on other goods and services. In pure general revenue systems, this can only be accomplished globally, through the political process. Within that process, providers and disease interest groups are likely to exert substantial political pressure to maintain or expand the size of the system. Moreover, since health care spending constitutes only one of many government services, it may be difficult for ordinary citizens to assess the efficiency of the system. The lack of transparency and political accountability of general revenue financed systems has led some analysts to prefer social insurance financing.

9

Under social insurance financing, the cost of health care is more transparent obvious to taxpayers, in the form of a tax rate or mandated premium payment 2 . Moreover, social insurance financed systems increasingly organize their systems into capitated health plans (paid risk-adjusted rates) so that consumers can adjust their consumption of health care and other goods at the margin. The basic social insurance payment to health plans can be set at a government-mandated minimum level and consumers who wish to consume more health care may choose more generous plans, paying out-of-pocket for the incremental valuation. Private insurance systems can also have transparent payment levels and permit consumers to choose more or less expensive health plans. In practice, the existence of employer-sponsored insurance, the preferential tax treatment of premiums, and the existence of substantial risk selection between plans may make it more difficult for private insurance systems to achieve efficiency in the delivery of services. In sum, almost all financing choices are compatible with efficiency in the delivery of health care. Arrangements with transparent costs, such as social insurance models, may reduce the ability of providers to exploit their concentration within the system. Arrangements that require consumers to pay for more costly than average choices may, at the margin, improve the efficiency of the mix between health care spending and other sectors. Empirical assessment of the effects of financing arrangements on health care spending is necessarily constrained by the limited number of similar countries available for study. The OECD routinely collects data on the costs and financing of health care

Note that the transparency of the system may be obscured to the extent that the health care tax or premium payment for an individual also captures a redistributive component.

2

10

systems (SourceOECD). Consistent data are available for about 20 health care systems in the 1990s, and somewhat fewer in the 1980s and 1970s. There is considerable persistence in the per capita cost of health care across countries over time (see Figure 2), even as financing arrangements change. Thus, rather than examining the effect of financing on health care spending at a point in time, I use this extended time series to assess the relationship between financing arrangements and the rate of growth of health care spending over time during each 5-year period. I estimate (separately for each of 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995, and 2000) simple equations of the form: Total expendituret = α+ βgeneral revenue sharet-5 + χsocial insurance share t-5 + δout-ofpocket share t-5 + φtotal expenditure t-5 + ε I also estimated specifications that included controls for changes in the demographic composition of the population (aging) and repeated the analysis using financing composition at the end rather than the beginning of the period. These modifications did not substantively affect the results. Results of the main analysis are reported in Table 1. I report results including and excluding the United States. The main finding of Table 1 is that there is no persistent and regular relationship between the structure of system financing and the rate of growth in per capita health expenditures in a health system. The results including the United States suggest that during the 1990-1995 period, countries that began the period with a greater proportion of health care expenditures funded from general revenues, social insurance, or out-of-pocket experienced less cost escalation did those with more private payment. Conversely, over the 1970-1980 period, countries with more private payment experienced less cost escalation. When the United States is excluded from the analysis, countries with more

11

general revenue financing or more out-of-pocket financing (but not those with more social insurance financing) experienced less cost growth than did those with more private insurance financing over the 1990-1995 period and there are no other statistically significant results. I also examined how the composition of public financing affected the rate of growth of public expenditures over time. The results are similarly variable over time, suggesting no clear pattern. The findings of these analyses are consistent with the theoretical discussion above. While taxes vary in the efficiency and progressivity with which they raise funds, the efficiency of operation of the health care system itself appears to depend much more on how providers are paid and how the delivery of care is organized than on the method used to raise these funds.

3.

Financing Choices and Lifecycle Equity

In additional to measuring financing choices in terms of their impact on the efficiency of operation of the system, it is also important to judge these choices on how they contribute to the equity of the system. The standard metric of progressivity used in public finance assesses progressivity as the ratio of taxes paid to income. This makes sense if the funds collected through taxation are used to fund public goods that are equally available to all. In the case of cash or in-kind transfers, however, equity requires an assessment of both revenue collection and transfers made. Equity suggests that there should be net benefit transfers to lower income people. For any given level of national health spending, the degree of equity in a health care system depends both on how

12

revenues for the system are raised and how spending in that system is disbursed among beneficiaries 3 . In assessing the effect of system financing on system equity, I therefore follow the public finance literature and examine how the difference between payments made and benefits received from a health insurance program for higher income people compares with the difference for lower income people. In the case of a fully private system, this calculation is straightforward. Premiums paid each year reflect expected health care benefits for that person in that year. Premiums each year are, after a non-income related adjustment for loading, actuarially equal to benefits received that year. Lifetime premiums paid are actuarially equivalent to lifetime benefits received. Although the system generates ex post redistribution between the healthy and the sick, ex ante the system is entirely non-redistributive. Social insurance and general revenue financed programs depart from this model in two ways. First, these programs pool all beneficiaries, so payments made in any given year reflect the average cost of all beneficiaries covered in that year, not individual specific costs. Second, payments into the system each year are related to current income, according to the design of the tax system. This means that lifetime premiums need not reflect lifetime benefits. To see the implications of these two features, imagine that income was unrelated to either health expenditures or health status. In a progressive financing system, this would imply that in each year, higher income people would pay more into the system

3

Since health care costs have been rising more rapidly than financing, there are substantial intergenerational transfers in the health care system. I will treat these inter-cohort transfers as progressivity-neutral.

13

than they would receive (and vice versa). The same pattern would hold over people’s lifetimes. The system would be redistributive from high to low income. In most universal publicly-financed health care systems, including Canada’s however, income is related to both health expenditures at a point in time and to health status. This relationship has three components. First, at any given age, lower income people are usually in worse health than are higher income people. This leads them to use more health care services, generating a progressive distribution of benefits. Second, conditional on need, higher income people and lower income people may use care differently, even under universal free access to care. Van Doorslaer and Masseria (2004) find that in about ½ of OECD countries (including Canada), conditional on need, lower income people are more likely to use hospital services than are higher income people, and in most countries, they spend more days in hospital once hospitalized. Conversely, in all OECD countries, conditional on need, higher income people are more likely to see any doctor, to use specialist services, and tend to have more specialist visits, than do lower income people (see also Roos and Mustard, 1997) 4 . On average, conditional on health status, higher income people use the system more intensively and use more costly health services than do lower income people. Third, income is closely related to mortality. In Canada, in 1996, life expectancy at birth was about 5 years longer for men in the highest income quintile than for men in the lowest income quintile. Life expectancy for women was about 1.6 years longer in the highest than in the lowest income quintiles (Wilkins, Berthelot, and Ng, 2002) 5 . Lower income people were much less likely to survive to age 75. While about 69% of
These income-related patterns are partially attributable to differences in access to health facilities in (higher income) urban and (lower income) rural areas. 5 I am grateful to Russell Wilkins for sharing the mortality data with me.
4

14

higher income men survived to 75, only 53% of lower income men did (see Figure 3). Among women, 80% of higher income but only 73% of lower income survived to age 75 (see Figure 4). This pattern of differential survival, combined with similar spending at each age and increasing spending over the lifecycle, reduces the lifetime spending benefits of a public health insurance system for lower income people. This combination of factors means that the extent to which benefits under a universal health insurance system are distributed in a progressive fashion, and the net progressivity of the system, is an empirical question. A small literature examines the net progressivity of social welfare systems in lifecycle context. Several studies have examined this question in the context of pension systems in the US and Canada (see, for example, Brown 1998, who concludes that both the US and Canadian pension systems remain progressive after accounting for longevity) and in the context of the U.S. Medicare system, which provides universal health insurance to people 65 and over. Studies of the US Medicare system, a universal, social insurance financed health insurance program for people 65+, reach conflicting results on progressivity. In their basic calculations (omitting the utility value of insurance), McClellan and Skinner (2005) conclude that Medicare generates modest dollar transfers toward higher income people. Bhattacharya and Lakdawalla (2005), using education, rather than income as the measure of socioeconomic status, find that the hospital benefit in Medicare is somewhat progressive. I examine this question in the Canadian context using data from the Canadian Community Health Survey 2000 6 (CCHS), data on mortality rates by income quintile in 1996 from Statistics Canada, and data on expenditures from SourceOECD. I compute the
6

Courtney Ward graciously provided these data to me.

15

average number of general practitioner visits, specialist visits, and hospital days by age group and gender and by income quintiles, using household-size adjusted income quintiles provided in the CCHS. I then assign a level of spending (intended to include associated ancillary services, diagnostic tests, etc.) to each general practitioner visit ($75), specialist visit ($375), and hospital day ($1000), so that total spending for physician service use and hospital use corresponds (roughly) to the OECD population totals for Canada. I use these data to compute spending levels by quintile throughout the life cycle. Figures 5 and 6 present these spending patterns for men and women. As expected, health care spending rises with age for both men and women. For both men and women, there is a pronounced difference in health spending between the three upper and two lower quintiles from ages 30 to about 55. After about age 55, spending patterns of the groups begin to converge. In late life, spending for the upper quintiles accelerates much more quickly than among the lower quintiles. I next combine these data with the information on survival. Using these combined data, I compute lifetime public health care expenditures in Canada by quintile. I calculate these expenditures at age 12, at age 25 (not shown), and at age 65. These results are reported in Table 2. In each set of results, the first column reports results that do not adjust for life expectancy and do not discount later spending. The second column reports results that adjust for life expectancy but do not discount later spending. The third column reports results adjusted for life expectancy and discounted at 5%. Undiscounted, unadjusted lifetime health care spending measured at age 12 ranges from about $85,000 (high income men) to $170,000 (low income women). Adjusting for differences in life expectancy reduces lifetime spending. For high income

16

men, the effect of adjusting for life expectancy (without discounting) is to reduce expected lifetime spending by about 22% for men (slightly more for lower income men) and by about 11% for women (slightly more for higher income women). Discounting substantially reduces lifetime spending, particularly measured at earlier ages, because most health care costs occur in later life. Discounted lifetime health care costs are between 12% and 65% higher for women than for men in each quintile. The three rows below the quintile estimates indicate the ratio of lifetime health spending between the highest and lowest quintiles (Q1:Q5), the middle and lowest quintile (Q3:Q5), and the highest and middle quintile (Q1:Q3). The patterns are quite different for men and women. Using the discounted figures, among men, lifetime expenditures are about 10% higher for men in the lowest quintile men than for men in the middle quintile, while spending is about 50% higher for men in the middle quintile compared to those in the highest quintile. For women, the differences are smaller. Spending for women in the middle quintile is about 9% higher than spending in the highest quintile, while spending in the lowest quintile is about 40% higher than spending in the middle quintile. Measuring lifetime expenditures at age 25, rather than age 12, has little effect on the patterns (not shown). Consistent with prior studies in the United States, however, lifetime expenditures beginning at age 65 tend to be slightly higher for higher income groups than for lower income groups. The final column in each of the panels describes the redistributive impact of putting $1 of tax funds into the health care system. The modest relationship between lifetime health care spending and income mean that a universal health insurance system

17

can only be slightly redistributive. Putting $1 of tax funds into the public health insurance system effectively channels between $0.23 and $0.26 toward the lowest income people, and about $0.50 to the bottom two income quintiles. For example, suppose all funds for a universal health insurance system were generated from the top three income quintiles. As these quintiles also use health care services, about ½ of the funds raised would be returned to them. The other ½ of the funds raised would be redistributed to the bottom two income quintiles. The lifecycle and cross-service patterns of health care spending also suggest that some forms of health care spending are more progressive than others. Lower income people are disproportionate users of hospital days, perhaps because arranging discharge is more complicated for those with fewer resources (Van Doorslaer and Masseria, 2004). In most health care systems, low income people are less likely to initiate specialist care than are higher income people, despite their worse initial health status. In most countries, lower income people use more hospital days, conditional on hospitalization, than do higher income people. In Canada, higher income people also make disproportionate use of elective surgical procedures, such as hip replacement and knee replacement (Roos and Mustard, 1997). Finally, higher income people make more use of health care services at older ages, while lower income people have disproportionately higher use in mid-life. These patterns suggest that focusing the marginal public health care dollar on skilled nursing days, access to general practitioners, and care associated with conditions that manifest in mid-life will have a more progressive effect than focusing additional tax dollars on elective surgical procedures or specialist care. At the margin, progressive financing sources should be devoted to progressive ends.

18

4.

Health Care in the Bigger Picture

The optimal design of health care system financing cannot be assessed in isolation from the rest of the components of the economy and the welfare state. Public funds used to finance health care cannot be used for other purposes. If health care spending rises, either taxes must increase or other services must be cut. This problem is acute in the case of health care spending because this sector is growing more rapidly than any other element of government budgets. Moreover, the relatively modest progressive impact of spending on health care raises the risk that rising health care spending is displacing more progressive cash or in-kind transfer programs. A limited number of studies have examined the effect of in-kind transfer programs, such as health insurance programs, on the general progressivity of the welfare state. If non-cash benefits are very large relative to incomes, the inclusion of universal, uniformly-distributed, non-cash benefits would significantly reduce measured inequality in a population. If non-cash benefits are progressively distributed, their inclusion will reduce measured inequality still further. Smeeding et al. (1993) use data from the early1980s to examine the impact of including non-cash benefits in the measurement of economic inequality across countries. In that study, inclusion of non-cash in-kind benefits (including public health insurance) had little effect on the relative rankings of countries in terms of economic inequality. In a recent paper, Garfinkel, Rainwater, and Smeeding (2006) revisit this issue. Their analysis incorporates the value of in-kind educational and health transfers (measured at the average cost across countries), and the distributive impact of the taxes

19

used to finance these transfers. Note that Garfinkel, Rainwater and Smeeding conduct their analysis at a point in time and do not incorporate the lifecycle considerations described above. They find that the most important redistributive in-kind transfers are those that provide education to children. Inclusion of these benefits substantially alters the picture of relative well-being among children across countries. Garfinkel, Rainwater, and Smeeding isolate the effects of health spending transfers by conducting analyses that focus only on the population 65 and over. In their analyses, health spending levels vary by age but not by income level. Empirically, health spending varies relatively little by income at older ages, suggesting that this assumption probably does not affect their results very much. Garfinkel, Rainwater, and Smeeding report results for the population 65 and over using average values of health benefits across country 7 . As expected, they find that unadjusted income inequality tends to be higher in the English-speaking countries and lowest in the Scandinavian countries. Consistent with Smeeding’s earlier study of the 1980s, however, the inclusion of the value of in-kind transfers (net of the impact on equity of the revenue collection to finance them) has very little effect on measured inequality, at least among older people. Inclusion of these benefits leads the inequality ratio for the low income vs. middle income population to fall slightly in most cases (by a maximum of 7 points, from 62 to 69 in Belgium) and actually generates a decline in equity in a few cases (by a maximum of 8 points, from 58 to 50, in Germany). The

7

Garfinkel, Rainwater, and Smeeding also report results using the actual value of health care benefits in each country. Using the average value of health benefits (as I do here) has the effect of reducing the impact of high US health care costs on the extent of inequality reduction achieved through health benefit transfers in the US.

20

effects on inequality between the high and middle income population are slightly greater in magnitude, but equally inconsistent in direction. These results suggest that public financing of the health care system has surprisingly little impact on overall economic equality. This implies that the value of health benefits received, net of taxes paid, by income quintile is small relative to income and other components of well-being and, consistent with our findings above, that health spending at a point in time does not vary greatly with income. The final question of interest is the impact of rising health care expenditures on equality. No studies have examined this question directly. Instead, I examine the evolution of health care spending and tax revenue over time. Figure 7 shows how the tax share of GDP and the health care share of GDP have evolved across the OECD over time. The tax shares of most economies have risen substantially since 1975, but there is considerable variation among countries in rates of growth of taxation. The health share of GDP has also increased since 1975 in most countries, but in most countries, the health share of GDP has increased less than the tax share of GDP. In these countries, increases in taxation have more than accommodated rising health care spending. By contrast, in six countries – Canada, Germany, the Netherlands, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States – the rise in health care spending as a share of GDP has been greater than the rise in tax revenue. In most of these countries, this pattern reflects a relatively slow increase in tax revenue rather than a relatively rapid increase in health care costs. If all health care spending in these countries were public, other types of spending would have been displaced by health care expenditures.

21

Figure 8 repeats this analysis using the public health expenditure share of GDP. Although the six countries above differ substantially in the share of expenditures that are public, the pattern seen in Figure 7 is repeated in Figure 8. In these countries, tax policy has been constrained and has not accommodated increases in publicly-financed health care expenditures. Rather, the effect of constraining taxes has been that publiclyfinanced health care expenditures have displaced other forms of government spending. Without further information, however, it is not possible to ascertain the relative efficiency or equity of this displacement.

5.

Implications for Financing

The analyses presented in this paper suggest first, that the form of health care financing has no systematic relationship to the efficiency with which the health care system operates, at least to the extent that efficiency can be proxied by cost 8 . Second, over the lifecycle, public expenditures on health care appear to be modestly progressive, with the main progressive impact of this spending occurring among middle-aged people. In Canada, $1 of tax money spent on health care generates about $0.50 worth of benefits to the lower two income quintiles and about $0.50 worth of benefits for the upper three income quintiles. Third, patterns of health service utilization in developed countries suggest that the marginal dollar of health care spending – money used to purchase high tech equipment or specialist services – is less progressively spent than the average dollar. Depending on the form of financing, this marginal dollar may not be distributed progressively at all. Fourth, health care spending has little impact on the general
8

As noted above, alternative sources of revenue themselves have efficiency implications, regardless of how the funding is used.

22

distribution of well-being in society. Distributing progressively-financed public funds through universal health insurance programs has limited impact on the distribution of total income. Finally, rising health expenditures threaten to displace other types of publicly-financed transfers. This outcome has already occurred in many relatively low tax share economies, including in Canada. This pattern of results has two implications for the form of financing of the health care system. In terms of public financing, the results suggest that forms of revenue collection that tax both older adults and young people are more equitable, over the lifecycle, than those that tax younger people and cover older people. The greatest redistributive benefits of public health financing occur among middle-aged people who become seriously ill or disabled. Differential mortality and relatively equal health status among survivors make public financing of benefits to the elderly less redistributive. In terms of the mix of public and private financing, the potential for public health insurance to crowd out other forms of redistributive benefits, without generating significant redistribution themselves, suggests that a mixed financing system may be the optimal way to balance efficiency and equity in health care. At the margin, increasing the level of public health expenditures to address ever-improving health care technologies will eventually – and, in some instances, may already -- reduce the overall level of equity in society by moving scarce tax revenues from cash to less redistributive in-kind transfers. Progressive taxes are most effectively deployed to provide progressive benefits. Targeting these funds toward lower income groups is likely to enable the maximum level of redistribution at the lowest efficiency cost.

23

References Amelung, Volker, Sherry Glied, and Angelina Topan. 2003. “Health Insurance and the Labor Market: The German Experience.” Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law. August 2003 (28:4): 693-714. Bhattacharya, Jay; Lakdawalla, Darius 2006. Does Medicare Benefit the Poor? Journal of Public Economics, January 2006, v. 90, iss. 1-2, pp. 277-92. Brown, Robert. L. 1998. Social Security: Regressive or Progressive? North American Actuarial Journal, Vol. 2, No. 2, 1-33. Garfinkel, Irwin, Lee Rainwater, and Timothy M. Smeeding. 2006. “A Re-Examination of Welfare States and Inequality in Rich Nations: How In-kind Transfers and Indirect Taxes Change the Story. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. Vol. 25, No. 4, 897-919. Kessleman, Jonathan R. and Ron Cheung. 2004. “Tax Incidence, Progressivity, and Inequality in Canada.” Canadian Tax Journal, v. 52, iss. 3, pp. 709-89. McClellan, Mark; Skinner, Jonathan. 2006. The Incidence of Medicare. Journal of Public Economics, January 2006, v. 90, iss. 1-2, pp. 257-76 Roos, Noralou P. and Cameron A. Mustard. 1997. “Variation in Health and Health Care Use by Socioeconomic Status in Winnipeg, Canada: Does the System Work Well? Yes and No. Milbank Quarterly, Vol, 75, No. 1, 84-110. Smeeding, Timothy M., Peter Saunders, John Coder, Stephen Jenkins, Johan Fritzell, Aldi J. M. Hagenaars, Richard Hauser, and Michael Wolfason. 1993. Povery, Inequality, and Family Living Standards Impacts Across Seven Nations: The Effect of Noncash Subsidies for Health, Education, and Housing. Review of Income and Wealth Series 39. Number 3. September, 229-256. SourceOECD. OECD Health Data, 2006. OECD. 2006. http://www.ecosante.org/index2.php?base=OCDE&langh=ENG&langs=ENG van Doorslaer, Eddy, Cristina Masseria and the OECD Health Equity Research Group Members. 2004. Income-Related Inequality in the Use of Medical Care in 21 OECD Countries. OECD Health Care Working Papers #14, May 11. Wilkins R, Berthelot JM, Ng E. 2002. “Trends in mortality by neighbourhood income in urban Canada from 1971 to 1996.” Health Reports 13(Suppl):45-72.

24

Figure 1: Composition of Financing, 2000 (SourceOECD, 2006)
100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0% us tr al ia A us tr ia C an ad a D en m ar k Fi nl an d Fr an ce G er m an y Ic el an d Ire la nd ly Ja pa n Sp ai n Sw ed Sw en itz U er ni la te nd d K in gd U om ni te d St at es ic o or ea s la nd N ew M ex la nd Ita

Out of pocket

Private Insurance

General Revenue

N

et he r

A

Source: SourceOECD, Online. Downloaded October 2006.

Ze a

K

Social Insurance

25

Figure 2: PPP Adjusted Health Care Spending per Capita 1960 and 1990 SourceOECD, 2006
5000 US 4500 4000 fitted 3500 Spending in 2000 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 0 20 40 60 80 Spending in 1960 100 120 140 160

fitted excluding US

Source: SourceOECD, Online. Downloaded October 2006.

26

Figure 3: Cohort Survival by Quintile: Canadian Men
100000

90000

80000

70000

60000 Survivors

50000

40000

Q1:Q5 survivors Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5

30000

20000

10000

0 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Age 55 60 65 70 75 80 85

Source: Statistics Canada Life Table data, 1996. Provided by Russell Wilkins.

27

Figure 4: Cohort Survival by Quintile: Canadian Women
100000

90000

80000

70000

60000 Survivors

50000

40000

Q1:Q5 survivors Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5

30000

20000

10000

0 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Age 55 60 65 70 75 80 85

Source: Statistics Canada Life Table data, 1996. Provided by Russell Wilkins.

28

Figure 5: Annual Spending by Quintile, Men
7000

6000

5000

Annual Spending

4000

3000

2000

1000

0 12 TO 14 15 TO 19 20 TO 24 25 TO 29 30 TO 34 35 TO 39 40 TO 44 Q2 45 TO 49 Q3 50 TO 54 55 TO 59 Q4 60 TO 64 Lowest 65 TO 69 70 TO 74 75 TO 80 79 YEARS

Highest

Source: Author’s tabulations of the Canadian Community Health Survey, 2000 combined with 1996 life table data from Statistics Canada.

29

Figure 6: Annual Spending by Quintile, Women
8000

7000

6000

Annual Spending

5000

4000

3000

2000

1000

0 12 TO 14 15 TO 19 20 TO 24 25 TO 29 30 TO 34 35 TO 39 40 TO 44 Q2 45 TO 49 Q3 50 TO 54 55 TO 59 Q4 60 TO 64 Lowest 65 TO 69 70 TO 74 75 TO 80 79 YEARS

Highest

Source: Author’s tabulations of the Canadian Community Health Survey, 2000 combined with 1996 life table data from Statistics Canada.

30

Figure 7: Change in Tax Share and Health Share of GDP, 1975-2003
20

15

10

5

0
I re la nd ed en nd Ic el an d et he rla nd N s ew Ze al an d a D en m ar k Ja pa n Au st ra lia Fi nl an d an ad Fr an ce Sp ai n itz er la gd om Ki n U st ria an y er m Au St a te s 1

Sw

C

-5 Change in Tax Change in Health

Source: Health data from SourceOECD, downloaded October 2006. Tax share data from OECD Annual revenue statistics at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/18/23/35471773.pdf, Table 2.

U

ni te d

N

ni te d

G

Sw

31

Figure 8: Change in Tax Share and in Public Health Expenditure Share of GDP
20

15

10

5

0
Ic el an d I re la nd ed en nd et he rla nd N s ew Ze al an d a D en m ar k Fi nl an d Ja pa n Au st ra lia an ad Fr an ce Sp ai n itz er la gd om Ki n U st ria an y er m Au St a te s 1

Sw

C

-5 Change in Tax Change in Public Health

Source: Health data from SourceOECD, downloaded October 2006. Tax share data from OECD Annual revenue statistics at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/18/23/35471773.pdf, Table 2.

U

ni te d

N

ni te d

G

Sw

32

Table 1: Relationship between Spending Composition and Spending Growth 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Total Expenditures Gen Rev Soc Ins OOP (N) Total Expenditures, No US Gen Rev Soc Ins OOP (N) Public Expenditures Gen Rev Soc Ins OOP (N) Public Expenditures, No US Gen Rev Soc Ins OOP (N) + + NA (6) + + + (11) 0 0 0 (8) 0 0 0 (11) (16)

2000 0 0 0 (20)

0 0 NA (5)

+ + NA (7) + + + (6)

0 0 0 (7) 0 (8)

0 0 0 (9) 0 (10)

0 (15) (16)

0 0 0 (19) 0 (20)

0 0 0 (7)

0 0 0 (9)

0 0 (15)

0 0 0 (19)

Data from SourceOECD, 2006 download. Results are from regressions of spending in column heading year regressed on expenditures (total or public, respectively) 5 years earlier, and on the composition of spending 5 years earlier. + indicates positive correlation, 0 indicates no significant correlation at 10% confidence level, - indicates negative correlation.

1

Table 2: Lifetime Spending by Quintile and Redistributive Effect of Health Care Spending At age 12 At Age 65 No LE MALE Highest Q2 Q3 Q4 Lowest Low:High Low:Mid Mid:High FEMALE Highest Q2 Q3 Q4 Lowest Low:High Low:Mid Mid:High 84953 95603 129646 159807 138298 1.63 1.07 1.53 127961 104700 124467 155599 170540 1.33 1.37 0.97 66449 74698 99472 129991 105591 1.59 1.06 1.50 108881 92895 110567 139694 151924 1.40 1.37 1.02 42332 48218 64762 86414 72194 1.71 1.11 1.53 69488 63603 75552 96697 104844 1.51 1.39 1.09 0.17 0.16 0.18 0.24 0.26 0.13 0.15 0.21 0.28 0.23 52810 57653 70187 68912 61943 1.17 0.88 1.33 78174 45956 52484 57302 53090 0.68 1.01 0.67 35521 38430 43042 44595 34521 0.97 0.80 1.21 60134 35450 40296 44085 39145 0.65 0.97 0.67 19185 20927 23200 24542 18959 0.99 0.82 1.21 32276 19132 21766 23977 21331 0.66 0.98 0.67 0.27 0.16 0.18 0.2 0.18 0.18 0.20 0.22 0.23 0.18 0% Redistributive 5% Effect at 5% No LE 0% Redistributive 5% Effect at 5%

Source: Author’s tabulations of the Canadian Community Health Survey, 2000 combined with 1996 life table data from Statistics Canada and SourceOECD October 2006. Spending computed as general practitioner visits @$75, specialist visits @$375, hospital days @$1000. Redistributive effect describes share received by group from $1 of health care spending, by gender.

2

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Comparative Summary

...Comparative Summary Financial statements and policies are important to all organization and in health care it is a measurement to reflect how well the organization is operating. This paper will look at 3 types of organizations: Nonprofit, for profit and government hospitals and examine the financial structures and the unique policies in each environment. It is important to understand the similarities and difference to fully grasp the significances and differences within the health care community. The first organization to examine is not for profit healthcare organizations. Not for profit organizations governed by a board of trustees and a required to comply with federal and local laws and regulations regarding charitable donations and fiscal compliance. There are three major organization that issue financial standards for not for profit organizations to follow regarding here financial status. The organizations are the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB), the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants (AICPA), and the U.S. Federal Office of Management and Budget (OMB) (Mercer, 1999). In order to maintain a not for profit status the organization must comply with the IRS reporting measures and provide. The rules with the IRS can be found under section 501(c)(3) of the Internal Revenue Code and is how an organization can be tax exempt. Beyond federal guidelines “many states require that contributions, gifts, grants, etc., and functional expenses be reported...

Words: 1182 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

An Overview of the Canadian Health Care System with a Comparison to the United States Heath Care System Canadian and American Health Care

...Running head: An Overview of the Canadian Health Care System with a Comparison to the United States Heath Care System Canadian And American Health Care Parween Nooruddin Stratford University Abstract The reason for this exploration paper is to look at healthcare systems in two very progressed industrialized nations: The United States of America and Canada. The principal piece of the exploration paper will concentrate on the portrayal of healthcare system in the aforementioned nations while the second part will dissect, assess and measure up the two systems in regards to value and proficiency. Canadian And American Health Care In this research paper I will be comparing Canadian and American HealthCare systems. In this paper I will provide a description of health care system for each country. I will also analyze, evaluate and compare the two systems regarding equity and efficiency. We begin by giving a general portrayal and examination of the structure of Healthcare systems in Canada and the United States. CANADA’S HEALTH CARE – OVERVIEW Canada's health care system is a group of socialized health insurance plans that provides coverage to all Canadian citizens. It is openly subsidized and controlled on a common or regional premise, inside rules set by the national government. Under the health care system , singular natives are given preventive care and medical treatment from essential consideration doctors and in addition access to clinics, dental surgery and extra...

Words: 1310 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Financial Ratios Analysis and Comparison Paper

...Financial Ratios Analysis and Comparison Paper Dianne Davis MHA 612 Professor Johnson June 7, 2014 Abstract It is important for healthcare organizations to understand their present performance and weak areas in order to generate more effective operational strategies. Financial ratio analysis is an effective tool to determine hospital’s performance on several indicators such as ability to pay debt, capability to generate revenue, and sales performance etc. The objective of this paper is to describe role of different financial ratios in understanding organizational performance and in developing new strategy. The paper also presents comparative ratio analysis of local healthcare organization and industry norms. Financial Ratios Analysis and Comparison Paper Introduction Financial planning and effective management play a major role in success of healthcare business. Financial ratio analysis refers to an effective financial management tool that helps in understanding financial performance of the hospital over a period of time. Financial ratio informs about the financial trends and information on key performance indicators that helped in strategy making. Financial ratios can also utilize in comparing business performance of two or more hospitals, and also to assess effectiveness of management. Financial ratios utilized in measuring liquidity of the hospitals, profit evaluation, debt structure, management of cash flow, risk determination...

Words: 1464 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Catamaran Corporation - Financial Analysis

...Catamaran Corporation Introduction Catamaran Corporation was formerly known as the SXC Health Solutions Corporation. The company was founded in 1993. The company acquired ComCoTec a software business in 2001. In 2006, the company moved its headquarters from Milton, Ontario to Schaumburg, Illinois. The company acquired four other companies, namely National Medical Health Card Systems, Inc., Zynchros, MedfushionRx, Inc., and Catalyst Health Solutions Inc. They acquired National Medical Health Card Systems in February 2008 for $143 million. Through the acquisition, the company doubled its size and labor force. Ten months after, the company acquired Zynchros, a formulary management business based in Seattle. On December 2010, the company bought MedfushionRx, Inc. for $100 million. The company purchased the MedfushionRx, Inc. to strengthen the company’s position in a special pharmacy market, improve management, as well as, improve supportive care. In 2012, the company purchased its competitor the Catalyst Health Solutions Inc. the cost was about $4.14 billion. On the same year, the company changes its corporate name to Catamaran Corporation. On March 30, 2015, the company was acquired by UnitedHealth Group Inc. for $12.8 billion. UnitedHealth Group Inc. purchased Catamaran Corporation to boost up their pharmacy services. Catamaran Corporation will be absorbed into the UnitedHealth Group Inc.’s OptumRX division. Catamaran Corporation is one of the leading and fastest-growing...

Words: 4439 - Pages: 18

Premium Essay

Finance

...centricity which translates into producing happy customers. In turn, to maintain an enriching customer experience, ITL needs to take good care of its employees as rightly pointed out by Sir Richard Branson. Happy employees lead to increased performance and productivity and its effect is reflected directly as increased profitability on the financial statement. INTRODUCTION OF PROJECT In line with its Human Resource Management strategy, ITL is seeking to implement a “Quality Work Life Balance” –Quality WLB, a concept to improve employees’ satisfaction, skills and effectiveness. This is becoming more of an international trend where we have recently observed the UK Prime Minister, Tony Blair citing the tangible and intangible business benefits of good Quality Work Life Balance …“The UK business environment has shown that it is possible to have flexible labour markets combined with a balanced family friendly policy to help work life balance-WLB. The result will no doubt be higher growth, higher employment and low unemployment.” In this perspective, we shall be addressing the project on three fronts. Firstly, we shall be looking at the definition and importance of project financing. Secondly, the different sources of financing will be discussed and lastly, we shall discuss the impact of financing on various stakeholders of ITL. PROJECT FINANCING It is often difficult to start a business without sufficient capital. All businesses require some form of finance throughout the...

Words: 1618 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Long Term Care

...Hospitals and Long-Term Care Facilities Glennis Bogard Dr. Angela J. Smith Health Services Organization – HSA 500 February 17, 2011 Abstract Hospitals can be set up as nonprofit or for-profit facilities. The differences between the nonprofit and for profit hospitals will be discussed. Hospitals have experienced different trends in the last thirty years. This paper will identify at least three major trends that have occurred within the hospital sector. Three examples that describe and differentiate the roles of hospitals and nursing homes are providing long-term care. The conclusion of this paper will be a brief critiquing of the current state of long-term care policy in the United States. Hospitals and Long-Term Care Facilities Describe the differences between nonprofit and for-profit hospitals. A characteristic as stated by Williams and Torrens (2008) of nonprofit hospitals is that these hospitals do not function under the realm of regular corporate law but under a special provision of the corporate law in each state. It is also noted that nonprofit hospitals also function under special federal and state tax provisions because of recognition of their community service function. Other characteristics of nonprofit hospitals are they do not have owners and their governing body is a community based board that has complete authority over operations. Nonprofit hospitals, in general, are not required to pay most of the taxes at federal, state and local levels...

Words: 1691 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

The Fate of Uninsured Veterans

...Policy Analysis Paper The fate of uninsured Veterans: A policy Analysis University of Mississippi Medical Center School of Nursing Define the problem and assemble the evidence Too many Veterans in the United States lack health insurance and are ineligible to receive care provided by the Veteran’s Health Administration. According to American Community Survey (ACS) conducted in 2010, one in 10 of the nation’s 12.5 million veterans under the age of 65 is uninsured. A veteran is defined by federal law as any person who served for any length of time in any military service branch. Contrary to the presumption of most, not all veterans qualify for free healthcare through the Department of Veteran Affairs. The Veterans Health Administration (VHA) operates as a branch of the Department of Veterans Affairs and is the largest health system in the nation. It is recognized for its commitment to providing high-quality population specific healthcare. The VHA also works closely with academic medical centers across the nation. Haley and Kenney (2012) identify eligibility for health care provided by the VHA as being on veteran status, service-connected disabilities and income level. Other factors include demographic location and cost sharing requirements. Health insurance coverage for veterans as with other groups of nonelderly adults has heavy dependence on access to employer sponsored insurance (ESI) and the costs of obtaining it. It must also be considered that the majority of states...

Words: 6628 - Pages: 27

Premium Essay

Financial Analysis of Square Pharma

...Question 1# Principal activities of SQUARE Pharmaceuticals: * Square strives for top quality health care products at the least cost reaching the lowest rungs of the economic class of people in the country. We value our social obligations. * Square owe their shareholders and strive for protection of their capital as well as ensure highest return and growth of their assets. * Square works for best compensation to all the employees who constitute the back-bone of the management and operational strength of the company through a pay-package composing salary/wages, allowances, bonuses, profit participation, leave salary and superannuation & retirement benefits. * Square works for the best co-operation of the creditors & debtors the banks & financial Institutions who provide financial support when we need them, the suppliers of raw materials &suppliers who offer them at the best prices at the opportune moments, the providers of utilities- power, gas & water etc. and the customers who buy our products & services by redeeming their claim in time by making prompt payment and by distributing proper product on due dates to our customers. * Square strives for fulfillment of our responsibility to the government through payment of entire range of due taxes, duties and claims by various public agencies like municipalities etc. * Square works as responsible citizen, for a social order devoid of malpractices, anti-environmental behaviors, unethical...

Words: 4003 - Pages: 17

Premium Essay

Ppp Model in Rural Health

...Rural Health Management in India Dec -2013 Contents Lists of Contents Page No 1. List of Abbreviations 3 2. Abstract 4 3. Introduction 6 3.1 Private Sector in India 7 3.2 THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE SECTOR IN HEALTH CARE 8 3.3 Public/Private Partnership 8 3.4 OBJECTIVES OF PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS 10 3.5 Classifying PPPs 10 3.6 Challenges in Partnership 11 3.7 Characteristics of Partnership 12 3.8 Scope and types of partnership 13 3.9 The Study for Research paper 15 3.10.1 Analysis and Discussion 16 3.10.2 Overview of the Case Studies 16 3.10.3 Enabling Conditions 17 3.10.4 Equity and Accessibility 19 3.10 Private partner selection and obligations of the Partners 19 3.11 Performance Specifications 20 3.12 Resource implications 20 3.13 Autonomy 21 3.14 Technical and managerial capacity 22 3.15 Quality of services 23 3.16 Stakeholder Perspectives 23 4. Summary and Conclusion 24 5. References 26 6. Annexure 29 1. List of Abbreviations PPP Public Private Partnership HSR Health Sector Reform ADBI Asian Development Bank Institute NRHM National Rural Health Mission FRU First Referral Unit MMVs Mobile Medical Unit CHC Community Health centre ...

Words: 15419 - Pages: 62

Premium Essay

Quazi-Markets In Health Care

...Introduction 1.1 Introduction to the research Problem Healthcare worldwide faces unprecedented challenges in meeting growing demands in presence of constrained resources (Jones 2010). In the United Kingdom healthcare services are delivered by an organization known as the National Health Service (NHS). The NHS is exposed to similar challenges, with broadly static health budgets for the last 5 years. It has been estimated that the NHS in England needs to make annual efficiencies of around 4% per year in order to be able to continue providing the current level of healthcare services and cope with the annual increase in demand (Roberts 2012). The structures and processes for delivery of health care in England have been evolving continuously in...

Words: 1781 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Abcasdasd

...TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction…………………………………………………………………………….…3 History and Background……………………………………………………………….…3 Business Description………………………………………………………………….…..4 Board of Directors………………………………………………………………………...5 SWOT Analysis………………………………………………………………………..….7 Financial Analysis…………………………………………………………………...….12 Ratio Analysis……………………………………………………………………………12 Cash Flow Analysis……………………………………………………………………..18 Conclusion………………………………………………………………………………20 References and Bibliography…………………………………………………………..22 INTRODUCTION Procter and Gamble is the world’s largest consumer goods company which operates in more than 180 countries around the world. It has more than 300 brands in beauty, health, fabric home, baby, family and personal care products. More than 20 of P&G's brands are billion-dollar sellers, including Actonel, Always/Whisper, Braun, Bounty, Charmin, Crest, Downy/Lenor, Folgers, Gillette, Iams, Olay, Pampers, Pantene, Pringles, Tide, and Wella, among others. It operates in America, Europe and Asia. It is headquartered in Cincinnati, Ohio and employs 138,000 people. P&G generated revenue of $68,222 million in the fiscal year of 2006. This is a whooping 20.2% increase from 2005. The net profits also went up by a massive 25.4% from 2005. HISTORY AND BACKGROUND William Procter, a candle-maker, and James Gamble, a soap-maker, formed the company known as Procter & Gamble in 1837. The company prospered during the nineteenth century. In 1859...

Words: 5531 - Pages: 23

Premium Essay

Investment

...services such as capital syndication. My internship experience with CreedCap Asia Advisors gave me firsthand experience on deal transactions. I worked on live equity and debt deal transactions. I learnt how to create financial models, analyze it and pitching for debt deals. My responsibilities during the period were as follows: I built and assisted in making financial models for equity and debt financing deals. As part of the financial modeling, I developed, analyzed and benchmarked the assumptions, and tested the feasibility of the model. Questioning each plugged in variable that will drive model and getting all the details right from the client was the process adopted to create a solid model. Followed by, projection of free cash flow of a company and using financial metrics like turnover, EBITDA, PAT, gross profit margin, ROCE, etc. to analyze the financial strength and operational efficiency of the firm over the projected period. I assisted in investor meets for debt deal. I assisted in financial ratio analysis for debt deal and routine task that helped them save time. I helped the firm in business development. I gathered information and assisted them in screening and evaluating companies that can be potential clients. I did research on health care industry, profiling the industry, the trends in private equity investment, assessing and identifying investment opportunities. Especially, the report focused on identifying funding opportunities in various subsectors and possible...

Words: 277 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Privatisation in Indian Healthcare Sector

...ADMINISTRATION TOPIC: PRIVATISATION IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE SECTOR CONTENTS 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1. PRIVATIZATION 1.2 INDIAN HEALTHCARE INDUSTRY 1.2.1 DRIVERS FOR GROWTH OF HEALTHCARE 1.3 PUBLIC HEALTHCARE IN INDIA 1.4 PRIVATE SECTOR IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE DELIVERY SYSTEM 1.4.1 GOVERNMENT POLICIES TO SUPPORT THE GROWTH OF PRIVATE SECTOR 1.4.2 FDI IN THE INDIAN HEALTHCARE 1.4.2.1 STATUS AND PROSPECTS FOR FOREIGN INVESTMENTS IN HOSPITALS IN INDIA 1.4.2.2 CONSTRAINTS TO FOREIGN INVESTMENTS IN HOSPITALS IN INDIA 1.4.2.3 FOREIGN PRESENCE IN HOSPITALS IN INDIA 1.4.2.4 SUMMARY OF PROS AND CONS FOR FINANCING SOURCES OF HOSPITALS OBJECTIVES 2. LITERATURE REVIEW 3. ANALYSIS OF THE IMPACT OF PRIVATIZATION IN THE HEALTHCARE SECTOR 3.1 QUALITY AND PRIVATE HEALTHCARE SERVICES 3.2 IMPACT OF FOREIGN INVESTMENTS IN HOSPITALS IN INDIA 3.3 CONSUMER PERCEPTION OF PRIVATE SECTOR 3.4 EMERGING TRENDS IN HOSPITALS IN INDIA: CHALLENGES AND INTERVENTIONS 4. CONCLUSION 5. ACKNOWLEDGEMENT 6. BIBLIOGRAPHY 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1 PRIVATIZATION Privatization can also be called denationalization or disinvestment. All three terms describe a situation where a government decides to transfer control of a government, and...

Words: 9237 - Pages: 37

Premium Essay

Comparative Summary

...& Ward (2006), “health care is an enormous part of the US economy, representing 17% of all personal consumption expenditures annually” (p. 7). The health care industry has multiple components, diverse types of providers, and many different types of health care organizations playing an integral part in the delivery of health care. Health care is provided by different health care financial environment namely for-profit organization (FP), not-for-profit organizations (NFP), and governmental organizations (Finkler & Ward, 2006). This paper will identify one entity from each health care financial environment identified from the previous week’s worksheet and will describe the financial structure of each financial environment. This paper will also address the policies that make this financial environment unique and identify which financial management practices are prevalent in the financial environment. This paper will also explain why effective financial management is more difficult in health care than in other industries. Entities FP, NFP, and government facilities exist throughout the country. This paper identifies the first entity FP healthcare organization JFK Medical Center. The second entity is Naples Community Hospital (NCH), a NFP healthcare organization, and the third entity is the Veterans Administration, a government funded facility. JFK Medical Center is a 460-bed acute care medical/ surgical hospital specializing in cardiovascular care, oncology services...

Words: 1536 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Aksxöm

...Sciences de l'Homme Alternative Systems of Health Care Provision Author(s): Timothy Besley, Miguel Gouveia and Jacques Drèze Reviewed work(s): Source: Economic Policy, Vol. 9, No. 19 (Oct., 1994), pp. 199-258 Published by: Wiley on behalf of the Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies, and the Maison des Sciences de l'Homme Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1344496 . Accessed: 24/12/2012 16:11 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . Wiley, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies, Maison des Sciences de l'Homme are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economic Policy. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded on Mon, 24 Dec 2012 16:11:43 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Alternative systems of health care provision Timothy Besley and MiguelGouveia and of Princeton University University Pennsylvania 1. I[ntroduction Around the developed world, many health care systems are in crisis. Populations feel...

Words: 27182 - Pages: 109