Free Essay

Industrial Engg

In:

Submitted By purusothaman85
Words 18118
Pages 73
Information Sharing in Supply Chains: An Empirical and Theoretical Valuation
Ruomeng Cui, Gad Allon, Achal Bassamboo, Jan A. Van Mieghem*
Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL

April 10, 2013
We provide an empirical and theoretical assessment of the value of information sharing in a two-stage supply chain. The value of downstream sales information to the upstream firm stems from improving upstream order fulfillment forecast accuracy. Such improvement can lead to lower safety stock and better service. According to recent theoretical work, the value of information sharing is zero under a large spectrum of parameters. Based on the data collected from a CPG company, however, we empirically show that if the company includes the downstream demand data to forecast orders, the mean squared error percentage improvement ranges from 7.1% to 81.1% in out-of-sample tests. Thus, there is a discrepancy between the empirical results and existing literature: the empirical value of information sharing is positive even when the literature predicts zero value. While the literature assumes that the decision maker strictly adheres to a given inventory policy, our model allows him to deviate, accounting for private information held by the decision maker, yet unobservable to the econometrician. This turns out to reconcile our empirical findings with the literature. These “decision deviations” lead to information losses in the order process, resulting in strictly positive value of downstream information sharing. We prove that this result holds for any forecast lead time and for more general policies. We also systematically map the product characteristics to the value of information sharing. Key words : supply chain, information sharing, information distortion, decision deviation, time series, forecast accuracy, empirical forecasting, ARIMA process.

1.

Introduction

The abundance of information technology has had a massive impact on supply chain coordination. Sharing downstream demand information with upstream suppliers has improved supply chain performance in practice. Costco and 7-Eleven share warehouse-specific, daily, item level point of sale data with their suppliers via SymphonyIRI platform, a company offering business advice to retailers (see Costco collaboration 2006). In addition to this uni-directional information sharing, Collaborative Planning, Forecasting and Replenishment (CPFR) programs advocate joint visibility and joint replenishment. According to Terwiesch et al. (2005), the benefit of CPFR programs
* E-mail addresses are: r-cui, g-allon, a-bassamboo, vanmieghem all @kellogg.northwestern.edu.
1

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2334352

2

can be significant: the GlobalNetXchange, a consortium consisting of more than 30 trade partners including Sears, Kroger etc, have reported a 5% to 20% reduction in inventory costs and an increase in off-the-shelf availability of 2% to 12% following the launch of their CPFR programs. In sharp contrast, however, the academic literature shows that the value of sharing downstream customer sales to improve upstream forecasting is limited. (We will also refer to customer sales as customer demand or demand.) For example, Gaur et al. (2005) model the demand process as an autoregressive moving average ARMA(1, 1) and show that the value of information sharing is zero under 75% of the demand parameters. Therefore, a direct conclusion of this literature is that the value of information sharing is zero under a large spectrum of parameters. Companies spend billions of dollar on demand forecasting software and other supply chain solutions (Ledesma 2004). Given the implementation cost of collaboration technology and the limited theoretical benefits, it is not clear in practice whether a firm should invest in information sharing systems. The decision to implement an information sharing system thus hinges on the following question: how much would sharing downstream information improve the supplier’s order forecast accuracy? We were approached with this question by the statistical forecasting team of a leading global consumer packaged goods (CPG) company that manufactures and sells beverages and snack foods to wholesalers and retail chains. Forecasting is necessary for the company due to the lead time to adjust manufacturing runs and deploy inventory. In the absence of downstream demand information, the upstream supplier uses its own demand history (i.e., its retailer’s order history), to forecast how much to manufacture. Not satisfied with its current forecasting performance, the firm sought solutions in information sharing by collecting downstream operations data (e.g., point of sale and inventory) from both its customers and a third party organization (e.g., RSI). Using this data set, we directly measure the supplier’s forecast accuracy improvement. Surprisingly, our empirical results indicate a substantial value of information sharing: (1) incorporating order and demand correlation yields a statistically significant improvement for some products even without accounting for the applied inventory policies; and (2) applying the underlying replenishment policies, we find that the value of information sharing is strictly positive (7.1% to 81.1% MSE percentage improvement) across all products with stationary demand while the literature suggests positive value for only 30% (4 out of 14) of products. To put this in perspective, the company views the forecast accuracy improvement opportunities of 10% as important and 30% as very significant. These empirical findings suggest that we need a better theoretical understanding of how demand propagation impacts forecasting. The works of Gaur et al. (2005) and Giloni et al. (2012) are important antecedents of our paper. In their setting, the decision maker strictly follows an order-up-to policy, via which the demand process propagates upstream and becomes the order process. If, for example, the retailer follows

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2334352

3

a demand replacement policy (the retailer orders the demand in the current week), the order process then equals the demand process. It is as if the demand process propagates fully upstream and the order process carries full demand information. In such setting, the value of including the downstream demand process is zero. The downstream demand information might be lost in this demand-to-order transformation. The authors derive the following insights: the value of information sharing is zero when the order process effectively carries all demand information, or equivalently, when the order is invertible with respect to demand shocks. The authors show that the order is invertible (thus the value of information sharing is zero) under 75% of demand parameters for an ARMA(1, 1) demand process. The key underlying assumption in the theoretical literature is that the decision maker consistently and strictly follows a given replenishment policy. In practice, however, we learned that the decision makers deviate from their target inventory policy based on private information that we cannot observe. The planner might round the order quantity due to truck load constraints and delivery multiple brands of products in batches. From an econometric perspective, we model the agent’s deviation from the exact policy, in the spirit of Rust (1997), by an “error term” that accounts for a state variable which is observed by the agent but not by the statistician. We demonstrate that including these idiosyncratic shocks in the model significantly increases the theoretical value of information sharing, in agreement with the empirical findings. In the presence of decision deviations, we provide a different and important insight into the value of information sharing. Unlike before, the demand process now propagates together with the decision deviation. The value of information sharing is zero if the order process carries both all demand information and all decision deviation information. The demand and decision deviation processes follow distinct evolution patterns to produce the order process: the evolution of inventory governs the translation of decision deviations into replenishment decisions while the evolution of inventory and current demand together dictates the translation of demand. This difference causes the order process to no longer carry full downstream information. Information sharing then becomes valuable to recover the order’s elaborate information structure and to forecast more accurately. At first glance, the decision uncertainty seems to diminish the attractiveness of analyzing a retailer’s replenishment process due to the unpredictability of the order decision. Such uncertainty, however, opens the door to information loss in the upstream orders, because the decision deviation distorts the normal demand propagation. We prove that as long as the variability in decision deviation and demand are both nonzero, the value of information sharing is strictly positive for any forecast lead time (regardless of the demand and policy). Our extended model induces qualitatively different results than the literature and reconciles our empirical findings.

4

We also conduct comparative statics and detailed numerical studies to examine the impact of product demand characteristics on the value of information sharing. These insights can help managers rank the potential gains from information sharing depending on the demand characteristics for different products such as sport drinks and orange juice. Our study is grounded in both empirical evidence and theory and attempts to understand the cause of strictly positive value of information sharing. We analyze a data set containing weekly downstream demand, upstream order fulfillment, and the price plan over a period of two and a half years. This allows us to make the following four main contributions: first, this paper complements the emerging area of research in information sharing with empirical evidence. Specifically, we directly measure the value of information sharing at a leading CPG company and demonstrate a positive value of information sharing in all the settings that we study. Second, we allow for decision deviations in our theoretical model to explicitly capture the decision maker’s private information that is unobservable to us. This model extends the existing literature and recovers the results from the literature as a special case where decision deviation is zero. Third, we prove that if both demands and order decisions are subject to random shocks, the value of information sharing is always positive. We demonstrate that the decision deviation distorts the normal demand propagation in a way that obscures the detailed information of the two processes. The resulting less informative order process induces larger forecast uncertainty, which indicates a positive value from using the downstream demand to recover the original elaborate information structure. Finally, we provide guidelines for the magnitude of the value of information sharing depending on the demand characteristics.

2.

Literature Review

Motivated by practice and theory, we study the value of a retailer to share its retailer’s downstream demand information with its supplier to help the supplier forecast the retailer’s order. We find that the results in the literature point towards the inconsistencies between the empirical evaluation of the benefit and the theoretical predictions. This paper reconciles these findings by extending the established theory. Therefore, our paper is related to two streams of literature: (1) theoretical work on information sharing and demand propagation through supply chains and (2) empirical work that bridges the above theory and operational data. There is a vast theoretical literature on the subject of demand propagation and information sharing in supply chains. A company’s demand propagates through the supply chain and becomes its order to the supplier. The properties of orders can help answer important questions in supply chains, e.g. is sharing retailer’s demand information beneficial for the supplier to forecast its own order and manage its inventory; is there incentive for the agents to share their own information; is

5

there a bullwhip effect and what is the driver? The demand propagation relies on two basic characteristics of the supply chain: demand structure and replenishment policy. We focus on the work that assumes truthful and complete information disclosure. We begin by introducing the various demand and policy structures studied in the literature. Next, we discuss our paper’s contribution relative to the two most related work: Gaur et al. (2005) and Giloni et al. (2012). Theoretical Work. The literature studies demand propagation under various demand structures. Lee et al. (2000) and Raghunathan (2001) adopt an autoregressive AR(p) process, Miyaoka and Hausman (2004) and Graves (1999) assume an integrated moving average IMA(d, q) process, Zhang (2004), Gaur et al. (2005), Kovtun et al. (2012) and Giloni et al. (2012) consider an autoregressive and moving average ARMA(p, q) process, Gilbert (2005) applies an ARMA with integration model called ARIMA(p, d, q) process, and Aviv (2003) uses the linear state space framework. Another body of literature applies the Martingale Model of Forecast Evolution (MMFE) structure. It uses the incremental signal, generated from the minimum mean squared error, to model the evolution of a process. Heath and Jackson (1994), Graves et al. (1998), Aviv (2001a) and Chen and Lee (2009) apply such demand structure to study production and forecasting. The general expression in the optimal forecast revision drives MMFE’s theoretical advantage: most time-series models can be interpreted as a special case of the MMFE model (Chen and Lee 2009). We will show our main conclusion holds under the MMFE structure (see Online Companion). Gaur et al. (2005) point out the ARMA model closely resembles the real-life demand structure and finds it valuable from the manager perspective to study such demand process. For our studies, we use an ARIMA structure to model and empirically fit the demand process. In the above literatures, the most commonly studied replenishment decision is the myopic orderup-to policy. The following papers investigate information sharing and the bullwhip effect under other policies. Caplin (1985) proves the existence of the bullwhip effect under periodically reviewed (s,S) policy. Cachon and Fisher (2000) quantify the value of information sharing with a batching allocation rule between one supplier and multiple retailers. These two papers model batching in replenishment, which is not amenable to exact and mathematically-tractable analysis. The following papers adopt a “linear replenishment rule,” in which orders are linear in past observed variables. Balakrishnan et al. (2004) propose an “order smoothing” inventory policy where the order is a convex combination of historical demands. Miyaoka and Hausman (2004) use the old demand forecasts to set the base stock level and show this can reduce the bullwhip effect. Graves et al. (1998) and Aviv (2001b) study the production smoothing policy and Chen and Lee (2009) extend it to a more general order-up-to policy (GOUTP), which bears an affine and time-invariant structure of the forecast revisions. We prove that our main result still holds under GOUTP (see Online Companion). According to the replenishment policy we observed at the firm that provided us with

6

the data, our paper introduces an order rule that keeps the days of inventory constant and uses some order smoothing. Such policy specifies the order as a linear combination of past demands and inventory. To summarize, the ARIMA model determines our input demand structure and the linear policy dictates how demand propagates through the supply chain. As reviewed in Section 1, Gaur et al. (2005) and Giloni et al. (2012) are the two most closely related works to our paper. They assume that the decision maker strictly and consistently follows the replenishment policy. They conclude that under certain demand and policy parameters, the value of sharing the demand information is zero. Under such strict policy adherence, orders only depend on the observed demand or demand signals. In practice, however, decision makers adjust their purchases by other factors. To account for these factors, we introduce an “error term” into the empirical model with the interpretation of a state variable observed by the agent but not by the statistician, in the spirit of Rust (1997). Therefore, our theoretical model differs from the existing literature in relaxing the strict adherence to the replenishment policy. Such an extension explains our substantial empirically evaluated value of information sharing, thus fills the gap between the literature and the empirical observation. Empirical Work. A growing body of empirical literature analyzes the bullwhip effect and information sharing. Cachon et al. (2007) investigate a wide range of industries and show insignificant variance amplification for some industries. Bray and Mendelson (2012b) further decompose the bullwhip by short, middle and long lead time signals. In the gaming environment, agents have incentives to partially rely on the data or share untruthful information. Cohen et al. (2003) model the supplier’s optimal production starting time after receiving forecasts by the retailer. The estimated high cost of starting the production too early indicates the supplier’s tendency to ignore the retailer’s early forecast, thus inferring the low efficiency of forecast sharing. Terwiesch et al. (2005) also conclude the low efficient forecast sharing by finding the agent’s forecast behavior falls in the noncooperative scenario. Bray and Mendelson (2012a) characterize the demand propagation under the MMFE structure and GOUTP rule. The authors suggest the positive value for the upstream supplier if the retailer better forecasts the demand. Using an econometric model, Dong et al. (2011) find that the inventory decision-making transfer between firms, which means the supplier manages the retailer’s inventory, benefit both upstream and downstream firms. They show a negative relation between the decision transfer and distributor’s average inventory. Route (2003) captures the order demand correlation including the retailer’s point of sale data, and evaluates the forecast accuracy improvement. Our study also applies the method to include the downstream demand information. In our paper, the retailer’s demand information is an additional indicator included to help forecasting supplier orders. Similarly, one can use other potential indicators to predict customer demand, e.g. financial market index or accounting variables (see Gaur et al. 2009 and Kesavan et al. 2009, among others).

7

3.

Including Downstream Demand Improves Order Forecasting

The goal of this section is to provide an empirical evidence that incorporating downstream sales data improves order forecast accuracy compared to the benchmark where the sales information is not shared. In this section, we proceed as follows: we first explain the supply chain structure; we then describe the data set; we next illustrate the forecasting procedure and finally show the empirical results. Supply chain setting. We consider a two-echelon supply chain with a supplier and a retailer. The retailer places an order Ot to the supplier in each period t. In each period, the supplier predicts the future order, e.g. the 1-step prediction for period t given the history through period t − 1, which ˆ we denote as Ot−1,t (throughout the paper, hat denotes forecasted quantities). The prediction error ˆ is the difference between the actual order and its predicted value, Ot − Ot−1,t . We will measure the forecast accuracy as a function of the prediction error using two metrics for our empirical study. The supplier aims to improve the forecast accuracy of future orders. We will compare the forecast accuracy under two settings: NoInfoSharing and InfoSharing. The NoInfoSharing denotes the setting when the supplier only has access to the retailer’s order history. Under the InfoSharing setting, in addition to the order data, the retailer also shares her sales history with the supplier. Data. We obtain the data from a CPG company, which is a leading manufacturer and supplier in the US beverage and snack food industry. We utilize a specific retail customer’s (1) sales from the retailer distribution center and (2) replenishment fulfillment from the supplier, over 126 weeks between 2009 and 2011. The sales data corresponds to the actual demand due to the few stockout. We study two brands of products: a sports drink and orange juice. We choose 14 low-promotional products for the study because of their stationary nature1 . Forecasting procedure. For the purpose of our study, we choose the last 26 weeks in our data as the out-of-sample test period. This out-of-sample comparison is made in two stages. First, we forecast the 1-period-ahead order over the out-of-sample test period. To be specific, the forecast begins 26 weeks before the end of the data. Given information history through the end of period t − 1, we predict the order for period t. Then we update the information history from the beginning of the data through the end of week t to predict for period t+1. We periodically update the available information history to obtain the order forecast and calculate the forecast error by comparing the actual observation and predicted value. Second, we conduct tests of equal forecast accuracy on the two sequences of forecast errors generated from two candidate forecasting methods. Next we explain the NoInfoSharing and InfoSharing forecasting methods. For the NoInfoSharing benchmark, we use order history to predict future orders. We fit the autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) model to the order history to obtain the best estimator with the
1

The stationary nature means the sales process has constant mean and covariance over time.

8

lower Bayesian information criterion (BIC)2 . We then predict the order by applying the estimated ARIMA model. The ARIMA model is generally referred to as an ARIMA(p, d, q) model where p, d and q are non-negative integers that refer to the degree of the autoregressive, integrated and moving average parts of the model respectively. In the ARIMA structure, the order is a linear combination of past
1 observations and shocks. The “first order differenced” process Ot − Ot−1 will be denoted by Ot . 1 We assume Ot is an ARMA(p, q) process 1 1 1 1 Ot = µ + ρ1 Ot−1 + ρ2 Ot−2 + · · · + ρp Ot−p + ηt + λ1 ηt−1 + λ2 ηt−2 + · · · + λq ηt−q .

(1)

where µ is the process mean, ηt is the order shock, ρi is the autoregressive parameter and λi is the moving average coefficient. Suppose the available information history is through the end of period 1 1 1 ˆ1 t − 1, the differenced order forecast for period t is Ot−1,t = µ + ρ1 Ot−1 + ρ2 Ot−2 + · · · + ρp Ot−p +
1 ˆ λ1 ηt−1 + λ2 ηt−2 + · · · + λq ηt−q or the order forecast for period t is Ot−1,t = Ot−1 + µ + ρ1 Ot−1 + 1 1 ρ2 Ot−2 + · · · + ρp Ot−p + λ1 ηt−1 + λ2 ηt−2 + · · · + λq ηt−q .

To analyze the impact of including retail demand data, we consider four InfoSharing forecasting methods: three “naive” methods and our “advanced” method. The “naive” methods capture the correlation between order and demand by specifying a linear model. The “advanced” method considers a specific replenishment policy, which we will discuss in detail in Section 4 and Section 6. The “advanced” method is used to evaluate the additional value of carefully considering the underlying order policy structure over the naive ones. We refer to such forecast scheme as the policy structure method. The first two naive methods capture the order demand correlation by regressing order on demands, or on both orders and demands, within the past five periods. If regressing order only on demands, we refer to this method as Reg D method where the order is expressed as Ot = c0 Dt + c1 Dt−1 + · · · + c5 Dt−5 + εt . (2)

ˆ We fit the ARIMA model to the demand process to forecast Dt−1,t . With the parameters estimated ˆ ˆ from equation (2), the order prediction in period t becomes Ot−1,t = c0 Dt−1,t + c1 Dt−1 + · · · + c5 Dt−5 . In the second naive method refered to as “Reg D and O” method, we regress order on historical demands and orders. This method expresses the order as Ot = c0 Dt + c1 Dt−1 + · · · + c5 Dt−5 + b1 Ot−1 + · · · + b5 Ot−5 + εt . (3)

As the demand Dt is not known at time t − 1, we fit the ARIMA model to the demand process to ˆ forecast Dt−1,t . With the parameters estimated from equation (3), the order prediction in period t ˆ ˆ becomes Ot−1,t = c0 Dt−1,t + c1 Dt−1 + · · · + c5 Dt−5 + b1 Ot−1 + · · · + b5 Ot−5 .
2

BIC is a criterion for model section for time series analysis and model regression. It selects the set of parameters that maximizes the likelihood function with the least number of parameters in the model.

9

The third naive method adds the observed demands to equation (1), i.e. it assumes
1 1 1 1 Ot = µ + ρ1 Ot−1 + ρ2 Ot−2 + · · · + ρp Ot−p + ηt + λ1 ηt−1 + λ2 ηt−2 + · · · + λq ηt−q

(4)

+a0 Dt + a1 Dt−1 + · · · + ap Dt−p .
1 A forecast for Ot then can be achieved in two steps: estimate the parameters in equation (4) and ˆ obtain the demand forecast Dt−1,t . The parameters in equation (4) can be estimated by fitting

Ot and Dt+1 series in a two dimensional vector ARIMA model. Note that equation (4) serves as a more general method than equation (1). We specify a vector ARIMA(3, 1, 1)3 model with µ = 0 for Ot . As the demand Dt is not known at time t − 1, the ARIMA model is fitted to ˆ the demand process to forecast Dt−1,t . The differenced order forecast for period t then becomes 1 1 ˆ1 ˆ Ot−1,t = µ + ρ1 Ot−1 + · · · + ρp Ot−p + λ1 ηt−1 + · · · + λq ηt−q + a0 Dt + a1 Dt−1 + · · · + ap Dt−p . We adopt the vector ARIMA model to estimate and forecast the process and thus we refer to this as the Vector ARIMA method. To measure the accuracy of various methods, we introduce two forecast error metrics used in the literature: mean absolute percentage error (MAPE) and mean squared zero-mean error (MSE). Let N be the number of weeks in the test period. The forecast metrics over the test period are: M AP E = M SE =
N 1 ∑ ˆ Ot+i − Ot+i−1,t+i /Ot+i , N i=1 N N 1 ∑ 1 ∑ ˆ ˆ (Ot+i − Ot+i−1,t+i − (Ot+i − Ot+i−1,t+i ))2 . N i=1 N i=1

(5)

MAPE is a widely used accuracy metrics in the literature (cf. Gaur et al. 2009, Kesavan et al. 2009). This metric is also closely related to the metric used by the company from which we received the data. MSE is a frequently adopted accuracy metric in the theoretical literature because of its mathematical tractability. We will also use this metric for our theoretical analysis. Note that in ∑N ˆ the MSE definition, i=1 (Ot+i − Ot+i−1,t+i )/N is the mean of the forecast error and as the sample ∑N ˆ size N goes to infinity, (Ot+i − Ot+i−1,t+i )/N → 0 under unbiased estimates. Therefore, as the i=1 sample size is large enough, the mean squared zero-mean error coincides with the mean squared error used in the theory literature. With the alternative forecasting models, we empirically assess the value of incorporating the downstream information. To this end, we perform a product-by-product forecast accuracy comparison. The disaggregated analysis enables a detailed detection for each product. We conduct the
] [ 1 1 ][ d ] [ 3 3 ][ d ] [ ] [ 1 1 ][ ] d Ot c c Ot−1 c c Ot−3 ηt e e ηt−1 = 11 12 + · · · + 11 12 + + 11 12 , 1 1 3 3 1 1 d d d ϵt+1 ϵt c21 c22 c21 c22 e21 e22 Dt+1 Dt Dt−2 i i 1 1 1 where c21 and c22 are restricted to zero for i = 1, 2, 3. e12 , e21 and e22 are restricted to zero, ηt is order shock and ϵt is demand shock. The larger the degree of AR and MA, the broader order pattern relative to the parameters found in equation (1). We choose (3, 1, 1) due to the computational constraints. Such parameter can represent the majority of parameters found in equation (1).
3

[

VARIMA(3, 1, 1) model is

10
Table 1

MAPE and MSE percentage improvement for the four methods that incorporate the

downstream demand data. Significant accuracy improvement over the no sharing method is marked by star. Significant (p = 0.1) accuracy improvement of the policy structure method over the unbold others is marked with bold value. MAPE percentage improvement Vector Reg D Reg D Policy ARIMA and O Structure 11.1% 12.2%* -14.6% 45.0%** -18.3% 8.1% 1.9% 30.3%* * 31.6% 15.7% 50.2% 58.6%* ** ** 40.8% 40.0% 38.0%** 50.2%** 16.1%* 4.1% 5.0% 18.8%* ** ** ** 12.8% 29.1% 23.8% 27.7%** 21.2% 26.2% 25.5% 39.8%** * 30.9% 25.7% 26.5% 36.0%** 2.8% -15.5% -18.4% 4.7% 26.8%** 26.2%** 26.2%** 44.2%** 22.1% 8.2% 11.4% 39.5%* 23.7%** 30.3%** 26.4%** 38.0%** 24.3%** 21.4%* 17.2% 29.9%** 16.9%* 18.3%* 14.0% 30.4%* MSE Vector ARIMA 8.7% -0.5% 32.4%** 30.5% 13.2%* 16.2%** 54.1%** 53.1%** 5.6% 43.3%* 44.5%** 50.1%** 46.4%** 30.2% percentage improvement Reg D Reg D Policy and O Structure 14.0%** 0.4% 18.1%** * 7.8% 18.8% 26.5%** ** 33.8% 35.1%** 53.4%** 36.3% 57.3%** 53.1%** 10.9% 10.7% 7.1% 31.0%** 11.4% 29.4%** ** * 48.7% 41.7% 62.5%** * * 42.9% 38.7% 68.4%** 30.9% 31.3% 51.3% 81.0%* 81.0%* 81.1%* 8.2% 9.2% 56.9%** 42.9%* 40.1%* 54.2%** 40.3%** 31.3%* 54.0%** 21.2% 18.3% 44.8%**

Brand Orange Juice

Sports Drink

Product 128 OR 128 ORCA 12 OR 12 ORCA 59 ORST 59 ORPC 500 BR 500 GP PD LL PD OR PD FRZ 1GAL GLC 1GAL FRT 1GAL OR

** At level p < 0.05, the accuracy improvement over no information sharing method is significant. * At level p < 0.1, the accuracy improvement over no information sharing method is significant.

pairwise t-test to determine the statistical significance of forecast performance improvement. Table 1 presents the MAPE and MSE percentage improvement of the four InfoSharing methods over the NoInfoSharing method for each product. The MAPE percentage improvement of method 1 over method 2 is given by (M AP E1 − M AP E2 )/M AP E1 . Similarly, the MSE percentage improvement is (M SE1 − M SE2 )/M SE1 . The larger the percentage improvement, the more accurate the forecast with information sharing. We carry out two sets of comparisons: the improvement with respect to the NoInfoSharing forecast and the improvement of the policy structure forecast over other forecasts. The star mark means that the forecast improvement with respect to the NoInfoSharing method is statistically significant. The policy structure forecast in bold induces a statistically significant improvement over the unbold forecasts. Table 1 delivers two key messages. First, for all products, at least one of the InfoSharing methods generates statistically significant improvement over the NoInfoSharing method for one error metric4 . On average, the NoInfoSharing forecasts have the lowest accuracy with MAPE around 56%, the number of which is representative of the typical number we observe at the CPG company. From these, we infer that for each product, the improvement of including the downstream demand
4

∑ ∑ ˆ The mean absolute error (MAE) is defined as N Ot+i − Ot+i−1,t+i / N Ot+i . For the product PD LL, the i=1 i=1 MAE metric shows that the policy structure method is statistically significantly (p < 0.1) better than the NoInfoSharing method, although both MAPE and MSE metrics indicate insignificant improvement.

11

information is statistically significant. Furthermore, we test whether considering the replenishment policy further strengthens the InfoSharing forecasts. The second message is that incorporating the policy structure yields the greatest or one of the greatest improvements. For the MAPE metric, the policy structure method has the highest improvement for all products and statistically higher improvement than all other forecast methods at p < 0.1 for 5 out 14 products. For the MSE metric, the policy structure method has statistically significantly higher improvement than all other forecast methods at p < 0.1 for 6 out of 14 products. The forecasts generated from the naive methods can be statistically indistinguishable from the policy structure method for some products. This means the naive methods can correctly capture the correlation between orders and demands for those products. On average, however, the policy structure method yields 40% MAPE percentage improvement, which is statistically significantly (p = 0.05) higher than the three naive methods5 . To summarize, (1) the downstream demand information adds positive value to the order forecast even if it is incorporated in a simple way but (2) incorporating the policy structure shows the largest improvement. Moreover, we will later develop theory to predict for which product characteristics we expect high forecast accuracy improvement.

4.

Model Setup

In this section, we describe the model setup and some preliminary results on the value of sharing information. Recall that we introduced a two-echelon supply chain in section 3. There are two key ingredients in our model: customer demand and the firm’s replenishment policy. Notice that the policy we will illustrate coincides with the policy structure method we discussed in section 3. In this section, we introduce the actual policy followed by the company that we studied, which we will call the ConDI policy with order smoothing. We then show that the main result from Giloni et al. (2012) and Gaur et al. (2005) still holds if the retailer follows such a replenishment policy. The contradicting empirical evidence, however, suggests the theoretical model fails to capture a key element which is the decision deviation. The decision deviation relaxes the assumption, commonly made in the literature, that the decision maker perfectly adheres to the inventory replenishment policy. And finally, we develop the order process under such relaxation. Recall that we consider a supply chain with two stages. The retailer is faced with demand Dt and places order Ot to the supplier during week t. There is a transportation lead time LR from the supplier to the retailer. The supplier is the retailer’s only source. Backlogging is allowed for the retailer. The retailer and supplier review their inventory periodically. Within each period, the following sequence of events occur: (1) the retailer’s demand is realized and then the retailer places an order to the supplier, (2) after receiving the order, the supplier releases the shipment, (3) then
5

We also assess the overall prediction improvement for these four InfoSharing methods (see Online Companion).

12

the supplier collects the latest information and predicts the future h-step ahead orders, (4) based on the updated prediction, the supplier makes production and replenishment decisions. 4.1. Demand Process

During each week t, the retailer faces demand Dt . We assume that Dt follows an autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) process. The model is generally referred to as an ARIMA(p, d, q) model, where p, d and q represent the degree of the autoregressive, integrated and moving average parts of the model, respectively. The ARIMA model assumes that demand is a linear combination of historical observations and demand shocks. We first illustrate the demand process under d = 0 and then derive the abbreviated expression for d ≥ 0. When d = 0, the ARIMA(p, 0, q) process is reduced to an ARMA(p, q) process Dt = µ + ρ1 Dt−1 + ρ2 Dt−2 + · · · + ρp Dt−p + ϵt − λ1 ϵt−1 − λ2 ϵt−2 − · · · − λq ϵt−q . (6)

2 where µ is the process mean, ϵt is an i.i.d. normal demand shock with zero mean and variance σϵ ,

ρi is the autoregressive coefficient and λi is the moving average coefficient. The backward shift operator B shifts variables backward in time; e.g. B d Dt shifts demand back by d times B d Dt = Dt−d , and (1 − B)Dt differences demand once (1 − B)Dt = Dt − Dt−1 . Differencing the demand twice means differencing Dt − Dt−1 one more time, (1 − B)2 Dt = Dt − 2Dt−1 + Dt−2 . Similarly, (1 − B)d Dt differences the demand d times, which we refer to as the dth-order differenced demand. We assume the mean of demand is constant. Under this assumption, E[(1 − B)d Dt ] = 0 for d > 0, which means the differenced demand (1 − B)d Dt is a zero-mean ARMA process. Therefore, the differenced demand has process mean µ = 0 for d > 0. Let the AR coefficient be denoted as ϕAR (B) = 1 − ρ1 B − ρ2 B 2 − · · · − ρp B p , the integration coefficient as π(B) = (1 − B)d , the ARI coefficient as ϕARI (B) = ϕAR (B)π(B) and the MA coefficient as φM A (B) = 1 − λ1 B − λ2 B 2 − · · · − λq B q . If we assume π(B)Dt is an ARMA(p, q) process, then Dt is an ARIMA(p, d, q) process with d ≥ 0. Then we replace Dt by (1 − B)d Dt in equation (6), and rewrite equation (6) as ϕARI (B)Dt = µ + φM A (B)ϵt . We can rewrite the dth differenced demand π(B)Dt in equation(7) as an MA representation π(B)Dt = µ + φ(B)ϵt . (8) (7)

where µ is the process mean, φ(B) = ϕ−1 (B)φM A (B) is the coefficient. We work with the MA AR representation because it provides the same intuition as an ARMA representation with a more concise analysis. In the rest of this section, we will review two basic, yet important, properties of an MA process from the time series literature: covariance stationarity and invertibility. For details, we refer readers

13

to Hamilton (1994) and Brockwell and Davis (2002). We assume the dth differenced demand is covariance stationary; that is, the differenced demand has a finite and constant mean, finite variance and time invariant covariance of π(B)Dt and π(B)Dt+h for any t and h. One might think that the MA model is restricted to a convenient class of models. However, representation (7) is fundamental for any covariance stationary time series. Any covariance stationary process is equivalent to an MA process in terms of the same covariance matrix (Wold 1938). Therefore, assuming the ARIMA model is not restrictive. We adopt Hamilton (1994, p. 109)’s description of the equivalence between the stationarity and MA representation, which is known as the Wold Decomposition property. Property 1 (Wold Decomposition) Any zero-mean covariance stationary process Xt can be ∑∞ ∑∞ represented in the MA form Xt = i=0 αi ϵt−i , where αo = 1 and i=0i α2 < ∞. The term ϵt is ˆ white noise and represents the error in forecasting: ϵt ≡ Xt − E(Xt |Xt−1 , Xt−2 , . . .). An MA process is determined by a unique covariance matrix. A covariance stationary process may have multiple MA representations in terms of different sets of coefficients αi relative to their corresponding white noise series. Among the alternative representations, we are only interested in one that leads to the second property: invertibility. An MA process Xt = µ + φ(B)ϵt is invertible relative to {ϵt } if the shock can be written as an absolutely summable sequence of past demands. ∑n An infinite sequence {αt } is said to be absolutely summable if limn→∞ i=0 |αi | is finite. Property 2 (Invertibility) Define φ(z) = 1 − λ1 z 1 − λ2 z 2 − · · · − λq z q . Then ϵt can be written as an absolutely summable series of {Xs } with s ≤ t, if and only if all roots of φ(z) = 0 lie outside of the unit circle, {z ∈ C, |z | > 1}. We say that Xt is invertible relative to {ϵt }. The invertibility guarantees future-independence: Xt is only correlated with past value of ϵt . Noninvertibility would allow for correlation with future values, which is undesirable. Invertibility is a property of the MA coefficients relative to the corresponding white noise series. According to Brockwell and Davis (2002, p. 54), for any noninvertible process Xt = φ(B)ϵt , we can find a new white noise sequence {wt } such that Xt = φ′ (B)wt and Xt is invertible relative to {wt }. We say that the coefficient φ′ (B) is in the invertible representation. Therefore, when estimating the parameters of a time series process, estimators are restricted in the invertible set. That is, the empirically identified parameters have invertible representations. Henceforth, we assume the differenced demand process, (1 − B)d Dt , satisfies invertibility. This assumption has both intuitive appeal and technical consequences (for Proposition 1 and 3). As Hamilton (1994, p. 68) points out, an MA process has at most one invertible representation, which has larger white noise variance than any other noninvertible representations. Later, we will illustrate that the enlarged white noise caused by converting from the noninvertible to invertible representation, is one trigger to the positive value of information sharing.

14

4.2.

The Theoretical Model

To understand the policy used in practice, we interviewed the planner that placed orders. According to the planner, the retailer aims at keeping the DOI (days of inventory) level of the total on-hand inventory and in transit inventory constant. The decision maker also admits that the end inventory might not reach the target days of inventory level because the actual replenishment is not fast enough, i.e. retailer’s capacity restriction. The smoothed order can explain such phenomenon both theoretically and empirically. We refer to the policy with smoothed order as the “ConDI policy with order smoothing”, where “Con” represents constant, “DI” represents days of inventory and “order smoothing” captures a linear control rule that smoothes orders to produce a desirable order-up-to level. We first define the ConDI policy and then extend it with order smoothing. Under a ConDI policy, the retailer places an order at the end of week t so that the inventory level reaches the week of inventory level (7−1 × target DOI level) multiplies the retailer’s total future demand forecast within transportation lead time LR . For example, if the target DOI level equals 14 and LR equals 2, the retailer orders up to 2× the demand forecast of next two weeks. If the demand is i.i.d distributed, then the optimal order up to level is constant, which coincides with the ConDI policy. When demands are correlated, the optimal order up to level changes every period. A fluctuating inventory target level is not convenient from the management perspective. Therefore, the ConDI policy becomes an attractive policy in practice. We assume the DOI level Γ is positive and constant. We assume that the retailer’s demand ˆR forecast for week t + k made in week t is Dt,t+k . Then the retailer’s order-up-to level at the end of ∑LR ˆ R week t is Γ k=1 Dt,t+k , where LR is the transportation lead time from the supplier to the retailer. According to the planner, their forecast of future demands is a linear combination of past demands. Therefore, we assume the retailer’s forecast of future LR period demands given Dt , Dt−1 , ... is a linear combination of past H demands and we denote it as mt ˆ mt ≡ ˆ
LR ∑ k=1 H ∑ j=0

ˆR Dt,t+k =

βj Dt−j .

(9)

where βj is the coefficient of demand in past jth period. The sum of the demand coefficients is the ∑H retailer’s lead time, j=0 βj = LR . When LR = 1, the forecast is the weighted sum of the current and past H periods’ demands. In order to capture order smoothing, we extend the ConDI policy by allowing a fixed proportion of last week’s inventory to become the current week’s inventory. Irvine (1981) introduces a similar notion and empirically confirms that firms attempt a partial adjustment towards the optimum level. Balancing the product inflow and outflow, the sum of the proportion of last week’s inventory and target inventory under the ConDI policy should equal 1. Therefore, the inventory becomes It = γΓmt + (1 − γ)It−1 . ˆ (10)

15

where γ is the order smoothing level, which takes values in [0, 1]. Given the fundamental law of material conservation, Ot = Dt + It − It−1 , equation (10) becomes Ot = Dt + γ(Γmt − It−1 ). ˆ (11)

The order in week t is the current week’s demand plus γ fraction of the net inventory under the ConDI policy. If γ = 1, it is reduced to the strict ConDI policy. If γ = 0, it becomes the demand replenishment policy. The larger γ, the faster the order adjusts to the target ConDI inventory level. The order smoothing component enables the extension of the ConDI policy to a rich family of linear policies. We can iteratively replace It−i with γΓmt−i + (1 − γ)It−i−1 for any i ≥ 0 in equation (11). We ˆ define ai ≡ Γβi for 0 ≤ i ≤ H, where ai is the policy coefficient of the past ith demand. Then ∑H Γmt = j=0 aj Dt−j and the order becomes ˆ Ot = D t + γ We define ψ(B) ≡ 1 + γ ∑H
H ∑ i=0 i

ai Dt−i − γ 2
− γ2 i=1 ∞ ∑ i=1

(1 − γ)i−1

H ∑ j=0

aj Dt−i−j .

(12)

i=0 ai B

∑∞ ∑H

j=0 (1

− γ)i−1 aj B i+j as the policy parameter.

Applying the backshift operator, we abbreviate equation (12) as Ot = ψ(B)Dt . Thus we have π(B)Ot = π(B)ψ(B)Dt . Since demand satisfies π(B)Dt = µ + φ(B)ϵt , the demand process can be written as π(B)ψ(B)Dt = µ + φ(B)ψ(B)ϵt . Therefore, the order process follows an ARIMA process with white noise {ϵt }: π(B)Ot = µ + φ(B)ψ(B)ϵt . (13)

Equation (13) has the same expression as equation (7) in Gaur et al. (2005): order is linear in demand shocks. It is worth noting that our policy parameters ψ(B) capture a broader linear policy than the myopic order up to policy considered in Gaur et al. (2005). The myopic order up to policy corresponds to a special case when γ = 1 in equation (12) (this is equivalent to equation (4) in Gaur et al. 2005). The coefficients of ϵt in equation (13) are obtained by multiplying the demand coefficient φ(B) of ϵt in Dt with the policy coefficient ψ(B) of Dt in Ot . Therefore, the first coefficient in equation (13) is C ≡ 1 + γa0 . We normalize the first coefficient to be 1. Then the centered order follows an MA process with white noise {Cϵt } π(B)Ot − µ = C −1 φ(B)ψ(B)Cϵt . (14)

The analysis of the value of information sharing. As introduced in section 3, the supplier aims to forecast the future order. In the rest of this section, we will focus on the 1-step ahead forecast as it provides the insight to the positive value of information sharing and serves as the

16

theoretical foundation that we can compare with the empirical results. Section 6 will discuss the h-step ahead forecast in detail in a more general setting. In our theoretical analysis, we adopt a mathematically tractable forecast error metric: the mean squared forecast error. We denote the space that contains the linear combination of the order history from period 1 to period t and all its limit points as ΩO . By definition, ΩO is the Hilbert t t space generated by the order history. Therefore, ΩO ∪ ΩD includes both the order and demand t t history. According to the Projection Theorem, the unique optimal estimator to minimize the mean ˆ squared error can be found conditional on either ΩO or ΩO ∪ ΩD . As before, we denote it as Ot,t+1 . t t t ˆ The 1-step mean squared forecast error without information sharing is Var(Ot+1 − Ot,t+1 |ΩO ) and t ˆ t,t+1 |ΩO ∪ ΩD ). The value of information sharing is positive if with sharing is Var(Ot+1 − O t t ˆ ˆ Var(Ot+1 − Ot,t+1 |ΩO ) > Var(Ot+1 − Ot,t+1 |ΩO ∪ ΩD ). t t t (15)

With downstream demand information, the demand and policy parameters can be estimated. We assume the parameters can be correctly estimated and are known to the supplier. The only ˆ uncertainty in Ot,t+1 − Ot+1 stems from the demand shock occurring in t + 1. Therefore, Var(Ot+1 − ˆ Ot,t+1 |ΩO ∪ ΩD ) = Var(Cϵt ). t t Without information sharing, the supplier analyzes the order history as an MA process. The MA process in equation (14) may not be invertible with respect to {Cϵt }. If not, we can find an invertible representation relative to a new white noise series {wt }, which has a larger variance than Var(Cϵt ). Then inequality (15) holds and thus the value is positive. Gaur et al. (2005) and Giloni et al. (2012) show similar intuitions for the positive value of information sharing. The following proposition states the sufficient and necessary condition that sharing demand benefit the supplier’s order forecast. Proposition 1 If the decision maker strictly adheres to the replenishment policy, the value of information sharing under the one step forecast lead time is positive if and only if at least one root of ψ(z) = 0 lies inside the unit circle. The value of information sharing is positive if and only if φ(B)ψ(B) is in the noninvertible representation, which in turn is equivalent to the existence of at least one root of φ(z)ψ(z) = 0 that lies inside the unit circle. Since all roots of φ(z) = 0 lie outside the unit circle due to the invertible assumption, the order is noninvertible relative to ϵt if and only if there exists at least one root of ψ(z) = 0 that lies inside the unit circle. Remark. We next illustrate two extreme setting of γ = 0 and γ = 1 and show that in both setting there is no value of information sharing. When γ = 0, it becomes the demand replacement policy Ot = Dt and ψ(z) = 1. Since no root of ψ(z) = 0 lies inside the unit circle, the value of information

17

sharing is zero. When γ = 1 and H = 0, it becomes the ConDI policy with policy parameter ψ(z) = ∑H 1 + a0 − a0 z. Since j=0 aj = ΓLR , coefficient a0 is positive. Since the unique root of ψ(z) = 0 is larger than 1, z = (1 + a0 )/a0 > 1, the value of sharing is zero. From these two examples, we can see that the value of information sharing under a strict replenishment policy can be zero. 4.3. The Empirical Model: Decision Deviations

The empirical results in section 3 indicate incorporating the downstream demand properly yields statistically significantly positive value of information sharing for all low-promotional products. The above theoretical results, however, suggest zero value for 10 out of 14 products based on the estimated parameters that we will show in Section 6. These empirical deviations call for a better theoretical understanding of the model in previous literature. The key underlying assumption in the theoretical model described above and in the literature is that the decision maker strictly and consistently follows a family of linear decision rules. Our discussion with the replenishment decision maker suggests this is rarely the case because the decision makers can implement their own adjustment based on the additional signals that we do not observe. The empirically observed idiosyncratic shocks in the order decisions also indicate that the decision makers may not replenish as the theory requires, or that the theoretical model does not capture all elements of reality. From the interview with the planner, we understand that the deviation from the theoretical model stems from several operational causes. The order quantity is rounded due to transportation and truck load constraints. To increase transportation efficiency, the retailer tries to fill up a full truck when placing an order. Products with inventory above the target DOI level might still be replenished because delivering in batches can decrease set up cost. Such a phenomenon is common as the week approaches Friday, because the decision maker needs to guarantee enough inventory. Orders might be moved from peak to nonpeak periods if planners anticipate a spike in future demands (Donselaar et al. 2010 also points out such advancing orders as an important consideration of the decision maker). In practice, the retailer might place orders daily. However, for this study, we have access only to the weekly aggregate level instead of daily information. Looking through the lens of the aggregate data, we lose the detail on the replenishment decision, which is reflected by the actual order’s departure from the theory. Among the above different operational drivers, a common characteristic is that the decision maker adjusts replenishment according to those drivers while statisticians cannot observe them. We rationalize the agent’s departure from the exact policy following the same spirit as Rust (1997): it is a state variable which is observed by the agent but not by the statistician. Since the actual observations always contain randomness from the observational perspective of the analyst, the

18

empirical model should successfully capture it and might yield qualitatively different results than the literature. We extend the theoretical framework by including the idiosyncratic shocks in decision making, and thus relax the strict adherence to the ConDI with order smoothing policy. We refer to such idiosyncratic shocks as decision deviation. The decision deviation is observable to the retailer, but not to statistician. We assume the decision deviation δt is normally distributed with zero mean
2 and variance σδ , and independent with historical demand shock ϵs , s < t. However, contemporane-

ous demand signals and decision deviation signals can be correlated. A common approach in the empirical literature is to model this error term as additively separable, in the decision. Using this approach, we obtain Ot = Dt + γ(Γmt − It−1 ) + δt . ˆ (16)

As before, we iteratively replace It−i with γΓmt−i + (1 − γ)It−i−1 + δt−i in equation (16) and ˆ obtain Ot = Dt + γ
H ∑ i=0 ∞ ∑ i=1 H ∑ j=0 ∞ ∑ i=1

ai Dt−i − γ ∑∞

2

(1 − γ)

i−1

aj Dt−i−j + δt −

γ(1 − γ)i−1 δt−i .

(17)

We define κ(B) = 1 − γ

i−1 i B i=1 (1 − γ)

as the order smoothing parameter. Applying the back-

shift operator, equation (17) can be abbreviated as Ot = ψ(B)Dt + κ(B)δt . Applying π(B) to both sides, order process can be abbreviated as: π(B)Ot = µ + φ(B)ψ(B)ϵt + π(B)κ(B)δt . (18)

where µ is the process mean, φ(B)ψ(B) is the demand shock coefficient and π(B)κ(B) is the decision deviation coefficient. ARMA-in-ARMA-out property. The order with decision deviation has a stationary covariance. According to property 1, the order process in equation (18) follows an ARIMA model. This is consistent with the “ARMA-in-ARMA-out” (AIAO) property discussed in the literature (Zhang 2004, Gilbert 2005, Gaur et al. 2005 and Giloni et al. 2012), where AIAO means that the retailer’s order process is also an ARMA process with respect to the demand shock. If the replenishment policy is an affine and time invariant function of the historical demand, inventory, demand shock and decision deviation, the order process has a stationary covariance. Therefore, the AIAO property holds for such policies.

5.

Strictly Positive Value of Information Sharing

In this section, we study the impact of decision deviation on the value of information sharing and prove that the value of information sharing is always positive if there is uncertainty in both decision deviation and demand processes.

19

We rewrite the order in equation (18) as a centered process Ot − π −1 (B)µ = C −1 π −1 (B)φ(B)ψ(B)Cϵt + κ(B)δt . (19)

where the constant C normalizes the first coefficient to one as defined before. Let qϵ denote the degree of π −1 (B)φ(B)ψ(B) and qδ denote the degree of κ(B). The centered order is the summation of two MA processes with demand shock and decision deviation as their corresponding white noise series. We study the value of information sharing with the existence of decision deviations. Preliminary results. Our key question is closely related to the general goal of forecasting the aggregation of multiple MA processes. Consider N MA processes (N can be infinite) where the process i is Xti = χi (B)ϵi with i.i.d. t random shock ϵi . The coefficient is χi (B) = 1 + λi B + λi B 2 + · · · + λi i B qi with degree qi . When pret 1 2 q dicting future value beyond qi periods, the forecast is constant and uncertainty cannot be resolved. Thus qi denotes the effective forecasting range for process Xti . We allow contemporaneous signals to be correlated, but require signals to be independent across periods. That is, ϵi is independent t of ϵj for any s < t. The summation of these N processes is s St =
N ∑ i=1

Xti .

(20)

According to Property 1, St can be rewritten as an MA process with degree qS ≥ 0, where qS is the largest k that guarantees nonzero covariance Cov(St , St+k ) ̸= 0. With full information (or with information sharing), we have access to each process’s history and parameters. With aggregate information (or without information sharing), we only have access to the aggregate process St . As before, ΩX and ΩS denotes the Hilbert space generated by Xti t t i ˆ ˆ and St history through period t. Let Xt,t+h and St+h denote the best estimator to minimize the i mean squared forecast error for Xt+h and St+h . With information sharing, the h-step ahead mean i ˆ squared error is Var(St+h − St,t+h | ∪i ΩX ). Without information sharing, the h-step ahead mean t ˆ squared error is Var(St+h − St,t+h |ΩS ). The value is positive for forecast lead time h if Var(St+h − t i ˆ ˆ St,t+h | ∪i ΩX ) < Var(St+h − St,t+h |ΩS ). The following theorem states the sufficient and necessary t t i

condition for the zero value of information sharing. Theorem 2 The 1-step mean squared forecast error is the same with and without sharing, i ˆ ˆ Var(St+1 − St,t+1 | ∪i ΩX ) = Var(St+1 − St,t+1 |ΩS ) if and only if the M A processes satisfy χi (B) = t t i ˆ χj (B) for any i, j. If there exists i ̸= j such that χi (B) ̸= χj (B), then Var(St+h − St,t+h | ∪i ΩX ) < t ˆ Var(St+h − St,t+h |ΩS ) for any finite forecast lead time h ≤ maxi {qi }. t Among N processes, if coefficients of any two processes differ, the aggregate process has strictly larger mean squared forecast error as long as the forecast is within the effective forecast range of one

20

process, h ≤ maxi {qi }. If qi = 0, Xti becomes an i.i.d. normal model with the coefficient χi (B) = 1. If qi = 0 for all i, the processes have the same coefficients, and thus the value of information sharing is zero. If maxi {qi } = ∞, the value of information sharing is strictly positive for any finite forecast lead time if φi (B) ̸= φj (B). Analysis of our model. Let us apply this general result to the order process in our setting in equation (19). The centered order has the same structure as equation (20), where the two processes are with respect to demand shocks and decision deviations Xt1 = C −1 π −1 (B)φ(B)ψ(B)Cϵt , Xt2 = κ(B)δt . We can apply Theorem 2 to determine whether the value of information sharing is positive. Similar ˆ ˆ as before, if Var(Ot+h − Ot,t+h |ΩO ) > Var(Ot+h − Ot,t+h |ΩO ∪ ΩD ), then the value of information t t t sharing is positive. The following proposition illustrates the result. Proposition 3 If the demand shock and decision deviation are nonzero, the value of information sharing is strictly positive for any finite forecast lead time h ≤ max{qϵ , qδ }. When qϵ = qδ = 0, both Xt1 and Xt2 are i.i.d. processes and St is also an i.i.d. process. Any forecast is a constant, and thus there is no value from sharing the downstream sales information. This situation can only occur when φ(B) = π(B) = ψ(B) = κ(B) = 1, which means the retailer faces an i.i.d. demand processes and adopts a demand replacement policy, which we refer to as “i.i.d demand replacement”. In the rest of the paper, we will exclude the discussion on this situation, because using historical observations cannot resolve any uncertainty of the future forecast. If not both processes are i.i.d. models, or equivalently qϵ = qδ = 0 is not true, then the two sets of parameters C −1 π −1 (B)φ(B)ψ(B) and κ(B) can never be the same. The key ingredient in the proof is to show that the polynomial (1 − B) is a factor in κ(B) but not a factor in C −1 π −1 (B)φ(B)ψ(B). Therefore, the value of information is strictly positive for any forecast lead time. Compared with the conditions on the policy parameter ψ(B) that induces positive value of information sharing under the strict adherence to a linear policy, Proposition 3 establishes a qualitatively different conclusion: the benefit of information sharing is strictly positive within any forecasting period. Under the strict adherence to the inventory policy, the planner makes replenishment decisions based only on information that statisticians also have access to, which leads to a pure demand propagation. The interview with the planner and our data suggests that this is rarely the case and the decision departures from the ideal policy due to private information that statisticians can not observe. Thus, unlike before, the demand now propagates together with the decision deviation. The value of information sharing is zero if the order process carries all demand information and (21)

21

all decision deviation information. The different propagation patterns of the demand process and decision deviation process, however, drive the loss of information as demand and decision deviation propagate upstream. To be specific, the ending inventory level carries current period’s decision deviation and rolls it over to next period’s replenishment decision which further determines the next period’s ending inventory. Thus the evolution of inventory governs the translation of exogenous decision deviation signals into orders. Demand signals, on the other hand, are governed by the evolution of both inventory and current demand. As both signals propagate together to become orders in such innately different patterns, the detailed information of two processes is lost and is replaced with the less informative (larger uncertainty) order signals. Consequently, the value of information sharing becomes positive regardless of the policy parameter ψ(B). The same intuition holds for any linear replenishment policy. It’s worth noting that the evolution patterns of the demand signals and decision deviation signals are different as illustrated above for other ordering policy that is linear in demands and demand signals, i.e. the myopic order up to policy, the ConDI policy with retailer’s demand forecast being optimal (we assume that it is linear in past H demands due to practice in our study) and the generalized order-up-to policy introduced by Chen and Lee (2009) (see Online Companion for more discussion), except for the “i.i.d demand replacement” (of which we care less since forecasting beyond zero period is constant). Therefore, the distinct propagation patterns obscure the detailed information structure, which drives positive value of information sharing for any linear inventory policy under any forecast lead time. Proposition 3 illustrates the value of information sharing when both demand and decision uncertainties are nonzero. If there is no decision deviation, Proposition 1 demonstrates the sufficient and necessary condition of positive value of information sharing. The following proposition, on the other hand, considers another extreme case when demand uncertainty is zero. Proposition 4 When the demand shock is zero, the value of information sharing is zero for any forecast lead time. In absence of demand shock, the centered order is reduced to an MA process with respect to decision deviations, Ot − π −1 (B)µ = κ(B)δt . For the value of sharing downstream information to be zero, the centered order must be invertible relative to δt (equivalent to κ(B) has an invertible representation). The unique root of κ(z ∗ ) = 0 lies on the unit circle, which Plosser and Schwert (1997) defined as strictly non-invertibility. When |z ∗ | = 1, there is no corresponding invertible representation. The author shows that the univariate MA parameter’s estimator is asymptotically similar to the invertible processes, which indicates parameters κ(B) can be correctly estimated from historical orders. Therefore, we can still apply the result for the invertible process and conclude that the value of information sharing is zero.

22
Figure 1

The MSE percentage improvement against the decision deviation weight for an
1
β0= 1.2; β1=−0.2

ARIMA(0,1,1) demand with λ = 0.5 and a ConDI policy with order smoothing with γ = 0.8 and Γ = 2. β0= 0.2; β1= 0.8 β =−0.2; β = 1.2
0 1

0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 MSE−PI 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Decision Deviation Weight

To summarize the above theoretical findings, we characterize the value of information sharing with a numerical analysis. We apply the MSE percentage improvement metric introduced in Section 3. Let M SE-P I denote the MSE percentage improvement over no information sharing. Recall that ˆ ˆ ˆ M SE-P I = (Var(Ot+h − Ot,t+h |ΩO ) − Var(Ot+h − Ot,t+h |ΩO ∪ ΩD ))/Var(Ot+h − Ot,t+h |ΩO ), which t t t t takes value between 0 and 1. Figure 1 displays the MSE-PI of the 1-step-ahead forecast with respect to the relative weight
2 2 2 of the decision deviation under several sets of policy parameters. We define σδ /(σϵ + σδ ) as the

deviation decision weight. The retailer places weights βi on historical demands to determine their future forecast as in equation (9). Keeping the DOI level and the order smoothing level fixed, we choose three sets of policy weight βi (i = 0, 1) that correspond to three lines in Figure 1. We consider the retailer faces an ARIMA(0, 1, 1) demand, Dt = Dt−1 + ϵt − λϵt−1 , with the MA parameter λ = 0.5. The policy parameter ψ(B) is non-invertible for the top two processes while invertible for the bottom one. Our theoretical prediction aligns with the numerical observations. When the decision uncertainty is zero, the value of information sharing is positive for the first two and zero for the last policy parameters. This pattern is consistent with Proposition 1. Note that the studies in the literature correspond to the points on the vertical axis where the decision deviation weight is zero. As decision deviation become dominant, there is no gain from sharing the downstream sales information, which coincides with Proposition 4. When the decision deviation and demand uncertainty both exist, Figure 1 presents a strictly positive value of information sharing, which agrees with Proposition 3.

23
Figure 2

Summary of sales, orders and point-of-sale price for product PD OR.

6.
6.1.

Data, Estimation and Model Validation
Data

As we introduced in Section 3, our data set is provided by a leading supplier in the beverage and snack food industry and consists of three elements corresponding to a specific retail customer: (1) the retailer’s sales, (2) the retailer’s orders to the supplier and (3) the products’ retail price. The data spans over 126 weeks between 2009 and 2011. To be specific, the raw data consists of the retailer’s sales from its six distribution centers to local stores, and orders from the retailer’s six distribution centers to the supplier’s distribution center. For the purpose of our analysis, we work with the aggregated sales and orders. We calculate the retailer’s inventory using the fundamental law of material conservation, given sales and orders. Without information sharing, the supplier only observes the retailer’s order and the price plan. With information sharing, the supplier observes additional information: the retailer’s sales. We eliminate untrustworthy data, the new-entering products that have not reached the stationary state or obsolete products that are existing the market. After cleaning the data, we have 51 product lines in total: 19 orange juice products and 32 sports drink products. We summarize the sales, orders and price of a specific product over 126 weeks in Figure 2. It shows the bullwhip effect: the upstream order has larger volatility than the downstream sales. Further, when there is a price promotion, the demand experiences a spike during the discount activity and suffers a slump as price returns to normal. For the purpose of our study, we shall classify the products into low-promotional and highpromotional products and focus on the former6 . This classification is based on the price discount
6

The Online Companion provides a discussion on the promotional products.

24

and frequency of discount being offered on the product. From the data, we observe that the beverage products are frequently on sale. A promotional activity can last for several weeks. During a promotional activity, all retailer’s local stores execute the same price discount plan. Negotiating at the beginning of each year, the supplier has a fixed price plan throughout the year. Thus the future price can help predict demand changes for promotional products. The spikes in orders caused by promotions result in a non-constant demand mean and perhaps a time-variant covariance matrix, breaking the stationary assumption that we use to develop our theory. To make the above precise, we define promotional depth metric to capture price discount and frequency. Promotional depth sums every promotion activity’s price discount measured as a per∑ centage within the last 26 weeks in our data, i discount ratei where i ≤ the number of activities in 26 weeks. We define the low-promotional product as those with positive depth ≤ 0.15 (or equivalently no promotional activity or one promotional activity), and the high-promotional product as those with higher promotional depth. The low-promotional items contain 14 product lines and occupy 20% of the total ordering volume of all products. In the rest of this section, we will only discuss the methods and results for these 14 low-promotional items. 6.2. Estimation Procedure and Parameter Results

In Section 3, we presented the forecast accuracy of the policy structure method and concluded that the forecast improvement of adopting such method to incorporate the downstream demand is statistically significant. In this section, we first describe the estimation of the policy structure method. Next, we show the estimated demand and policy parameters. Note that our analysis only uses sales and orders data. We assume that the retailer adopts the ConDI policy with order smoothing. In each period, the ∑H order is Dt + γ(Γmt − It−1 ) + δt . Recall that mt = i=0 ai Dt−i . In practice, the retailer’s forecast usually accounts for last months’ demands. Thus, we let H = 3. We rewrite equation (16) as Ot = (1 + γΓβ0 )Dt + γΓβ1 Dt−1 + γΓβ2 Dt−2 + γΓβ3 Dt−3 − γΓIt−1 + δt . The estimating equation then becomes Ot = c0 Dt + c1 Dt−1 + c2 Dt−2 + c3 Dt−3 + cinv It−1 + δt (22)

We run a linear regression of equation (22) to estimate the policy parameters for each week in the test period. We apply the step-wise variable selection method to only include variables with p < 0.05 in the regression. The idiosyncratic shock in the order equation is the decision deviation. If δt is positive, the retailer orders more than what our policy predicts and vice versa. To forecast supplier’s order in t + 1, we first forecast future demands. We fit the ARIMA model ˆ to forecast Dt,t+1 . With the parameters estimated from equation (22), the order prediction for ˆ period t + 1 uses Dt,t+1 and Ds where s ≤ t and It : ˆ ˆ Ot,t+1 = c0 Dt,t+1 + c1 Dt + c2 Dt−1 + c3 Dt−2 + cinv It . (23)

25
Table 2

Estimated demand and policy parameters. The number in parenthesis denotes the standard error of the estimate.
Brand Product Orange 128 OR Juice 128 ORCA 12 OR 12 ORCA 59 ORST 59 ORPC Sports 500 BR Drink 500 GP PD LL PD OR PD FRZ 1GAL GLC 1GAL FRT 1GAL OR Demand parameters (p, d, q) λ1 λ2 λ3 (0, 1, 1) 0.93 (0.04) (0, 1, 1) 0.93 (0.04) (0, 1, 2) 0.48 0.33 (0.10) (0.10) (0, 1, 2) 0.28 0.25 (0.10) (0.10) (0, 1, 1) 0.72 (0.07) (0, 1, 1) 0.8 (0.07) (0, 1, 3) 0.12 0.16 0.49 (0.09) (0.09) (0.09) (0, 1, 0) (0, 1, 0) (0, 1, 1) 0.3 (0.10) (0, 1, 1) 0.32 (0.09) (0, 1, 2) 0.2 (0.09) (0, 1, 2) 0.37 (0.10) (0, 1, 2) 0.29 (0.10) Policy parameters c1 c2 c3 cinv 0.27 -0.63 (0.16) (0.12) 0.30 -0.53 (0.17) (0.12) 0.60 -0.87 (0.18) (0.12) 1.09 0.36 -0.86 (0.23) (0.19) (0.12) -0.39 (0.07) -0.46 -0.28 (0.22) (0.08) 1.17 0.55 -0.35 (0.29) (0.33) (0.07) 0.39 0.67 0.63 -0.36 (0.25) (0.38) (0.29) (0.07) 0.61 1.11 -0.24 (0.40) (0.44) (0.06) 1.37 0.39 -0.29 (0.16) (0.23) (0.07) 1.27 0.47 -0.32 (0.16) (0.22) (0.07) 0.76 1.17 -0.54 -0.22 (0.25) (0.28) (0.21) (0.08) 1.49 -0.25 (0.13) (0.07) 1.52 -0.30 (0.12) (0.07) c0 1.30 (0.18) 1.33 (0.18) 1.46 (0.17) 0.97 (0.21) 1.55 (0.10) 1.84 (0.18) DOI 6.36 8.48 8.56 11.54 9.76 9.58 14.50 13.43 21.06 18.35 16.22 12.38 13.38 12.33

0.43 (0.09) 0.36 (0.10) 0.34 (0.10)

We present the demand and policy parameters in Table 2. For all products, demand has d = 1, which implies that the first-order differenced demand is an ARMA process. The transportation lead time from the supplier to the retailer is one week, thus we consider the case that LR = 1. ∑H ∑H Therefore, i=0 ai = 1 and Γ = −c−1 ( i=0 ci − 1). The last column displays the DOI level. In inv practice, the retailer targets at a lower DOI level for the orange juice brand and a higher DOI for the sports drink brand. Our estimated DOI level is consistent with the actual target level claimed by the decision maker. 6.3. Model Validation

In this section, we validate whether the signal propagation agrees with our theory predictions. To this end, we compare the predicted and actual root mean squared forecast error, separately under the policy structure method and NoInfoSharing method. To be specific, we first derive the actual forecast. We follow the above estimation procedure to obtain the actual forecast under information sharing. We fit the ARIMA model and forecast order using only order information without information sharing. Second, based on the theory we explained in section 5, we calculate the root mean square error, which we refer to as the predicted value. We next elaborate on the procedure used to obtain the predicted value. We calculate the insample mean squared error from demand when fitting the ARIMA model in Table 2, and we use

26
Figure 3

Actual vs predicted root mean squared forecast error with information sharing (left) and without information sharing (right).

2 it as σϵ . We calculate the in-sample mean squared error from estimating policy in equation (22), 2 and we use it as σδ . Together with the estimated demand and policy parameters, we know all the

parameters in the model7 . We empirically test the correlation between contemporaneous shocks δt and ϵt . The result suggests weak correlation or no correlation. Therefore, when there is information
2 2 sharing, the mean squared forecast error is c2 σϵ +σδ . In absence of information sharing, we calculate 0

the mean squared error by applying the Innovation Algorithm used in the time series literature (see Online Technical Companion). We present the results in Figure 3. We plot the fitted against actual root mean squared prediction error under both information sharing (left) and no information sharing (right) case. A perfect model fit would lead to the points lying on the 45-degree dashed line in the figure. The fitted points from our model are overall close to the 45-degree line for both with information and no information, indicating a good fit. We fit a regression of the theoretical prediction on the actual observation. The 95% confidence interval is [1.01, 1.27] under the information sharing setting and [0.86, 1.14] under the no information sharing setting. The good fit indicates that our theoretical model with decision deviations can well explain how demands prorogate upstream, and thus well predict the value of information sharing. In Section 5, we proved that the presence of decision deviations guarantees strictly positive value under any forecast lead time. In the following section, we will investigate how the value of sharing changes with respect to the demand, policy and lead time on the value of information sharing.
7

In the policy parameter sector of Table 2, for some products, the coefficient of current week’s demand is zero, which means the retailer’s replenishment fulfillment places zero weight on current week’s demand. This is unlikely to occur in practice. Our estimation shows zero coefficient because the retailer may replenish inventory during the week, but our data set consists of system’s snapshots at the end of the each week. If the retailer replenishes certain products always on Monday, the current week’s order should be a linear combination of past weeks’ demand, not including the current week (since current week’s demand has not been realized yet). Therefore, for products with zero c0 in Table 2, we interpret a1 as the actual coefficient of current week (shift a2 and a3 in the same way).

27

7.

Properties of the Value of Information Sharing

While we have shown that the value is positive, we have not specified its magnitude and how it changes relative to other key variables. In this section, we investigate the impact of demand on the value of information sharing. We study how the value changes with respect to the parameter of an ARIMA(0, 1, 1) demand process. (We focus on this particular form of ARIMA demand process as 8 out of 14 products in the data have this structure). We then show that the theoretically obtained relation is consistent with our empirical observations. We focus on the 1-step-ahead forecast. We theoretically analyze two special cases to understand the intuition and resort to numerical studies for more involved settings. We analyze a simple yet reasonable model to derive the theoretical prediction. The empirical estimation suggests that 8 out of 14 products follow an ARIMA(0, 1, 1) demand. Therefore, in this section, we assume that the demand follows an ARIMA(0, 1, 1) process with parameter λ ∈ [0, 1), Dt = Dt−1 + ϵt − λϵt−1 , which can be equivalently written as Dt = (1 − λ) ∑∞ i=1 λ i−1

Dt−i + ϵt . The current observation

is a weighted average of historical observations with exponentially decaying coefficients. Values of λ closer to one put greater weight on recent data and thus react more intensely to recent variations, while processes with λ closer to zero smooth the weight on past observations and thus are less responsive to recent changes. Therefore, the process trends more slowly with a smaller λ. For example, the products that we study can be classified according to λ. Orange juice is an everyday drink for consumers since it is usually served with breakfast. A sports drink is designed for rehydration and energy-providing, which is mainly consumed for exercising. Thus its consumption is influenced by weather, temperature and sport events. The data exhibits a clearer slowly trending pattern in demand for sports drinks. Consistent with the above analysis, orange juice products has larger λ while sports drink have smaller λ according to our demand parameter estimations. We refer to demands with small λ as slowly trending demands. Recall that the retailer’s future demand forecast is a linear combination of historical H + 1 periods demands. In the rest of this section, we assume the retailer’s order relies on current and last week’s demand, H = 1. The order-up-to level of the ConDI policy becomes Γmt = Γβ0 Dt + Γβ1 Dt−1 (β0 + β1 = 1 due to β0 + β1 = LR = 1). We will refer to the two parameters β0 and β1 as policy weights. The order can be written as a summation of two processes in equation (21) ∞ ∑ Xt1 = (1 + γΓβ0 + γΓβ1 B)(1 + λB)ϵt − γ 2 (1 − γ)i−1 (Γβ0 + Γβ1 B)(1 + λB)ϵt−i , i=1 Xt2 = δt − δt−1 −

∞ ∑ i=1

γ(1 − γ)i−1 (δt−i − δt−i−1 ),

28
Figure 4

The MSE percentage improvement with respect to an ARIMA(0,1,1) demand with λ and a ConDI policy with order smoothing with β0 , γ and Γ = 2. β0=1.5 1 β0=0.5 β0=−0.2

0.8

MSE−PI

0.6

0.4 λ=0 λ=0.5 λ=0.9 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1 0 0.5 1

0.2

0

Decision deviation weight

where ϵt is the demand shock and δt is the decision deviation. We assume ϵt is independent with δs for any s. For the purpose of our theoretical analysis, we focus on processes Xt1 and Xt2 with degree smaller or equal to 3. When the degree of either process exceeds 3, the complexity of the problem precludes analytically tractable solutions and necessitates numerical analysis. Therefore, we first focus on two simple policies: (1) the retailer follows a demand replacement policy (γ = 0) and (2) the retailer adopt a ConDI policy (γ = 1) with zero weight on previous week’s demand (a1 = 0). Under (1), the order process is Ot = Dt + δt and under (2), the order process becomes Ot = (1 + Γβ0 )Dt − Γβ0 Dt−1 + δt − δt−1 . The following proposition demonstrates that under the demand replacement policy, the value strictly decreases with λ. Proposition 5 The value of information sharing under the 1-step-ahead forecast strictly decreases with λ if (1) the retailer follows a demand replacement policy, or (2) the retailer follows a ConDI policy with β1 = 0. To further explore the demand’s impact under other parameters, we conduct numerical studies. Figure 4 presents the relation of MSE-PI with respect to λ under three policy weight parameters. The DOI level is set to 2 and the order smoothing level is set to 0.5. In each sub-figure, the three lines from top to bottom correspond to λ = 0, 0.5 and 0.9. The three columns from left to right correspond to β0 = 1.5, 0.5 and −0.2. Consistent with the theoretical prediction, the value of information sharing with demand parameters closer to zero dominates those with larger λ. This indicates that the products with slowly trending demands have strictly larger forecast accuracy improvement, regardless of the decision deviation weight, policy and demand parameter. Let us revisit the empirically obtained MSE-PI results in the last column of Table 1 in Section 3. The two orange drinks 12 OR and 12 ORCA

29

have much smaller bottle volume compared to other orange juice products. In Table 2 in Section 6, their λ is closer to zero which differs substantially from the other orange drinks. Thus, their demand structure is closer to the sports drink products. Consistent with our theoretical prediction, the percentage improvement of the sports drink and the above two products are in general larger than the rest of orange juice. In short, our theory can provide correct mapping from the demand pattern to the potential gain from information sharing. The result implies that it’s more worthwhile for managers to invest in the information sharing system for products with slow trending consumption under the one-step-ahead forecast lead time. It’s worth noting that forecasting beyond one period might reverse the relation of the value of information sharing and demand parameter λ. We recommend that the managers run a numerical study to validate the potential gain based on demand and policy characteristics.

8.

Conclusion and Discussions

This paper empirically evaluates the supplier’s forecast improvement by incorporating downstream retail sales data and supports the observations with an extended theoretical model. Table 1 in Section 3 summarizes our main empirical findings. Overall, the forecast accuracy improvement can be statistically significant, even when including demand data in a naive way. We further show that a more refined inclusion of demand (by modeling the underlying policy structure along with the demand) yields the highest forecast accuracy and its forecast improvement over the NoInfoSharing method is statistically significant across all products. Our observations highlight the positive value to suppliers from incorporating retailers’ sales data: 7.1% to 81.1% MSE percentage improvement across 14 products and 40% MAPE percentage improvement on an overall level, which is regarded as a significant improvement by the CPG company we studied. We also revisit and extend the theoretical model in the existing literature. Until now, the theoretical literature showed no value of information sharing for 10 out of 14 products. We recognize that the key assumption in the theoretical model is that the decision maker strictly and consistently follows the specified replenishment policy, which in practice is rarely the case. A decision maker may implement adjustments according to private information that we do not observe. Following the same spirit as the “error term” defined by Rust (1997), we introduce “decision deviations” that stem from a state variable observable to the agent but not to us. Our extended theory yields qualitatively different results than the previous literature. We demonstrate that if both demand shock and decision shock are nonzero, the value of information sharing is strictly positive for any forecast lead time. We identify that the distinct evolution patterns of demand process and decision deviation process drive such conclusion. As both processes propagate together in different manners, the detailed information is lost and is replaced with an order signal with larger variance.

30

Our extended theory reconciles our empirical observations. Our paper therefore underscores the importance of extending the theoretical model by recognizing that the decision maker may deviate from the exact policy, a phenomenon that is common in practice and is absent in earlier theoretical models. We not only show that the value is positive, but also investigate the impact of demand characteristics on the magnitude of the value of information sharing. We suggest that managers invest in information sharing systems for products with slow trending consumption. This shows another contribution of our framework: we provide guidelines for evaluating the potential gain of information sharing. Our study focuses on a specific linear and stationary inventory policy with a stationary demand process. The conclusion regarding the strictly positive value of information sharing can be generalized to both broader linear and stationary inventory policies and nonstationary demand processes. For any linear and stationary inventory policy and stationary demand, the evolution patterns of the demand process and decision deviation process are different because of the distinct way that they accumulate in the order decision. This implies that if a retailer follows the generalized order-up-to policy under the MMFE demand (studied in Chen and Lee 2009), the value of sharing the retailer’s demand forecast revision is always positive for any forecast lead time. It’s worth noting that the information shared by the retailer is no longer sales history but sales forecast revision history (based on the MMFE structure). In this paper, we restrict our attention to low-promotional products, the demand of which follows the stationary process. The demand of high-promotional products, however, can become nonstationary due to the spikes and slumps caused by the promotions. The nonstationary demand indicates that the order structure (in demand signals and decision deviation signals) changes over time. Therefore, the optimal estimator for the order structure obtained in the current period might be suboptimal for the next period, if the supplier has access to only the order (and price schedule) information. The suboptimal estimator together with the distinct evolution pattern reinforce our conclusion: the value of information is strictly positive. Our model demonstrates that the decision deviation from a linear policy can allow the supplier to reap higher benefit from incorporating downstream sales data. We believe that our model can well represent many industries in practice, but our analysis has limitations and future work is needed to test the robustness of our results. In particular, future theoretical research should explore nonlinear policies such as the (s, S) policy and forecasting multiple products with correlated demands. The former breaks the affine structure and thus requires a re-examination via a non-linear time series model or a proper approximation.

References
Aviv, Yossi. 2001a. The effect of collaborative forecasting on supply chain performance. Management Sci. 47(10) 1326–1343.

31 Aviv, Yossi. 2001b. On the benefits of collaborative forecasting partnerships between retailers and manufacturers. Management Sci. 53(5) 777–794. Aviv, Yossi. 2003. A time-series framework for supply chain inventory management. Oper. Res. 51(2) 210–227. Balakrishnan, Anantaram, Joseph Geunes, Michael S. Pangburn. 2004. Coordinating supply chains by controlling upstream variability propagation. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 6(2) 163–183. Bray, Robert L., Haim Mendelson. 2012a. Deriving supply chain metrics from financial statements. working paper . Bray, Robert L., Haim Mendelson. 2012b. Information transmission and the bullwhip effect: An empirical investigation. Management Sci. 58(5) 860–875. Brockwell, Peter J., Richard A. Davis. 2002. Introduction to Time Series and Forecasting. Springer. Cachon, Gerard P., Marshall Fisher. 2000. Supply chain inventory management and the value of shared information. Management Sci. 46(8) 1032–1048. Cachon, Gerard P., Taylor Randall, Glen M. Schmidt. 2007. In search of the bullwhip effect. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 9(4) 457–479. Caplin, Andrew S. 1985. The variability of aggregate demand with (s, s) inventory policies. Econometrica 53(6) 1395–1409. Chen, Li, Hau L. Lee. 2009. Information sharing and order variability control under a generalized demand model. Management Sci. 55(5) 781–797. Cohen, Morris A., Teck H. Ho, Z. Justin Ren, Christian Terwiesch. 2003. Measuring imputed cost in the semiconductor equipment supply chain. Management Sci. 49(12) 1653–1670. Costco collaboration. 2006. Iri costco collaborative retail exchange. http://www.symphonyiri.com (as of 8/23/2012). Dong, Yan, Martin Dresner, Oliver Yao. 2011. An empirical analysis of the value of managing information asymmetry in vendor managed inventory Working paper. Donselaar, Karel H. Van, Vishal Gaur, Tom Van Woensel, Rob A. C. M. Broekmeulen, Jan C. Fransoo. 2010. Ordering behavior in retail stores and implications for automated replenishment. Management Sci. 56(5) 766–784. Gaur, Vishal, Avi Giloni, Sridhar Seshadri. 2005. Information sharing in a supply chain under arma demand. Management Sci. 51(6) 961–969. Gaur, Vishal, Nikolay Osadchiy, Sridhar Seshadri. 2009. Sales forecasting with financial indicators and experts’ input. Working Paper, Cornell University. Gilbert, Kenneth. 2005. An arima supply chain model. Management Sci. 51(2) 305–310.

32 Giloni, Avi, Clifford Hurvich, Sridhar Seshadri. 2012. Forecasting and information sharing in supply chains under arma demand. working paper . Graves, Stephen C. 1999. A single-item inventory model for a nonstationary demand process. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 1(1) 50–61. Graves, Stephen C., David B. Kletter, William B. Hetzel. 1998. A dynamic model for requirements planning with application to supply chain optimization. Oper. Res. 46(3) S35–S49. Hamilton, James D. 1994. Time Series Analysis. Princeton University Press. Heath, David C., Peter L. Jackson. 1994. Modelling the evolution of demand forecasts with application to safety stock analysis in production/distribution systems. IIE Trans 26(3) 17–30. Irvine, F. Owen. 1981. Retail inventory investment and the cost of capital. The American Economic Review 71(4) 633–648. Kesavan, Saravanan, Vishal Gaur, Ananth Raman. 2009. Incorporating price and inventory endogeneity in firm level sales forecasting. Working Paper. Kovtun, Vladimir, Avi Giloni, Clifford M. Hurvich. 2012. Assessing the value of demand sharing in supply chains Working paper. Ledesma, Gabi. 2004. Waste not, want not. http://mhlnews.com/global-supply-chain/waste-not-want-not (as of 2/4/2013). Lee, Hau L., Kut C. So, Christopher S. Tang. 2000. The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Management Sci. 46(5) 626–643. Miyaoka, Julia, Warren Hausman. 2004. How a base stock policy using “stale” forecasts provides supply chain benefits. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 6(2) 149–162. Plosser, Charles I., G. William Schwert. 1997. Estimation of a non-invertible moving average process: The case of overdifferencing. Journal of Econometrics (6) 199–244. Raghunathan, Srinivasan. 2001. Information sharing in a supply chain: A note on its value when demand is nonstationary. Management Sci. 47(4) 605–610. Route, Robert. 2003. Impact of pos data sharing on order forecasts with stationary demand series. Unpublished manuscript. Rust, John. 1997. Structural estimation of markov decision processes. Handbook of econometrics 4 3081– 3143. Edited by Robert F. Engle and Daniel L. McFadden. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Terwiesch, Christian, Z. Justin Ren, Teck H. Ho, Morris A. Cohen. 2005. An empirical analysis of forecast sharing in the semiconductor equipment supply chain. Management Sci. 51(2) 208–220. Wold, Herman. 1938. A study in the analysis of stationary time series. Uppsala: Almqvist and Wiksell. Zhang, Xiaolong. 2004. Technical note: Evolution of arma demands in supply chains. Manufacturing Service Oper. Management 6(2) 195–198.

33

9.

Appendix
Proof of Theorem 2: With information sharing. The process i is Xti = χi (B)ϵi with t i coefficient χi (B) = 1 + λi B + λi B 2 + · · · + λi i B qi . Recall that ΩX = sp{ϵi , ..., ϵi } is the plane 1 t 1 2 q t containing the historical shocks ϵi , ..., ϵi . According to the definition, ϵi ⊥ ΩXi . Since we assume t 1 t t+1 ϵi ⊥ ϵj for any k > 0, the general orthogonal condition is t t−k ϵi ⊥ Ωt j , ∀i, j. t+1
X

(24)

The future forecast of a process depends only on its realized historical shocks. Therefore, with full information, it is optimal to generate predictors for each process and aggregate the optimal individual forecast as the total prediction. ˆi The h-step-ahead forecast of process Xti made in period t isXt,t+h = λi ϵt + λi ϵi + · · · + h h+1 t−1
X ˆ λi i ϵi q t+h−qi . The h-step-ahead mean squared forecast error is Var(St+h − St,t+h | ∪i Ωt ) = Var(St+h − ∑N ˆ i i=1 Xt,t+h ). i Without information sharing. In absence of demand information, the order process is an MA model. We consider the invertible MA representation and define it as St = χS (B)ηt , where {ηt } is the white noise series, the MA coefficient is χS (B) = 1 + θ1 B + θ2 B 2 + · · · + θqS B qS . Recall that ΩS = sp{η1 , ..., ηt } is the plane containing the order process signals η1 , ..., ηt . Since χS (B)ηt = t ∑N ∑N −1 i i i i=1 χi (B)ϵt , then ηt = χS (B) i=1 χi (B)ϵt . Since ηt is a linear combination of ϵs , s ≤ t, then ΩS ∈ ∪i ΩX . t t According to the orthogonal condition in equation (24), we have ϵj ⊥ ∪i ΩX for any j. Since t+1 t ΩS ∈ ∪i ΩX , then t t ϵi ⊥ ΩS , ∀i. t+1 t (25) i i i

ˆ The h-step-ahead forecast of process St made in period t isSt,t+h = θh ηt + θh+1 ηt−1 + · · · + θqS ηt+h−qS . We abbreviate the h-step-ahead mean squared error under no information sharing ˆ ˆ Var(St+h − St,t+h |ΩS ) as Var(St+h − St,t+1 ) in the rest of the proof. t The Value of Information Sharing. Next we prove that if χi (B) ̸= χj (B) for any i, j, then ∑N ˆ i ˆ ˆ i=1 Xt,t+h ̸= St,t+h for any finite forecast lead time h ≤ maxi {qi }. We rewrite Var(St+1 − St,t+1 ) as ∑N ˆ i ∑N ˆ i ˆ Var(St+1 − i=1 Xt,t+1 + i=1 Xt,t+1 − St,t+1 ). According to the orthogonal condition in equation ˆ (24) and (25), Var(St+1 − St,t+1 ) can be simplified to ˆ Var(St+h − St,t+h ) = Var(St+h −
N ∑ i=1 N ∑ ˆi ˆ ˆi Xt,t+h − St,t+h ). Xt,t+h ) + Var( i=1

(26)

∑N ˆ i ∑N ˆ i ˆ ˆ Var(St,t+h − St,t+h ) > Var(St+h − i=1 Xt,t+h ) if and only if i=1 Xt,t+1 ̸= St,t+h . ˆi If qS < maxi {qi }, then for the forecast lead time h that satisfies qS < h ≤ maxi {qi }, Xt,t+h ̸= 0 ∑N ˆ i ˆ ˆ for qi ≥ h and St,t+h = 0. Therefore, i=1 Xt,t+h ̸= St,t+h . Suppose that there exists a finite forecast

34

lead time h ≤ qS ≤ maxi {qi } (the latter inequality is from the MA process aggregation) such that ∑N ˆ i ∑N ˆ i ˆ ˆ Xt,t+h = St,t+h . This is equivalent to Xt−h,t = St−h,t , which can be expanded as i=1 i=1

θh ηt−h + θh+1 ηt−h−1 + · · · + θqS ηt−qS =

N ∑ i=1

i i λi ϵt−h + λi ϵi h h+1 t−h−1 + · · · + λqi ϵt−qi .

(27)

For notational convenience, let λi = 0 for j > qi . Since ηt + θ1 ηt−1 + θ2 ηt−2 + · · · + θqS ηt−qS = j ∑N i i i i i i=1 (ϵt + λ1 ϵt−1 + · · · + λqi ϵt−qi ), we subtract equation (27) from it, ηt + θ1 ηt−1 + · · · + θh−1 ηt−h+1 = We replace ηt−j with χ−1 (B) S ∑N i i=1 χi (B)ϵt−j N ∑ i=1

ϵi + λi ϵi + · · · + λi ϵi t 1 t−1 h−1 t−h+1 .

(28)

for all j, equation (28) becomes h−1 ∑ j=0

ηt + θ1 ηt−1 + · · · + θh−1 ηt−h+1 =

θj χ−1 (B) S

N ∑ i=1

χi (B)ϵi . t−j

(29)

inv We denote the degree of χ−1 (B) as qS . Since qS ≥ 0 and χS (B) is the invertible representation S inv inv (which guarantees nonnegative qS ), then qS ≥ 0. Therefore, according to the above equation, inv χS (B)ηt is the summation of N processes with degree qi + qS + min{h − 1, qS } relative to shock

ϵi . Then from equation (28), the degree with respect to ϵi is min{h − 1, qi }. When there exist two t t processes with different coefficients, then we can find a pair of processes with different coefficients, one of which has the largest degree maxi {qi } and we denote the process as Xtk . Since h < maxi {qi }, Xtk has a degree of h − 1 with respect to ϵk according to equation (28). Since h ≤ qS , Xtk has a t inv inv degree of qi + qS + h − 1 with respect to ϵk in equation (28) is. Since qk + qS + h − 1 > h − 1, we t

have reached a contradiction. As a result, for any finite forecast lead time h ≤ maxi {qi }, we have ∑N ˆ i ∑N ˆ i ˆ ˆ i=1 Xt,t+h ) i=1 Xt,t+h ̸= St,t+h and according to equation (26), Var(St,t+h − St,t+h ) > Var(St+h − for all h ≤ qS . The contrapositive of the above statement is that if there exists a forecast lead time h ≤ qS such ∑N ˆ i ˆ that Var(St,t+h − St,t+h ) = Var(St+h − i=1 Xt,t+h ), then χi (B) = χj (B) for any i, j. If χi (B) = χj (B) for any i, j, then it is obvious that the aggregated process has the same parameters and ∑N i ˆ ˆ ηt = i=1 ϵi . Therefore, Var(St+h − St,t+h | ∪i ΩX ) = Var(St+h − St,t+h |ΩS ) for any forecast lead t t t time h including h = 1. Proof of Proposition 5: The retailer follows the demand replacement policy. Recall that the centered order is the summation of two MA processes Ot − Ot−1 = ϵt − λϵt−1 + δt − δt−1 . We denote the aggregate MA process (or the order process) as St = ηt + θηt−1 , where Var(ηt ) = v. It satisfies the covariance equations
2 2 −λσϵ − σδ = vθ, 2 2 (1 + λ2 )σϵ + 2σδ = v(1 + θ2 ).

(30)

35

We use equation (30) to solve for θ and v given parameters σϵ , σϵ and λ. We substitute θ with v in equation (30) to obtain a function f (v, λ) with variable v and parameter λ such that the solutions
2 2 of f (v, λ) = 0 is the variance of ηt . The function f (v, λ) satisfies f (v, λ) = v 2 − ((1 + λ2 )σϵ + 2σδ )v + 2 2 (−λσϵ − σδ )2 .

The aggregate process St has an invertible representation and a noninvertible representation. Each representation corresponds to a solution of (30). Therefore, fixing λ, f (v, λ) = 0 has two solutions: the variance of the invertible process and the noninvertible process. We denote the former
2 2 as v ∗ . The value of information sharing is 1 − (σϵ + σδ )/v ∗ . We will prove the invertible white noise

variance of the aggregated process is decreasing in λ.
2 2 We first take derivatives of f (v, λ) with respect to v, ∂f (v, λ)/∂v = 2v − ((1 + λ2 )σϵ + 2σδ ). 2 2 Since the invertible solution θ of (30) is smaller than 1, 2v ∗ = 2((1 + λ2 )σϵ + 2σδ )/(1 + θ2 ) > 2 2 (1 + λ2 )σϵ + 2σδ . As a result, ∂f (v, λ)/∂v > 0 at v ∗ . Since f (v, λ) is continuous, ∂f (v, λ)/∂v > 0 in

an open interval of v ∗ (λ). v ∗ is decreasing in λ. Therefore, it suffices to show that ∂f (v, λ)/∂λ > 0. We have ∂f (v, λ) 2 2 2 2 = 2σϵ (−λv + λσϵ + σδ ) = −2σϵ v(θ + λ). ∂λ (31)

2 The covariance generating functions of the two MA processes are gϵ = σϵ (1 − λz)(1 − λz −1 ) and 2 gδ = σδ (1 − z)(1 − z −1 ), where z = cos(ω) − i sin(ω) = e−iω . The covariance generating function for

the aggregated process is gη = v(1 + θz)(1 + θz −1 ), where gη = gϵ + gδ ,
2 2 σϵ (1 − λz)(1 − λz −1 ) + σδ (1 − z)(1 − z −1 ) = v(1 + θz)(1 + θz −1 ).

(32)

2 2 2 Let z = 1, equation(32) then becomes σϵ (1 − λ)2 = v(1 + θ)2 . Since v ∗ > σϵ + σδ , then (1 + θ)2 <

(1 − λ)2 . Since 1 + θ and 1 − λ are both positive, θ + λ < 0. Therefore, the right hand side of equation (31) is positive and v ∗ is decreasing in λ. The retailer follows the ConDI policy. The order under the ConDI policy is (1 + Γβ0 )ϵt − (λ + λΓβ0 + Γβ0 )ϵt−1 + λΓβ0 ϵt−2 + δt − 2δt−1 + δt−2 . Let α = Γβ0 /(1 + Γβ0 ). We denote the aggregate process as St = ηt + θ1 ηt−1 + θ2 ηt−2 , with the covariance equations
2 2 σδ + αλσϵ = θ2 v, 2 2 −4σδ − (λ + a)(1 + αλ)σϵ = θ1 (1 + θ2 )v, 2 2 2 2 6σδ + (1 + (λ + a)2 + α2 λ2 )σϵ = (1 + θ1 + θ2 )v.

(33)

Following the same spirit as above, we substitute θ1 and θ2 with v in equation (33) to obtain a function f (v, λ) with variable v and parameter λ. The function f (v, λ) satisfiesf (v, λ) = v 2 (v +
2 2 2 γ(2))2 + v 2 γ(1)2 + (v + γ(2))2 (γ(2)2 − γ(0)v), where γ(2) ≡ σδ + αλσϵ , γ(1) ≡ −4σδ − (λ + a)(1 + 2 2 2 αλ)σϵ , γ(0) ≡ 6σδ + (1 + (λ + a)2 + α2 λ2 )σϵ .

36

As before, we denote v ∗ as the invertible white noise variance of the aggregated process. We need to prove that v ∗ is decreasing in λ. Following the same argument from before, it is equivalent to prove ∂f (v, λ)/∂λ > 0. We take derivatives of f (v, λ) with respect to λ ∂f (v, λ) = 2(v + γ(2))γ ′ (2)[v 2 + (γ(2) − γ(0))v + 2γ(2)2 ] + 2v 2 γ ′ (1)γ(1) − (v + γ(2))2 vγ ′ (0) (34) ∂λ 2 2 2 = −2v 3 σϵ (1 + θ2 )[θ1 (1 + 2αλ + α2 ) + (1 + θ2 )(λ + α + λα2 ) − α(θ2 + θ2 − θ1 )]
2 = −2v 3 σϵ (1 + θ2 )[(α + λ − αλ + θ1 + θ2 )(αθ1 + 1 + θ2 ) − (−αλ + θ2 )(1 + α)(θ1 + θ2 + 1)]

For the process ηt + θ1 ηt−1 + θ2 ηt−2 , the invertible solutions of 1 + θ1 m + θ2 m2 lie outside the unit circle. Since 1 + θ1 m + θ2 m2 = 1 at m = 0, then the function takes positive value at m = 1, θ1 + θ2 + 1 > 0. Using the same argument, the function 1 − (λ + α)m + αλm2 takes positive value at m = 1, 1 − λ − α + αλ > 0.
2 2 The covariance generating functions satisfy σϵ (1 − λz)(1 − αz)(1 − λz −1 )(1 − αz −1 ) + σδ (1 − 2 z)2 (1 − z −1 )2 = v(1 + θ1 z + θ2 z 2 )(1 + θ1 z −1 + θ2 z −2 ). Let z = 1, we have σϵ (1 − λ − α + αλ)2 = 2 2 v(1 + θ1 + θ2 )2 . Since v > σϵ + σδ , (1 + θ1 + θ2 )2 < (1 − λ − α + αλ)2 and 1 + θ1 + θ2 < 1 − λ − α + αλ.

Therefore, α + λ − αλ + θ1 + θ2 < 0. Since γ(2) > 0 and γ(1) < 0, θ2 is positive and θ1 is negative. Since θ1 + θ2 + 1 > 0 and θ1 < 0, αθ1 + 1 + θ2 > θ1 + θ2 + 1 > 0. Therefore, (α + λ − αλ + θ1 + θ2 )(αθ1 + 1 + θ2 ) < 0. We next prove −αλ + θ2 > 0. If σδ /σϵ = 0, then θ2 = αλ. If σδ /σϵ → ∞, then θ2 = 1. As σδ /σϵ increases from 0 to ∞, θ2 changes continuously from αλ to 1. If there exists a θ2 < αλ, there must
2 2 2 be a θ2 = αλ when σδ /σϵ ̸= 0. Then according to equation(33), v = σδ /αλ + σϵ and θ1 = αλ(−4σδ − 2 2 2 2 (λ + α)(1 + αλ)σϵ )/(1 + αλ)(αλσϵ + σδ ). Plugging v and θ1 , θ2 into equation σϵ (1 − λ − α + αλ)2 =

v(1 + θ1 + θ2 )2 , we have
2 2 4 ((1 + αλ)(1 − λ)(1 − α) − 2(1 − αλ)2 )αλ(1 − λ − α + αλ)(1 + αλ)σϵ σδ − (1 − αλ)4 σδ =0 2 2 αλ(1 + αλ)2 (αλσϵ + σδ )

Since 2 > 1 + αλ, 1 − αλ > 1 − λ and 1 − αλ > 1 − α, then (1+ αλ)(1 − λ)(1 − α) < 0. Since 1 − αλ > 0,
4 1 + λ − a − aλ > 0, λ < 0 and −(1 − αλ)4 σδ < 0, the numerator is negative. Since the denominator

is positive, the equation is violated. Therefore −αλ + θ2 > 0. The right hand side of equation(34) is positive at v ∗ . Applying the same argument as before, v ∗ is decreasing in λ.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Nike Dilemmas

...Nike Dilemma: Still waiting for them to "do it"! Another corporate giant having its fare share of controversies over the years is Nike. Nike employs approximately 26,000 people worldwide. In addition, approximately 650,000 workers are employed in Nike contracted factories around the globe. More than 75% of these work in Asia, predominantly in China, Thailand, Indonesia, Vietnam, Korea and Malaysia (Nike 2006). In 1998 Nike came under fire for the sweatshop conditions of the workers in the Nike factories in China and other third world countries. The evidence showed that the workers were regularly subject to physical punishment and sexual abuse and exposed to dangerous chemicals. (Nike Accused of Lying About Asian Factories 1998). Sub standard working facilities, bare minimum wages and risks to health of labourers mark NIKE factories in Asia. The firm was also accused of practicing child labour in Pakistan. So the question now is, why did it happen, and more importantly, has anything been done since to correct it. So why did it happen? Well that is quite clear. The reason why most firms outsource their activities to lesser developed countries is to exploit cheaper labour and production costs. Nike has a brand reputation worldwide, and in-fact is a market leader in the sales of athletic shoes. The constant focus is to formulate ways and strategies to reduce production costs, and one way of that is fewer wages to the workers. The high unemployment levels in the third world countries...

Words: 1725 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Nike: the Sweatshop Debate

...Nike Corporation is one of the largest marketers of athletic apparel and sportswear equipment in the world and was founded in Beaverton, Oregon, in 1964 by Phil Knight and Bill Bowerman. According to Nike.com (2009) it had record earnings of 19.2 billion dollars and continues to grow at a steady pace. Nike sold its products in a 140 countries and successfully discovered that manufacturing its products was not the only method to successfully produce the results it was looking for but instead marketing and designing its products and contracting the manufacturing out to global factories 600 throughout the country. With the company’s success come painful lessons learned along the way. This paper will describe the legal, cultural, and ethical challenges that Nike Corporation faced as a result of its global business ventures. In addition, it will touch on the roles the host governments played in manufacturing Nike’s products and will summarize the strategic and operational challenges that Nike Managers face in dealing with the interworking of global business. Nike as well as other global companies in the industry has the option to manufacture their products domestically or internationally in either situation there are challenges. If a company chose to the domestic approach it could potentially be more expensive, however, the organization and its manufacturing facility contractors would have to adhere to U.S. labor and safety laws in the areas of wages, code of conduct, working...

Words: 762 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

The Industrial Revolution - Labor Conditions

...The Industrial Revolution – the Factory Worker vs. the Plantation Worker: A Discussion of the Labor Conditions The Industrial Revolution was a period of great change in Europe and North America – a period where progress in agriculture, technology, transportation and more allowed the development of human civilization from the previous primarily agricultural based societies. This time period between the 18th to 19th century saw many developments such as canals, roads, steam power, combustion engine, as well as significant strides in manufacturing and factory work. Immense changes occurred in society: affecting daily life and causing significant societal impacts. The objective of this paper is to discuss the significant social effects that the Industrial Revolution (and industrialization, in general) – focusing on the working conditions and dynamic of plantations and factories. In this time period, it is evident that the employer, business owner, and middle class factory owner would benefit from the lower class, general laborer who would be unfairly compensated and be subject to poor conditions, creating a significant gap between the upper/middle and lower classes. The period of the Industrial Revolution was not only a driving force in technology, but economics and society. Industrialization brought a new form of wealth and riches to the people who were able to capitalize on it; this largely being the middle class, and to a smaller extent, the upper class. New opportunities...

Words: 1401 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Cruel Labor

...Shaping of the Modern World 5/8/11 Cruel Labor The Industrial Revolution wasn’t the first instance of cruel human labor in the history of the world, but some may argue that it was the harshest. Flora Tristan says in her piece from the London Journal, “Since I have known the English proletariat I no longer think that slavery is the greatest human misfortune.” (1) Cruel labor is an injustice that originated in ancient civilizations, became worse in the eighteenth century, and unfortunately still exists today. No matter what event you choose to focus on, between the Atlantic Slave Trade, to the London Laboring Classes and its child labor, to the more recent sweatshops that still exist in Asia, the pain and suffering these people had to go through and are still going through is not only inhumane, but also immoral. “The London Laboring Classes” is an excerpt from the London Journal by Flora Tristan. The article is broken down into two parts: Factory Workers and Prostitutes. Tristan wrote this article in order to expose the cruelties suffered by industrial workers, women, and slaves, during the Industrial Revolution. It would be an injustice to Tristan if I paraphrase her shocking description of the life of the factory worker, so I’ll quote her directly. “Most of the workers lack clothing, a bed, furniture, a fire, wholesome food, and often even potatoes! They are shut up twelve to fourteen hours a day in mean rooms where they breathe in, along with foul air, cotton, wool...

Words: 1605 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Essays

...During the 1800s the Industrial Revolution spread throughout Britain. The use of steam-powered machines, led to a massive increase in the number of factories (particularly in textile factories or mills). Many factory workers were children. They worked long hours and were often treated badly by the supervisors or overseers. Sometimes the children started work as young as four or five years old. A young child could not earn much, but even a few pence would be enough to buy food. lasted from the 18th century to the 19th century As the number of factories grew people from the countryside began to move into the towns looking for better paid work. The wages of a farm worker were very low and there were less jobs working on farms because of the invention and use of new machines such as threshers. Also thousands of new workers were needed to work machines in mills and foundries and the factory owners built houses for them.Cities filled to overflowing and London was particularly bad. At the start of the 19th Century about 1/5 of Britain’s population lived there, but by 1851 half the population of the country had set up home in London. London, like most cities, was not prepared for this great increase in people. People crowded into already crowded houses. Rooms were rented to whole families or perhaps several families. The Industrial Revolution affected many people, some of these people were affect in a positive way and some in a negative way. The new industry needed a lot of working...

Words: 495 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

M&S and Primark Csr

...Arianne Dyball MAIN Geography Miss Green Issue I Will be looking into Exploitation of workers. Wages and Hours? Child Labour? How are employees treated? Safety and exposure to toxins and lack of trade unions and equal rights for disabled e.t.c.? Global issues, how is waste disposed? Are any resources being polluted? Carbon footprints? Primark Evidence found underpaying workers and not paying overtime. Evidence found child labour being used. Evidence found of lack of regard for workers’ rights and lack of safety. Marks and Spencer's Evidence found fair pay for workers. Evidence found of use of child labour early on. Evidence found helping to assist workers to be shown how to how to do job properly. Evidence found changing to more ecofriendly recycled bags. Evidence found helping environment with ‘Plan A’. Evidence of Social Responsibility for Primark. This shows that Primark takes into account all social issues relating to the customers and stake holders. Evidence 1. This is an opinion of a stake holder (Primark’s owner). Primark's code of Conduct Primark’s code of Conduct: • Employment is freely chosen collective bargaining are respected • Working conditions are safe and hygienic • Child labour shall not be used • Living wages are paid • Working hours are not excessive • No discrimination is practised • Regular employment is provided • No harsh or inhumane treatment is allowed. • Freedom of association and the right to A limitation is that...

Words: 2128 - Pages: 9

Free Essay

Time

...duration of one's life; the hours and days which a person has at his disposal. How we dispose of that time is time management. It's the way we spend our time to organize and execute around our priorities. Remember just because time is intangible doesn't mean that it is not valuable. I want to teach you about the background of time management, the different styles and how to use them, and how it will change your life. Background Time management today is not as it was in the past. It has grown with time. Stephen R. Covey places time management into four generations. He feels it has evolved the same way society has. Each generation grows on the one before it. For example, the agriculture revolution was followed by the industrial revolution, which was then followed by the informational revolution. The first wave or generation is basically notes and checklist. Which really only identifies the demands placed on our time and energy. Calendars and appointment books characterize the second generation. This reflects an attempt to look ahead. The third generation is current time management field. It's the last two generations with the ideas of prioritization, clarifying values, and comparing the worth of...

Words: 317 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Trade Secrets

...Running head: Trade Secrets Name Course Tutor Date Introduction Economic espionage occurs when an individual knowingly shares sensitive information that may lead to financial loss or loss of a comparative advantage of the owner. Trade secrets are a form of information, formula, procedures, techniques, or prototypes that the owner has taken reasonable efforts to protect. Trade secrets have an independent economic value regardless the form they are. Economic espionage is commercially motivated. A company, individual, or government uses illegal tactics to gain commercially valuable information about a competitor. Most economic espionage involves an employee in a company bribed by a competitor to share sensitive information. The increased use of the computer and the Internet makes computer hacking another common economic espionage. In extreme cases, a competitor may hire a gang to break into the rivals premises to steal or destroy information. Trade secrets There are many methods used to gather information about rivals. Some of the methods are legal, whereas others are not. A rival may use information available in the newspaper, company reports, patent applications, and the Internet to collect intelligence regarding the activities and plans of a company. The use of unethical methods to achieve competitive advantage is on the increase. Since 1985, economic espionage on American companies has increased by 260%. In most of the cases, the aim of the espionage is to...

Words: 1049 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

B.U.G. Inc. Paper

...B.U.G. Inc. Paper LAW/421 May 9, 2013 B.U.G. Inc. Paper BUG Inc. is one of the largest manufacturers within confines of the United States that produces and sells electronic recording devices that are heavily used by law enforcement agencies, i.e., police, FBI, etc. to intercept and record sounds and voices. These products that are manufactured by BUG are highly dangerous if it falls into the wrong hands. These electronic devices have the ability to tap into telephone wires, cell phone transmissions, and even intercept sound waves and voices through the walls of any room in any house or open areas. BUG wants to expand its product internationally, but is hesitant to pursue because of possible detriments that it may have in regards to the different types of legal protections, civil liabilities, torts, and down to its privacy, security, infringement issues, and email contract validity. BUG Inc. hired a group of specialists to define these problem areas and discuss the importance of why it should be taken care of. Bug, Inc. should have several protections for its intellectual property. The protections include trademarks, trade secrets, copyrights, and patents. The Uniform Trade Secret act and common law protect the secret processes, formulas, methods, procedures, and lists that provide Bug, Inc. with economic advantage. This protection lasts for the life of the entity or owner. For example, customer lists with contact information, buying patterns, and credit histories involving...

Words: 1663 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Case Study

...parents' income. There are many causes of child labor. However, a closer look into those causes can help end the exploitation around the world. Businesses or corporations around the world are one of the major causes. Due to their influence and money driven attitudes, many factories are placed strategically in poor areas. This is to attract cheap labor and millions of children end up working for them. Another cause is the lack of protection from governments. Many developing nations and some industrial countries fail to provide millions of children proper education. Poverty may be the biggest cause of child labor. Child labour refers to the employment of children at regular and sustained labour. This practice is considered exploitative by many international organizations and is illegal in many countries. Child labour was employed to varying extents through most of history, but entered public dispute with the advent of universal schooling, with changes in working conditions during the industrial revolution, and with the emergence of the concepts of workers' and children's rights. In a developing...

Words: 363 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Capitalism - Jack the Ripper

...We have come a long way from the days of Feudalism where Lords were land (fief) owners and the vassals were the common folk who provided a service to the Lord for use of the land, whether it is to serve in the military or other forms as requested. This was the way of life in medieval times, up until the 15th century (Hirst, 2012). From here, the transition began from Feudalism to the early stage Capitalism, where the ordinary people broke away from the Feudal system and owned property and the means of production as well as the resources to make and maintain wealth (Dictionary.com, 2012). England in the 1800’s was hard in comparison to today. The life expectancy for a man aged 20 in 1850 was 60.1 years compared to 76.7 in 2004 (Geoff Canyon's Appeal to Authority, 2009). This was mainly due to the living conditions and especially those in the poor area of East London, where animals not only shared the often over crowed living area with humans but also the human waste that was thrown onto the streets. Often those who lived in the bottom apartments lived close to if not in the stench, more so than those who lived multiple stories above the streets. With the pollution of human waste in the streets and the polluted River Thames from the sewage of the West End, no matter where you lived in the East End, you still had to walk through the rising filth. These living conditions were the main reason for the various outbreaks of diseases, sores and premature deaths during the 1800’s...

Words: 2931 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

The Industrial Revolution

...The Industrial Revolution The term Industrial Revolution refers to the social and economic changes that led to the transition from an agricultural and commercial society to a modern industrial one. This revolution relied on machinery instead of basic tools. This happened in Great Britain in the middle of the 18th century until the middle of the 19th century. The Industrial Revolution spread to other parts of Europe as well as other parts of the world. The period of explorations from the 14th to the 16th centuries helped in laying the foundations for the Industrial Revolution. Because of the explorations and subsequently colonialism, gold and silver from the New World flooded Europe. Prices of commodities rose, industries bloomed and a money-based economy fully developed. The expansion of trade and the economy based on money led to the creation of financial and lending institutions. Thus, the necessary factors for the emergence of an Industrial Revolution had already been established in the 15thcentury. The term Industrial revolution does not imply that changes happened only in the industry. In fact, the rise in the number of factories, the economic changes and the new inventions in science all had a great impact in the lives of the people in Europe and even the whole world. THE RISE OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION IN GREAT BRITAIN From the 18th to the 19th centuries, Great Britain was the leading force in industry. It had large deposits of coal and iron. Because...

Words: 2414 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Why Nations Fails

...Why Nations Fail In this essay, I am reviewing a book entitled Why Nations Fail written by Daron Acemoglu, and James Robinson. The book was written in 2012, and the authors mention the ongoing Arab Spring as they were putting together their ideas in writing. This coincidence makes me wonder if these authors were also impacted by the information revolution or the information outburst as Nye (2013) often chooses to call. In fact, the authors did not mention the term ‘information revolution’ in the book; they simply state that Egyptians are on the street not because they are poor, as many scholars and political analysts suggest, but because power has resided in the hands of a few elites, and these elites have used political power to amass personal wealth at the expense of the bigger mass. But why the Egyptian revolution took place at this particular time, instead of a decade ago, for example? As far as I understand political theories, the answer lies behind globalization and information revolution which opened a new gate to information. That is, since billions of people around the globe are capable of reaching the internet (about 1.7 million according to Nye), many are able to read online news, or even watch them live as they are being broadcasted. Thus, it is possible to associate the Egyptian revolution or the Arab Spring to globalization and information revolution. Acemoglu et al, (2012) also indicate that Egypt’s ex-president, Hosni Mubarak gathered a huge amount of...

Words: 1702 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Industrial Revolution

...Child Laborer during Industrial Revolution in United States               During the Industrial Revolution kids were very harshly treated for no apparent reason. This is a story about a young fellow named William Spruce and his horrifying experiences about working in the factories and fields during the industrial Revolution.             Now William started working in the factories around the time he was ten years old. There were girls and boys of all ages working, some as young as four. He would work ten to fourteen hours and on some days. On certain days, he would work as long as eighteen hours with a one-hour break period. William would work so hard and would only get half as much or even a fraction of the pay than the adults would receive.             Every morning William would come to work as early as six in the morning. There were days he would wake up earlier too. Consequences included heavier workload if he was late. One day, William arrived late to the factory due to family illness; when he arrived to the factory practically out of breath from running, he only turned out being less than five minutes late. That didn’t seem to matter when he stepped through the factory door since an overseer came by and tied a very heavy weight around his neck. He made him walk up and down the factory aisles so the other children who were working can take an “example” out of him. William was humiliated; he had to do this for up to an hour on his bare feet while inhaling the toxic factory...

Words: 1079 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Inteligencia de Negocios

...Inteligencia de Negocios – Actividad Ética Transversal Protección jurídica a los programas de ordenador Para entender la protección jurídica de los programas de computadora en México, hay que tener una visión global y un punto de comparación. El tener una idea general nos dará una perspectiva más enfocada a conocer la aplicación de las leyes en México y cómo se diferencia con el resto del mundo. La protección de los programas de computadora, se puede dar de dos formas: ya sea por patente o por derechos de autor (modelo idóneo según los tratados internacionales). Las implicaciones sobre la posibilidad de patentar programas son muy importantes, ya que la patente no solamente protege la expresión de la idea, sino que, además, protege la propia idea tal y como se describe en las reivindicaciones de la propia patente. Esta protección puede ir desde cubrir solamente la copia textual hasta, en algunos casos, proteger más allá de los elementos literales de manera que se considera infracción algo que sea sustancialmente similar al original. El alcance de la protección jurídica es determinante para los desarrolladores. Copiando tal vez no el código textual, pero teniendo los diagramas y el saber cómo funciona, pueden hacerlo sin infringir la ley. Entre mayor sea la protección, mejor se pueden cuidar las ideas y por lo tanto habrá menos ideas de ese tipo de programas. Conforme al sistema legal mexicano, el derecho patrimonial de reproducción de un programa de ordenador no va más allá...

Words: 915 - Pages: 4