Free Essay

Islamic Finance

In:

Submitted By irfan0067
Words 14577
Pages 59
Islamic Economic Studies Vol.9, No. 2, March 2002

FINANCING MICROENTERPRISES: AN ANALYTICAL STUDY OF ISLAMIC MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS
HABIB AHMED ∗ While conventional microfinance institutions (MFIs) have expanded their operations in the last two decades, poverty-focused MFIs based on Islamic principles are lagging behind. This paper provides the theoretical basis, operational framework, and empirical support for the establishment of Islamic MFIs. After critically evaluating the conventional MFIs, an Islamic alternative is presented. The theoretical part of the paper shows that there is a great potentiality of Islamic MFIs that can cater for the needs of the poor. Islamic MFIs have some inherent characteristics that can mitigate some of the problems faced by conventional MFIs. Empirical evidence from three Islamic MFIs operating in Bangladesh, in general, supports some of the theoretical assertions. The case studies, however, reveal that Islamic MFIs have not yet tapped some of the sources of funds, nor have they used the variety of financial instruments in their operations. 1 ?. INTRODUCTION With the failure of experimenting in top-down (trickle down) development policies for a few decades to alleviate poverty in most developing countries, financing microenterprises is considered a “new paradigm” for bringing about development and eradicating absolute poverty. 1 Though the importance of developing small-scale enterprises has been discussed for a long time, the innovative poverty focused group-based financing of microentrepreneurs is a relatively new concept. Pioneered by Professor Muhammed Yunus of Grameen


Economist, Islamic Research and Training Institute, Islamic Development Bank. I gratefully acknowledge the assistance and support of the following in conducting the field survey on Islamic microfinance institutions in Bangladesh: Shah Abdul Hannan and Muzahidul Islam of Islamic Economics Research Bureau, field surveyors Mohammad Nurul Huda, Sheikh Muhsin Ali, Md. Hasan Sharif, and M.A. Hassan and nu merous officials of three microfinance institutions (Al-Fallah, Noble, and Rescue) surveyed. I am grateful to Ausaf Ahmad, Mabid A. Al-Jarhi, Osman Babikir, Boualem Bendjilali, M. Umer Chapra, Hussain Fahmy, Sirajul Haq, Munawar Iqbal, M. Fahim Khan, and Tariqullah Khan for their comments and suggestions on an earlier draft of the paper. I also thank two anonymous referees for their comments. The usual caveat of remaining errors being author’s responsibility, however, applies. 1 For an extensive study on microfinance, see Hulme and Mosley (1996a & b), Journal of International Development (Vol. 8, No. 2), Kimenyi, et al (1997), Otero and Rhyne (1994) and Schneider (1997).

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Bank in Bangladesh, microfinance institutions (MFIs) providing credit to the poor has burgeoned in both developing and industrialized countries. A total of USD 7 billion has been disbursed to over 13 million people worldwide by microfinance institutions (Parker 1998, p. 8). “Microcredit Summit 1997”2 envisages that 100 million poor would have access to microfinance by 2005. Most of the microfinance institutions (MFIs), however, have non-Islamic characteristics. Their financing is interest-based. Furthermore, apart from the delivery of finance to the poor, many MFIs have social development programs that are mostly secular in nature. Given that microfinance can facilitate poverty alleviation, this paper studies the prospects of microfinance from an Islamic perspective. We first outline the features of the conventional MFIs and critically examine their strengths and weaknesses. A model for Islamic microfinancing is then outlined drawing from the strengths of conventional MFIs. Apart from identifying the differences between the conventional MFIs and their Islamic counterpart, the paper addresses how the latter MFIs deal with some of the inherent problems of the former. These theoretical discussions are com plemented with the experiences of three Islamic MFIs operating in Bangladesh. The paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we first define microenterprises and then discuss the economics of financing these activities. Given the important role of devel pment that microenterprises play in poverty alleviation, this section o argues for social intermediation by specialized microfinance institutions. It then critically evaluates the operations of conventional MFIs. In section 3, an Islamic alternative is pres ented and compared with the conventional one. Sections 4 through 7 are based on the results of a field survey conducted on three Islamic MFIs operating in Bangladesh. While section 4 gives basic information regarding these MFIs and their beneficiaries, section 5 evaluates the performance of these institutions. Section 6 identifies some of the problems faced by the Islamic MFIs and section 7 critically evaluates the operations of Islamic MFIs surveyed and concludes the paper. 2. FINANCING MICROENTERPRISES: THEORY AND INSTITUTIONS Microenterprises can be defined differently, depending on country’s stage of development, policy objectives, and administration (World Bank 1978, p.18). Micro and small enterprises are identified as those having fixed capital or he t number of workers under certain threshold levels. Microenterprises constitute small
2

The Microcredit Summit was held on February 2-4, 1997 in Washington DC. The Summit was participated by 2,900 people from 137 countries. A nine year campaign was launched to provide credit to 100 million poor by year 2005. For more information on Microcredit Summit, see www.microcreditsummit.org.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

businesses and shops, cottage industries, transport services, etc. 3 Three broad categories of economic activities can be identified namely, production, trading, and providing transport services. In production, the poor may be involved in agricultural or non-agricultural activities. Agricultural activities include farming, cattle rearing, poultry rearing and fisheries. Non-agricultural production can cover a wide variety of activities ranging from food processing to producing different handicrafts and household items like pots, mats, cloth, etc. Trading includes shopkeeping, small business, and selling specific items like vegetables, fish, etc. Providing transport services can be through rickshaws, boats, or motor vehicles used as taxis. Growth in microenterprises or small enterprises can be important means for employment generation and development of poor countries. High population growth rate and limited employment opportunities in the agricultural sector and the modern manufacturing sectors leaves a vast majority of the labor force without productive employment. Microenterprises can play a significant role in employing the surplus labor force productively. Other than generating employment, a World Bank study (1978) points out the advantages of microenterprises as increasing the aggregate output, enabling the efficient use of capital and labor, initiating indigenous enterprise and management skills, bringing a regional balance, and improving the distribution of income. The problems associated with microenterprises are identified as low wages, high price of finance, and use of primitive technology. Furthermore, limited input and output markets and inadequate infrastructure facilities can hinder the growth of small enterprises. Smaller firms usually do not have any access to funds from traditional financial institutions (Berger and Udell 1998). The underlying theoretical explanation for this phenomenon lies in the traditional problems of asymmetric information in financial intermediation. The problems of adverse selection and moral hazard worsen in case of smaller enterprises in developing countries due to some added constraints and problems. Bennett (1998) points out some b arriers that can arise between the financial institutions and the clients in a developing economy perspective. These barriers can accentuate the asymmetric information problems. Physical barriers of poor infrastructure like lack of markets, roads, power, communications, can worsen both the adverse selection and moral hazard problems. Physical constraints inhibit the financial institutions to gather information on their prospective clients and once credit is advanced, it is difficult to monitor the use of the funds. Socioeconomic factors of clients like low numerical skills due to illiteracy, caste/ethnicity/gender aspects preventing interaction also add to the adverse selection problem.

3

Though in some writings, a difference is made between microenterprises and enterprises financed by microfiance institutions, in this paper we consider these two kinds of enterprises to be the same.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Microentrepreneur’s lack of collateral due to poverty can increase the moral hazard problem. These barriers would make assessment of projects and monitoring the use of loans (to minimize adverse selection and moral hazard problems) very costly. Furthermore, as the size of the loan for microenterprise is small, the administering cost of loans increases. These economic factors make it impossible for traditional financial institutions to offer credit to microenterprises. While small-scale business has been the focus of some development policies, the smallest amongst them were left out from these programs. The problems of financing pointed out above become more acute in case of microenterprises run by impoverished. As these enterprises are important means to increase employment and reduce poverty, there is a need for a social financial intermediation of funds for the microentrepreneurs. Bennett (1998, pp. 106-7) points out two approaches of financing microenterprises. First, the linking approach under which conventional financial institutions are linked to the target group (i.e., the poor) through some intermediary like a government agency, a non-government organization (NGO) or a local group. The other approach is to provide microcredit through specialized organizations, like NGOs, government agencies, cooperatives, and development finance institutions. Almost all of the financing for microenterprises in recent times has come from the latter kind of institutions. We discuss the nature of these institutions next. 2.1. Specialized Financial Institutions for Microenterprises Traditionally, sources of credit in developing countries can be broadly classified as institutional and non-institutional. While institutional sources include financial institutions and cooperatives, non-institutional supply of credit comes from friends, relatives, and money-lenders. Even though the importance of developing smallenterprises has been recognized, the poor microentrepreneurs do not have access to the institutional sources, as some physical collateral, which they often lack, is a prerequisite for getting loans from these sources. Moreover, as pointed out above, the banks are not interested in financing microenterprises since the transaction cost per unit of credit is high. Thus, the non-institutional loans form the bulk of the credit for the poor. 4 With the exception of credit from friends and relatives, the interest rate on these loans is exorbitant. In some cases, the poor loose their land or other assets against which credit is provided. Pioneered by the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh, MFIs have developed as specialized financial institutions that cater to the needs of the poor.5 Microfinance
4

For example, before the operations of MFIs in Bangladesh, only 10-15 percent of the rural credit requirements in Bangladesh came from institutional sources (Ahmed 1983, p. 18). 5 Though different approaches to microfinance have evolved, the dominant among these is the Grameen Bank model (Morduch 1999).

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

is a new concept in banking and has distinct characteristics. In order to understand the nature of MFIs as specialized financial institutions, we briefly outline their operations and activities next. 6 To get finance from MFIs the client or beneficiary has to be poor. Different institutions define their target group in different ways. For example, a household must own less than 0.4 acres of land and must not have assets exceeding the market value of one acre of cultivable land to be eligible to get credit from Grameen Bank. A person must form a group of five like-minded people with similar socioeconomic status to get credit. Male and female groups are formed separately and relatives cannot be in the same group. A group is usually trained for couple of weeks to be familiar with the rules and procedures of the MFI. Each group elects its own chairman and secretary. A number of groups are federated into a center with a center chief and deputy center chief elected from amongst them. Weekly meetings of the center are held at a convenient place in the locality. All members (i.e., beneficiaries) of the center are required to attend these meetings. An MFI official attends the meeting to conduct the transactions and other business of the center. MFIs provide small amount of credit on interest to the poor without any physical collateral. 7 Instead, social collateral is introduced by forming groups. Loan repayment by an indiv idual member of a group is the collective responsibility of all the members in the group and default by a member disqualifies all members to get new loans. Members in the group monitor the activities of each other and peer pressure induces the repayment of the loan. This format of peer monitoring mitigates the problem of asymmetric information and reduces transaction costs (Huppi and Feder 1990, Morduch 1999, Stiglitz 1990). Borrowers are involved in multiple activities, which mostly do not require special skills (Dichter 1996, p. 263). Loans are given for three months to a year at market rate of interest and repaid with interest in weekly/monthly installments. Borrowers meet weekly/monthly at centers where an official from the MFI institution collects ins tallments. Most MFIs target women as they are considered better borrowers in terms of use and repayment of funds (for example over 94 percent of Grameen borrowers are women). By providing much needed financial capital to the poor, these institutions enable them to be self-employed in productive activities thereby increasing their income levels. Most MFIs have various (forced) savings programs. In case of Grameen Bank, 5 percent of the loans is deducted for group (risk) fund and a quarter of the total interest amount is collected as emergency (insurance) fund when the principal is handed over to a member. While
6

The format discussed here is that of Grameen Bank, which serves as the dominant model for most microfinance institutions, ibid. 7 Other than meeting the target group criterion and the description of the project for which funds are sought, the prerequisites may include knowing how to sign names, memorizing of certain rules, regulations, and slogans that form the basis of the social development program.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

the beneficiaries can borrow from the risk fund in case of major social event (like wedding ceremony), the emergency fund is given to members in times of distress. In addition, the members are required to put aside a small amount (Taka 1) every week in their personal savings account. Sometimes, MFIs also extend credit to individuals for building houses and to a group or center for collective enterprise. Most MFIs have a social development program along with their credit programs. The objective of this program is to generate personal and social consciousness among the members. These programs include aspects that affect behavioral changes (such as personal hygiene, sanitation, drinking clean water), moral teachings (like teaching to be honest, disciplined and cooperate among themselves) and social customs (like accepting family planning, not practicing the dowry system). Knowing these principles and norms are prerequisites to obtain loans from the MFI and are continuously inculcated in the members during the weekly meetings. Sometimes, workshops and exchange visits are also organized to complement the teachings inculcated in weekly meetings. At times, necessary inputs to implement these social programs (like tube wells for water, oral rehydration salt) are provided by the MFI on subsidized basis. As can be observed, MFIs being banks for the poor operate quite differently from the conventional commercial banks (see Table 1). Whereas commercial banks are profit-maximizing firms, MFIs are either government or non-government organizations (NGOs) formed to provide the poor with much-needed finance. Given this nature, most MFIs have a social development program along with its credit facilities. Furthermore, the structure of liabilities is different in case of two institutions. A conventional bank is a financial intermediary linking the savers and investors in the economy, with deposits forming the bulk of a bank’s liabilities. For MFIs, funds from external sources form the bulk of the liabilities. The savings of their clients (beneficiaries) are the only deposits. Moreover, unlike conventional banks where clients come to the bank, MFIs go to the people to extend financial services. 2.2 MFIs: Prospects and Problems Microfinance initiative is acclaimed as a new approach to poverty alleviation and to bring about development. Microfinance alleviates poverty as the credit given in successive years is used in productive economic activity(ies), increases the household income and saving and enables the household to build up its own capital. Income and saving eventually increase to a level where the household does not depend on borrowed capital. At this stage, the household graduates to non-poor status and becomes a full-fledged microenterprise. This process of graduation is termed by Muhammed Yunus, as the virtuous circle of ‘low income, credit, investment, more income, more credit, more investment, more income’ (see Hulme and Mosley 1996a, p. 108). While a vast literature exists that shows the success of

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

MFIs,8 some recent studies point out the failure of these institutions in meeting some of their objectives. Some of the problems identified are given below. Table 1 Comparison between Conventional Banks and Microfinance Institutions Conventional Banks A profit-maximizing firm Financial Intermediary between savers and investors in the economy Deposit forms the bulk of the liability Does not include social/educational programs Physical Collateral required to get funds Clients are relatively well-off Clients come to the bank Amount of loan is large Capital and interest usually paid at the maturity of the contract Most clients are men Microfinance Institutions (MFI) Non-profit Government/Nongovernment Organizations Funds from external sources provided to the poor Savings (forced) of the clients only deposits Includes social/educational programs Social collateral through group and center formation Clients are poor MFI goes to the people Amount of loan is small Capital and interest paid in weekly/monthly installments over a year. Most clients are women

1. Asymmetric Information Problems: The bulk of the loan by microfinance institutions is targeted towards women. In reality, however, the male members of the household initiate taking loans and control the funds received by the female members. Furthermore, loans taken from the bank are often used for purposes other than those for which the loan is sanctioned (Rahman 1999, p. 75). When loans are used for non-productive purposes, the chances of default increase. Buckley (1996, p. 390) reports that in 1993, 46 percent of the Malawi Mudzi Fund’s (a MFI in Malawi) borrowers were in arrears because they diverted the funds for consumption purposes. Among the defaulters (those who did not pay more than 4 installments), the corresponding number was 33 percent.

8

See Bornstein (1996), Fuglesang and Chandler (1993), Goetz and Gupta (1996), Hashemi, et al (1996), and Hossain (1983, 1987).

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

2. Economic Viability of MFIs: Due to lack of fund mobilization and the high administrative cost, most MFIs are not economically viable. Bennett (1998, p. 116) reports that administrative cost of five MFIs in South Asia is in the range of 24 percent to more than 400 percent of per dollar lent. Reed and Befus (1994, p. 190) study five MFIs and find average return on assets for three of these to be below 2 percent, one at 3.5 percent and the other at 14.6 percent. Hashemi (1997) and Khandker, et. al. (1995) point out that Grameen Bank would operate at a loss without grants. A Subsidy Dependence Index (SDI) developed by Yaron (1992) indicate that in 1996 Grameen Bank would have to increase its lending interest rate by an additional 21 percent in order to breakeven without subsidies (Hashemi, 1997). Similarly, Hulme and Mosley (1996a, p. 52) find that 12 out of 13 MFIs from six countries have positive SDI ranging from 32 percent to 1884 percent. 3. Low Rate of Return on Investment: The type of activity for which the funds are used may also be low productivity activities. Furthermore, MFIs target women and some studies find that rate of return on credit given to women is low as they engage in relatively low productivity activities (Hossain 1987, Rahman and Khandker 1994). Osmani (1989) points out that one factor that forces some households out of microcredit schemes is that the result ing increase in the supply of output causes the rate of return on loans to be lower than its cost of borrowing. 4. High Drop-out Rate and Non Graduation from Poverty: Ditcher (1996), Hulme and Mosley (1996a), and Montgomery (1996) report that microfinance institutions do not serve the poorest who are either not given loans or drop out of the credit schemes. 9 Karim and Osada (1998) observe that there is a steady increase in dropout rate from Grameen Bank (15 percent in 1994) and that 88 percent of the total dropouts did not graduate to the status of non-poor. Assaduzzaman (1997) finds that whereas microfinance does increase the income level of the poor, the current operations of MFIs are not very effective in improving the lives of the extreme poor. Hulme and Mosley (1996b, p. 114) report that the average income of a household borrowing for a third time from Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC), a microfinance institution in Bangladesh, is less than a household that has borrowed only once (average incom e being 58 percent and 68.5 percent of the poverty line respectively). Ahmed (1998) finds that longer association with Grameen Bank reduces the household income. 5. Debt Trap: In a recent survey, Rahman (1996 a, b, 1999) discovers that the Grameen Bank borrowers often take loans from other sources to pay installments and are trapped in a spiraling debt cycle. 10
9

For example, dropout rates for the Grameen Bank and BRAC are 15 percent and 10-15 percent per annum, respectively (Hulme and Mosley 1996a, p. 122). 10 Newspaper reports allege that “the poor are falling victims of vicious cycles of creditors and NGOs” (Holiday, Feb. 7, 1977, p. 8) and that instead of removing poverty, the Grameen Bank is “robbing whatever resources people had” (New Nation, October 26, 1996).

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

6. Targeting Women as Recipients: The declared objective of targeting women as recipients of funds is to empower them (Khandker 1998 and Rahman 1999). Khandker (1998), however, finds that financing women rarely empowers women. Rahman (1999) further reports that targeting the women as beneficiaries of credit by MFIs creates tensions within the household and increases frustration and violence in the family. This is because receiver of funds and the user are different people. The male members put pressure on the female members to obtain funds, as it is easier for women to get funds. While the women apply for the funds and are responsible for its repayment, it is often men who use the funds. At the other end, the MFI puts pressure on the female members to repay the installments, who in turn put pressure on their male counterparts. Note the points 1 and 2 mentioned above relate to the fundamental problem of financial intermediation mentioned before. As asymmetric information exists, the monitoring/supervision costs of financial institutions increase. Points 3, 4, and 5 relate to borrowers’ investment decisions and viability of the projects they invest in. Point 6 relates to social issues of microfinancing. Given these drawbacks in conventional microfinancing, and recognizing that microfinance can be an important vehicle in poverty alleviation, we discuss an Islamic alternative to microfinancing next. After discussing the approach to Islamic microfinancing, we discuss the results from field survey on three Islamic MFIs operating in Bangladesh. While we touch on different problems mentioned above, the discussion will focus primarily on the asymmetric information problem and profitability/viability of MFIs. 3. ISLAMIC MFI S AND CONVENTIONAL MFIS : A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS Initiatives in Islamic banking and conventional microfinancing started concurrently in the mid-1970s. Given the newness of Islamic banking, researchers and practitioners have, until recently, overlooked issues related to Islamic microfinance. Though there has been discussion on financing small-scale enterprises by specialized institutions and Islamic banks using Islamic modes (see Mohsin 1995 and Yousri 1995), the new innovative poverty-focused format used by MFIs has not been examined. As mentioned earlier, the innovative operational format of MFIs suits the poor, whose lack of physical collateral disqualifies them to borrow from traditional commercial banks. Group based microlending acts as social collateral and lessens the asymmetric information problem that exists in financial intermediation. Islamic microfinance institutions (IMFIs) can retain this innovative format of operation of conventional MFIs and orient the program towards Islamic principles and values. Though the basic format of Islamic MFIs will be similar to that of its conventional counterpart, there will be certain

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

qualitative differences among them. The nature of Islamic MFIs and their differences from conventional MFIs are discussed below.11 3.1 Sources of Funds Other than being interest-free, IMFIs would differ from conventional MFIs in several important ways. On the liability side, the sources of funds of conventional MFIs come mainly from foreign donors (both multilateral and national agencies), government and the central bank. IMFIs, in addition, can get funds from religious institutions of waqf and other forms of charities. The institution of waqf originated during the time o the Prophet (peace be upon him) and entails the use of cash, f land, real estate for charitable purposes. 12 There are certain conditions governing waqf, but the objective is to serve the poor and the community. The presence of waqf and charities on the liability side of IMFIs is compatible with the social financial intermediation role of MFIs. 3.2 Modes of Financing On the asset side of the balance sheet, the bulk of the assets of conventional MFIs are interest-bearing debt, given for different activities (trade, production, transport services, etc.). Interest (one form of riba) being prohibited in Islam, the assets of IMFIs will comprise different types of non-interest bearing financial instruments. Important aspects of Islamic modes of finance are that financial capital cannot claim a return on itself and that the transaction must involve a real good or object. Principles of Islamic financing are many and varied. The type of financing instrument will depend on the type of activity for which funds are granted. As discussed earlier, the economic activities that microenterprises usually engage in are production, trading and providing (transport) services. We point out the appropriate Islamic modes of financing for these activities below. Other than interest-free loans (qard-hasan), the principles of Islamic financing can be broadly classified as partnerships (shirakat) and exchange contracts (mu’awadat).13 Partnership can be on the basis of profit sharing or output sharing. Though there are different kinds of exchange contracts, the important among these is the deferred-trading principle. Deferred-trading contract can either be a price-deferred sale or an object-deferred sale. What is relevant for microfinancing is the price deferred sale (bay‘-mu’ajjal) in which the object of sale is delivered at
11

The information on IMFIs in this section was gathered in a field survey and interviews with the officials of these institutions conducted by the author. 12 Çizakça (1996) discusses the cash waqfs in Turkey during the Ottoman period giving its legal background. For detailed discussions of waqf see Basar (1987) and Çizakça (1998). 13 Detailed expositions of the different principles of Islamic financing are found in Kahf and Khan (1992) and Ahmad (1993).

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

the time of the contract but the price is paid later. The price can also be paid in the future in installments. One type of financial transaction under this format is markup sale (murabahah), in which the IMFI buys a good or asset and sells it to the client at a mark-up. The client pays for the good or asset at a future date or in installments. Ijarah is a leasing contract in which the client uses an asset by paying rent. One form of this arrangement can be the hire-purchase scheme or leasepurchase scheme (ijarah wa iqtina‘), in which the installment includes rent and part of the price. When the installments are fully paid, the ownership of the asset is transferred to the client. From the discussion above, we see that various kinds of financing arrangements can be used to finance different kinds of activities. Musharakah principle can be used in production (agricultural and non-agricultural). The IMFI can provide part of the financial capital to produce an output and in return receive a share of the profit. In trading, the IMFI and the client can jointly finance the purchase and selling of a certain good and distribute the profit. Production undertaken under mudarabah principle would imply that the IMFI finances and the client manage the project. In agricultural production, output sharing can take the form of muzara‘ah. The IMFI may fund the purchase of irrigation equipment, fertilizers, etc., which the landowner uses on his land to cultivate a certain crop. The harvested crop is then shared by the landowner and the IMFI at an agreed ratio. Other than profit-sharing principle discussed above, murabahah and ijarah forms of financing can also be used in production. For example, if a client is in need of initial physic al capital (equipment, gadgets, etc.), the IMFI can buy the items and sell these to the client at a mark-up. In trading, profit sharing schemes and deferred trading contracts can be used. The murabahah principle can be applied where the items to be trad ed are first bought by IMFI and then sold at a mark-up to the clients. The clients pay back the IMFI once they sell the goods. In transport services, both mark-up principle and the leasing principle can be applied. For example, if a client wants to buy a rickshaw, the IMFI can purchase it and sell it to the client at a mark-up. The client then pays the price on an agreed installment plan. Alternatively, hire-purchase arrangement can be made in which the client pays rent plus a part of the price in his installments. Once the installments are fully paid, the client becomes the owner of the rickshaw.14 3.3 Financing the Poorest It has been pointed out above that the poorest sections of the population are left out by conventional MFIs. One reason is that extreme poverty leads to the diversion of
14

Some hypothetical examples to illustrate some ways in which Islamic financing principles can be applied can be found in Ahmad (1998).

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

funds from productive activities to consumption and asset purchases. This lowers the overall return on investment and makes it difficult for the poor to repay the loans. The IMFIs, however, can combine the institution of zakah and other forms of voluntary charity (sadaqah) in microfinancing to provide financial services to the poorest. Zakah 15 and sadaqah in Islam are important tools for the redistribution of income and growth. Zak ah is one of the five pillars of Islam and obligatory on every wealthy Muslim. Zak ah and other forms of charities can be used to increase the participation in production of the poor (El-Ghazali, 1994, p. 48). Zakah can be integrated into the microfinance program in a variety of ways to benefit the poorest beneficiaries. It can be transferred to the poor as outright grants or given as qardhasan and can be used either for consumption or for investment purposes.16 In case of the extreme poor, zakah can be given as grants to stop the diversion of funds for consumption purposes so that the funds from IMFI can be used exclusively in production. As zakah will reduce the need for diverting funds meant for investment to unproductive use, it is expected that investments in productive activities will increase the overall return decreasing the probability of default.17 Thus, integrating zakah with microfinancing will not only improve the economic condition of the poor, but also ensure the repayment of the funds to the IMFI. 3.4 Amount of Funds Transferred to Beneficiaries As mentioned above, once a loan is sanctioned, conventional MFIs deduct a part of the principal for different funds (group and emergency funds). The beneficiary, however, pays interest on the total amount sanctioned. As a result the effective interest rate that the beneficiary pays to the MFI increases. 18 Furthermore, it is easier for a beneficiary to divert funds to non-productive uses once cash is received. Under Islamic modes of financing this is not possible. In principle, when a good is being transferred by the IMFI, no deductions can be made. As cash is not handed out, the scope of diverting money for other uses becomes difficult, if not impossible.

15 16

For detailed discussion on zakah, see El Ashker and Haq (1995). Though there is a view that zakah should involve transfer of ownership of funds, a few scholars have opinioned that it can be given as qard -hasan (Qarda wi 1980, p. 634 and Moududi 1985, pp. 5657). OIC Fiqh Academy (resolution no. 3), Kuwait Finance House (Fat awa Nos. 247 and 426) and Kuwait Zakat House (Fatwa No. 81) opinion that zakah can be used for investment purposes. 17 This was pointed out by Mohammad Muzahidul Islam, Associate Professor, Department of Finance, Dhaka University. 18 For example, Grameen Bank charges 20 percent on its loans and deducts 5 percent for the Group fund. If Tk.1000 is sanctioned, a beneficiary receives Tk.950 and pays Tk.200 as interest, making the effective interest rate to be 21.05 percent.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

3.5 Group Dynamics There will be some qualitative differences in the group dynamics of the beneficiaries of IMFIs compared to that of conventional ones. Group guarantee in repaying the funds back to the IMFIs may take the form of kafalah, making the group members guarantors for repayment. The members in the group can agree to help each other in case of inability of any member to pay the installment. One way to do this is to provide qard-hasan (interest-free loans) to the person facing problems in paying the installments. 3.6 Social Development Program Whereas the content of the social development program of conventional MFIs is secular (and sometimes anti-Islamic) in nature, 19 the counterpart of IMFIs has Islamic content. In the social development program different behavioral, ethical, and social aspects are introduced in the light of Is lamic principles. Islamic approach has a couple of benefits. First, people feel more comfortable adapting to these norms as they take them as part of belief and worship. Second, the Islamic social development program builds the social capital (e.g., feelin g of brotherhood and comradeship, obligation to repay debt), which helps repayment of installments regularly. 3.7 Objective of Targeting Women As mentioned above, the majority of the clients of conventional MFIs are women. The objective of targeting women in the conventional approach is to empower them. The rationale is that women use the funds productively to increase their income levels. As a result, they become more independent and this increases their self-respect. As pointed out above, however, some recent studies show that this is not the case (Khandker 1998 and Rahman 1999). The male members of the household usually persuade the women to obtain credit and often use it. The women, however, are responsible for the repayment of the installments. This creates tensions in the family. Though the majority of beneficiaries of Islamic MFIs are women, the underlying objectives of choosing them are very different from those of the conventional approach. IMFIs target group is the family. This is evident in th e contract between the IMFI and the beneficiary. Both, the women and the spouse sign the contract and are liable for the repayment of the funds. IMFIs deal with women, as it is more convenient and efficient. It is easier for women to attend the weekly meetings, as men go out to work and are not available. Another important externality of dealing with women is that they are at the receiving end of the social
19

See Ahmad (1998) for a discussion.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

development program. It is believed that imparting Islamic teachings to women serves the purpose of dissemination better as they convey these values to the other members of the family (particularly children). This attitude, along with the other religious content of the Social Development Program (discussed below) does not create tensions in the family. 3.8 Work Incentive of Staff Members Given the Islamic approach of IMFIs, the attributes of staff members working in them are different from the conventional MFIs. All three IMFIs inform that they recruit employees by first advertising the positions in newspapers. The candidates have to take a written examination and then face interview. Other than profession related skills, the IMFIs also seek Islamic orientation and a desire to work for the betterment of the poor in the candidates. The employees, as such, not only work to earn a living but also take the work as part of their religious duty. This acts as an incentive to work effectively and decreases the shirking behavior of the staff members of IMFIs. 3.9 Dealing with Default To deal with arrears and default, conventional MFIs use group and center pressure. When this fails, sometimes threats are made and in extreme cases assets are sold. IMFIs approach has certain advantages when it comes to dealing with arrears and defaults. The spirit of brotherhood and mutual help created by Islamic teachings induces members of a group or the center to assist in paying the arrears. Other than the group/center members, the spouse of the member can also be approached. Furthermore, the Islamic doctrine of not paying back debt as sinful also motivates the members to repay their dues. The differences between Islamic MFIs and conventional MFIs are summarized in Table 2.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

Table 2 Differences between Conventional and Islamic MFIs Conventional MFI External Funds, Savings of clients Interest-based Poorest are left out Islamic MFI External funds, Savings of clients, Islamic Charitable Sources Islamic Financial Instruments Poorest can included by integrating zakah with microfinancing Good transferred No deductions at inception Family Ease of availability Recipient and spouse

Liabilities (Sources of Funds) Assets (Mode of Financing) Financing the Poorest

Funds transfer Deductions at inception of contract Target group Objective of targeting Women Liability of the loan (when given to women) Work incentive of employees Dealing with Default

Cash given Part of the funds deducted at inception Women Empowerment of women Recipient

Monetary Group/center pressure and threats Secular (or un-Islamic) behavioral, ethical, and social development.

Monetary and religious Group/center/spouse guarantee, and Islamic ethics Religious (includes behavior, ethics, and social)

Social Development Program

4. IMFIs AND THEIR BENEFICIARIES: NATURE AND CHARACTERISTICS In this section, we present the information gathered from three IMFIs operating in Bangladesh and their beneficiaries. The discussion is based on information collected in a field survey and interviews with the officials of these institutions. After briefly outlining the field survey, we discuss the different characteristics of the IMFIs and their beneficiaries below.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

4.1 Field Survey: A Brief Preview The field survey was conducted during the period of August 18, 1999 to November 10, 1999 in Bangladesh. Islamic Economics Research Bureau (IERB), Dhaka was approached to assist in the field survey. They identified four field surveyors and contacted Association of Muslim Welfare Associations in Bangladesh (AMWAB) to identify the IMFIs. After discussions with officials of IERB, it was decided that surveyors would survey beneficiaries and officials of three IMFIs. The surveyors were trained and mock interviews were conducted. After discussions with the officials of IERB and AMWAB, Al-Fallah Aam Unnayan Sangstha, Noble Educational & Literary Society, and Rescue were chosen for the survey. The criteria for choosing the IMFIs were age and ease of accessibility. Of these three, two (Al-Fallah and Rescue) are engaged in microfinancing, the other (Noble) has other schemes (education, fisheries and forestry, etc.). The field surveyors went to the head offices of the respective IMFIs and had interviews with the officials. Information on beneficiaries was gathered by going to the weekly meetings and randomly choosing the beneficiaries for interviewing. The author personally interviewed the officials of these IMFIs to have a better understanding of the operations of these institutions. 4.2 Management Structure of IMFIs Though the specific management structure varies from one IMFI to another, they appear to have a similar pattern in general. Often the initial activities of the IMFI start with the contributions of the members of the Board of Directors. The members in the Board constitute a group of conscientious people interested in the welfare of the poor. The Board of Directors is the policy making body of the institution. The Executive Director runs the institution and is responsible for implementing the decisions taken by the Board of Directors. Under the Executive Director, Managers of Accounts and Administration take care of their respective departments. The General Manager oversees all microfinance operations carried out at the branch level. The Branch Manager is responsible for his branch activities. Under him, supervisors direct Field Workers who do most of the work at field level. Field workers (and sometimes supervisors) attend the weekly meetings at locations, train the beneficiaries, receive application for funds, collect installments, etc. The management structure of a typical IMFI is given in Appendix-I. 4.3 IMFIs: Facts and Figures Before discussing the performance of IMFIs, we elaborate the characteristics of the institutions and their beneficiaries. We discuss the attributes of the IMFIs in

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

this sub-section and outline the characteristics of the beneficiaries in the next subsection. Table 3 gives the basic information of three IMFIs included in the study. AlFallah located in Dinajpur district started its operations the earliest (1989) is the largest of the three IMFIs n terms of having the most beneficiaries (6,793), i employees (40), and highest disbursement (Tk.23,918,000). It also has the highest disbursement of Tk.3521 per beneficiary. Next is Noble, based in Bogra, started its operation most recently (1993). It has the fewest number of beneficiaries (2,251), but a relatively larger disbursement of Tk.3127 per beneficiary. The last IMFI, Rescue of Rangpur district, started its operation in 1991. It has 2515 beneficiaries and an average disbursement of Tk.2148 per member. Female beneficiaries are dominant in all three IMFIs, particularly in Al Fallah (98.6 percent) and Rescue (97.5 percent). The dropout rate in Noble and Rescue averages 3.75 percent. Savings per beneficiary equal Tk.276.9 and Tk.352.7 for Noble and Rescue respectively. 20 The officials of IMFIs inform that the members seldom want to cut off dealings with IMFIs. Most of the dropouts are released at the initiative of the IMFIs as disciplinary actions against some unwelcome behavior. Table 3 Basic Information on IMFIs Al-Fallah Location of Operation Year of Establishment No. of Beneficiaries Total Disbursements a (Tk.) Disbursement/Beneficiary (Tk.) Number of Employees Female Beneficiaries (% of total) Dropout Rate (% of total) Members Savings (Tk.) Risk Fund (Tk.) Members Savings/beneficiary (Tk.) Dinajpur 1989 6,793 23,918,000 3521 40 98.6% Noble Bogra 1993 2,251 7,039,000 3127 32 67.7% 3.7% 623,231 20,288 276.9 Rescue Rangpur 1991 2,515 5,402,000 2148 19 97.5% 3.8% 886,933 156,622b 352.7

a. For the fiscal year 1998-1999 (July 1, 1998 to June 30, 1999) b. Risk Management Fund

20

Data on dropout rate, and the breakdown of member savings and risk fund was not available for AlFallah.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Table 4 shows the asset structure of the IMFIs. The bulk of the assets for all three IMFIs is earning assets (79.9 percent for Al Fallah, 85.4 percent for Noble, and 8 percent for Rescue). Noble has relatively large share of fixed assets (12.3 0.9 percent of the total). While Al-Fallah has a relatively high percentage of deposits with banks (15.9 percent), Rescue holds 12.9 percent of assets as cash. Table 4 Asset Structure of IMFIs
Total (Tk.) Deposits with Banks (Tk.)(% of Total) Earning Assets (Tk.) (% of Total) Fixed Assets (Tk.) (% of Total) Cash (Tk.) (% of Total) Al-Fallah 14,585,516 2,323,316 (15.9%) 11,657,375 (79.9%) 585,182 (4%) 19,643 (0.13%) Noble 1,931,524 45,514 (2.4%) 1,648,700 (85.4%) 237,310 (12.3%) Rescue 3,908,541 152,297 (3.9%) 3,161,137 (80.9%) 90,196 (2.3%) 504,910 (12.9%)

Table 5 shows the capital and liability structure of the three IMFIs. Al-Fallah has the largest capital fund (13.2 per cent) and Rescue the smallest (2.2 percent). Similarly, Al-Fallah has mobilized beneficiaries’ funds to the tune ofTk.7,077,286 (48.5 percent). Rescue has the lowest amount of beneficiary accounts (4.4 percent) and the highest amount of net borrowing (92.4 percent) from external sources. 21 More than 50 percent of Noble’s liabilities are borrowed, while a quarter of AlFallah’s liabilities constitutes net borrowing. Table 5 Capital and Liability Structure of IMFIs
Total (Tk.) Capital Funda (Tk.) (% of Total) Beneficiaries Accounts (Tk.) (% of Total) Net Borrowing (Tk.) (% of Total) Other liability (credit) (Tk.) (% of Total) Al-Fallah 14,585,516 1,932,108 (13.2%) 7,077,286 (48.5%) 3,622,767 (24.8%) 1,653,355 (11.3%) Noble 1,931,524 241,105 (12.5%) 643,519 (33.3%) 1,046,900 (54.2%) Rescue 3,908,541 87,467 (2.2%) 172,747 (4.4%) 3,612,494 (92.4%) 35,833 (0.9%)

a. Includes Net Profit form current year operations.
21

All three IMFIs have borrowed funds from Palli Karma Sahayak Foundation (PKSF), a national organ created to finance microfinance activities in Bangladesh.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

Table 6 shows the income earned from different income earning assets. Bulk of the financing takes place in the form of bay[ mu’ajjal. Income earned from this mode of financing is 86.4 percent for Al-Fallah, 86.2 percent for Noble, and 75.9 percent for Rescue. Only Noble has income from some other Islamic instruments. Seven percent of its income comes from musaqah and musharakah from forestry and fishery activities. Table 6 Income and their Sources of IMFIs
Al-Fallah Total (Tk.) Deposits with Banks (Tk.) (% of Total) Musharakah (Tk.) (% of Total) Bay[ mu’ajjal (Tk.) (% of Total) Other Income/Grants (Tk.) (% of Total) 3,347,860 463,965 (13.9%) 2,491,805 (74.4%) 392,090 (11.7%) Noble 491,623 18,941 (3.9%) 34,500 (7%) 423,763 (86.2%) 14,419 (2.9%) Rescue 807,476 15,146 (1.9%) 613,045 (75.9%) 179,285 (22.2%)

4.4 Characteristics of IMFI Ben eficiaries The basic characteristics of the beneficiaries included in the sample are shown in Table 7. The sample size for Al-Fallah, Noble, and Rescue are 50, 52, and 50 respectively. Of these, majority of the beneficiaries interviewed were women (100 percent, 76.9 percent, and 92 percent for Al-Fallah, Noble, and Rescue respectively). Average age of the beneficiaries is around 30 years (28.9, 30.4, and 30.7 for Al-Fallah, Noble, and Rescue respectively). The literacy rate of the beneficiaries of Al-Fallah is the highest (98 percent), followed by Noble (63.5 percent), and Rescue (58 percent). Note that these numbers are much higher than the national average of 38 percent). The average household size for Al-Fallah is 6.3 persons, 2.5 of whom are working. The average number of persons in a household for Noble and Rescue is 5 and 5.1 persons respectively, with 1.3 and 2 of them engaged in work respectively. The average value of assets that beneficiaries have is the highest for Noble (Tk.287,731). It also has the largest standard deviation indicating wide dispersion of the assets. The poorest group, in terms of assets, is that from Al-Fallah (Tk.100,490) followed by Rescue (Tk.179,621). It appears AlFallah is doing a better job in terms of targeting the poorer households.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Table 7 Basic Data of the Beneficiaries of IMFIs Included in the Sample Al-Fallah 50 100% 28.9 (9.7) 98.0% 6.3 (10.3) 2.5 (0.8) 100,490 (213,373) Noble 52 76.9% 30.4 (8.2) 63.5% 5.0 (1.8) 1.3 (0.5) 287,731 (559,618) Rescue 50 92% 30.7 (6.7) 58.0% 5.1 (1.6) 2.0 (0.7) 179,621 (450,576)

Sample Size Female (% of total) Average Age of Beneficiary (years) Literate (% of total) Average Household Size Average of Working Members Average Value of Assets (in Tk.)

Note: The figures in parentheses are standard deviations.

5. PERFORMANCE OF IMFIs: FINDINGS FROM THE FIELD SURVEY We analyze the operations and performance of three IMFIs in this section. In doing so, we highlight how IMFIs perform in dealing with some problems facing conventional MFIs pointed out in Section 2. 5.1 Profitability and Viability of IMFIs The viability of any institution can be analyzed by examining its profitability and efficiency. Table 8 shows the income, expenditures and profitability of the IMFIs included in the study. We distinguish total income from operating income. Whereas total income includes income from all sources (including donations/grants), operating income includes that generated from investments and returns on deposits with banks. We observe that Nob le has the highest share of income from investments (93.2 percent), while the other two IMFIs shares at around 75 percent. With a relatively large amount of deposits, Al-Fallah seems not to have any cash constraints. Large deposits, however, may also indicate limitations in the expansion of operations. On the cost side, most of the expenditures constitute operating costs (wages, rent, utilities, etc.). These range from 63.5 percent for Noble to 95.2 percent for Al-Fallah. Al-Fallah's borrowing costs are, however, the least (4.9 percent). This is due to the smallest net borrowing of Al-Fallah (see Table 5).

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

We define total profit as total income less total expenditures and operating profit as the difference between operating income and costs. Table 8 shows that for all three IMFIs, total profit is positive and greater than operating profit. Except Rescue, the operating profit is positive for the other two IMFIs. To have a clearer picture of these figures and the performance of the IMFIs we use the following ratios to measure profitability and efficiency. 22 1. Return on Assets (ROA) = (Net Income/ Assets)*100 2. Net Interest (Return) Margin (NIM) = [Total income from investment and interest-Total borrowing Cost (interest payments)/ Total Assets]*100 3. Operating Costs as a Percentage of Loan Disbursed (OCL) = (Operating Costs/Loan Disbursed)*100 4. Beneficiaries to Employee Ratio (BER) = Total Beneficiaries/Full-time Employees. ROA is a measure of efficiency as it indicates how well the institution’s assets (resources) are used to generate income. This ratio, however, may be misleading for MFIs if the total income is used since a part of the income of these institutions is in the form of grants. We instead use operating income to obtain the ROA. NIM indicates the efficiency of the intermediation of funds from different sources to users. Another measure of operating efficiency is the OCL. As IMFIs advance small size of loans/funds, this ratio will be larger than conventional banks. Among different MFIs, however, if the field workers are efficient is covering a larger number of beneficiaries, this ratio will be lower. Finally, we use a measure that has relevance to the operations of MFIs in particular. BER is used to measure the efficiency of the employees in reaching the beneficiaries. Note, however, that while a large number of beneficiaries may increase the income per employee, it may also lead to lack of supervision and increase the default rate affecting income adversely. In order to analyze the performance of the IMFIs in proper perspective, we compare financial ratios of the IMFIs with a well-established and largest conventional MFI, Grameen Bank operating in Bangladesh. 23 The large size of Grameen Bank is apparent by the number of its beneficiaries. Grameen Bank served 1,892,287 beneficiaries in 1994. Note that Grameen Bank charges an interest rate of 20 percent while all three IMFIs charge a rate of return of 16 percent. Table 9 exhibits different measures of profitability and efficiency of IMFIs along with Grameen Bank.

22 23

See Rose and Fraser (1988, pp. 199-210) for a discussion. Grameen Bank was chosen as the relevant data was available. Data on Grameen Bank has been taken from Khandker, et al (1995) is for 1994.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Table 8 Income, Expenditure and Profit of IMFIs (Head Office)
Al-Fallah Total income (including Donations/grants) (Tk.) Income from investment (Tk.)(% of Total) Income from Deposits (Tk.) (% of Total) Total Expenditures (Tk.) Borrowing Costs (Tk.) (% of Total) Operating Costs (Tk.) (% of Total) Total Profit (Tk.) Operating Profit (Tk.) 3,347,860 2,491,805 (74.4%) 463,965 (16.1%) 2,419,930 115,810 (4.9%) 2,304,120 (95.2%) 927,930 71,875 Noble 491,623 458,263 (93.2%) 18,941 (3.9%) 286,460 102,558 (35.8%) 183,902 (64.2%) 205,163 171,803 Rescue 807,476 613,045 (75.9%) 15,146 (1.9%) 752,564 93,900 (12.5%) 605,978 (80.5%) 54,912 -139,519

To sum up, IMFIs have performed relatively well when compared to the wellestablished conventional MFI in terms of profitability and efficiency. Among the IMFIs, Rescue has the poorest figures. Rescue, however, has some indicators that are better than Grameen Bank. For example, it has a higher NIM and lower operating costs (OCL) than Grameen Bank. Noble has performed the best among the IMFIs in terms of economic viability. It has the highest ROA and NIM and the lowest OCL. Noble, however, is not productive in terms of reaching the beneficiaries as it has the lowest BER. When this factor is considered, Al-Fallah appears to have the best record in terms of profitability and efficiency. It has a relatively high ROE, NIM, and BER and low OCL. Possible explanations of the relative performance of the IMFIs are given in Section 7. Table 9 Profitability and Efficiency of IMFIs
Al-Fallah Noble Rescue Grameen Bank a Return on Assets (ROA) 0.49 8.89 -3.57 Net Interest (Return) 19.5 21.4 13.7 Margin (NIM) Operating Costs as a percentage 9.6 2.6 11.2 of Loan Disbursed (OCL) Beneficiaries to Employee Ratio 169.8 70.3 132.4 (BER) a. Figures for Grameen Bank are of 1994 and taken from Khandker, et. al. (1995). -0.5 6.9 12.7 174.2

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

5.2 Asymmetric Information Problem As mentioned above, asymmetric information problem may take place before and after a contract is signed causing adverse selection and moral hazard problems respectively. In the context of microfinancing, the former problem may exist if the intended use of fund is different from that applied for. The latter problem arises when funds are used for purposes other than it was sanctioned for. MFIs policy of targeting women as beneficiaries in households where their spouses (or other male members) make the financial decisions is the source of both adverse selection and moral hazard problems. Different problems that originate from this fact are discussed below. a) Intended Use of Funds Contrary to what Applied for: This problem arises when the beneficiary applies for funds indicating use of funds in certain productive enterprise, but hides the intended use of funds which may be for other purposes (including consumption). Adverse selection problem exists, as the MFI does not know the intended use of funds by the beneficiary. When funds are sanctioned and the beneficiary uses the funds in activities other than that applied for, it is a case of moral hazard. In conventional interest-based debt the diversion of funds is possible as cash is handed out to the beneficiary, who can then use it on things other than what it is intended for. In case of Islamic mode of financing used by IMFIs (i.e., bay[ mu’ajjal) this problem cannot arise in principle as instead of handing over cash, the good/asset is handed over to the beneficiary. As a result, diversion of funds to other purposes is not possible. In some cases, however, when cash is given out instead of good/asset the possibility of misuse of funds is there. Table 10 shows if funds were used in the intended activities by the beneficiaries of the three IMFIs. Whereas Al-Fallah and Noble do not appear to have any problems of fund diversi n to non-productive o activities, Rescue has a few cases (12 percent) of fund diversion for consumption. Note that funds can be diverted mainly because cash is handed out instead of good/asset. Cash is often given out (not to the beneficiary directly but to a representative) due to the difficulties the IMFIs face in applying the Islamic mode of financing perfectly (discussed in section 6.1). b) The User of Funds is Different from the Person Obtaining the Funds: The declared objective of many conventional MFIs to finance women is to empower them. In many cases, however, male members of the household initiate or coerce their spouses to apply for funds from MFIs. Once funds are obtained, the male members of the household determine how to use them. The approach of targeting women by conventional MFIs creates the dual problems of adverse selection and moral hazard as discussed above. Here, we focus on the problems related to the user of funds.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Table 10 Fund Use in Intended Activities by Beneficiaries Use of Funds Intended Activity Intended and other productive activities Intended activity and Consumption Consumption Al-Fallah 37 (74%) 1 (2%) Noble 50 (96.2%) Rescue 41 (82%) 3 (6%) 5 (10%) 1 (2%)

In case of IMFIs, we also observe that it is male members of the household who not only decide on the use of funds but also use them. Table 11 illustrates the dominant decision-makers in the household regarding fund use for beneficiaries of the three IMFIs in the study. Whereas in most of the cases of Nob le and Rescue, the spouse (husband) decides how to use funds (55.8 percent and 50 percent respectively), majority of the beneficiaries of Al-Fallah (78 percent) collectively make decisions regarding fund use. One way of determining who uses the funds is to examine who spends most of the time on the funded activity. Table 12 indicates that the spouse (husband) is most involved in the funded activity in majority of the cases. This holds true particularly for the beneficiaries of Al Fallah as a large number of respondents (88 percent) indicate that their spouses use time mostly in the funded activity. The corresponding numbers for Noble and Rescue are around 42 percent. Table 11 Decision of Fund Use by Beneficiaries Household Members
Decisions Regarding Fund Use Self Spouse Together (self and spouse) Other Household Members Al-Fallah 1 (2%) 10 (20%) 39 (78%) Noble 15 (28.8%) 29 (55.8%) 7 (13.5%) 1 (1.9%) Rescue 16 (32%) 25 (50%) 8 (16%) 1 (2%)

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

Table 12 Fund Use by Beneficiaries Household Members Most Time used in Funded Activity* Self Spouse Other Household Members Hired Employees Al-Fallah 1 (2%) 44 (88%) 12 (24%) Noble 18 (34.6%) 22 (42.3%) 4 (7.7%) 4 (7.7%) Rescue 28 (56%) 21 (42%)

* The percentage may add up to more than 100 percent as multiple cases are possible (for example the spouse and other household members may be spending most time in a funded activity).

The above figures from IMFIs, however, do not mean that problems of asymmetric information exist in these institutions. The asymmetric information problem in terms of user of funds disappears in case of IMFIs, as their approach is different from that of the conventional MFIs. As mentioned above, IMFIs’ target is the family. Interviews with officials of all three IMFIs indicate that they know that funds given to women are largely used by the male members of the household. They, however, do not consider this to be a problem. Instead, they encourage participation of other members of the household in the funded activity. The IMFIs also involve the male members in the financial transaction by making them responsible in the contract (by making them sign the contract). As mentioned above, IMFIs deal with women because it is easier to conduct transactions with them. Given this approach of IMFIs, fund-use by a large percentage of male members is rather expected and encouraged and does not pose a moral hazard problem. c) Lack of knowledge about the beneficiary’s skills and expertise: Though MFIs finance mostly low skill activities, in some cases expertise of the beneficiary may be considered important. Skills of the beneficiary in the activity she is applying for may be unknown to the MFI. For example, prospective beneficiaries may apply for funds for use in a productive cottage industry, like weaving baskets. If the beneficiary does not know how to weave, then the default risk increases. Ascertaining the required skills of the beneficiaries before the funds are delivered to them can mitigate this adverse selection problem. Officials of all three IMFIs indicate that they scrutinize the skills and expertise that beneficiaries have before funds are sanctioned.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

5.3 Group Dynamics Forming groups and centers is an integral part of microfinance program as they serve as social collateral and ensure the repayment of funds to the MFIs. Recovery of funds and the success of MFIs depend on the strength and solidarity of the groups. From the MFIs perspective, a group is considered to be carrying out it’s functions when members of a group help/pressurize other fellow members in case of nonpayment of installment(s). Other than the usual social bonds that determine the strength and solidarity of a group, the IMFIs can also use an additional device to strengthen the relationship among group members. The concept of Islamic brotherhood along with religious duty of debt repayment can further improve the relationship of the group members and help clear the installments. The educational content in the Social Development Program is used to impart these ethics. The officials of all three IMFIs affirm that they use group pressure to recover arrears in installment payments. They are also of the view that imparting Islamic teachings makes the beneficiaries better clients. Some other aspects of group dynamics are illustrated in Tables 13-16. Table 13 shows that almost all beneficiaries consult their fellow members regarding use of funds. Table 14 indicates that there are no arrears in payments for Al-Fallah and Noble, and 10 percent beneficiaries have fallen back on payments in case of Rescue. The arrears have occurred due to different negative shocks beyond their control. 24 Table 15 shows that majority of members are willing to help a fellow group member to pay arrears in installments. Table 18 indicates that in majority of cases, joining IMFI has improved the relationship with group members. One reason of this may be the Islamic educational content of the Social Development Program (discussed in the next sub-section). Table 13 Group Dynamics: Consultation about Fund -use by Beneficiaries Cousult Group-members Yes No Al-Fallah 50 (100%) Noble 50 (96.2%) 1 (1.9%) Rescue 49 (98%) 1 (2%)

24

For the five members who are in arrears, the reasons were stated as business failure (1), natural disaster (2), and family and other mishaps (2).

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

Table 14 Group Dynamics: Arrears in Payments by Beneficiaries Arrears in Payments Yes No Al-Fallah 0 50 (100%) Noble 0 52 (100%) Rescue 5* (10%) 45 (90%)

*The reasons of arrears were stated as business failure (1), natural disaster (2), and family and other mishaps (2).

5.4 Impact on Beneficiaries Impact on beneficiaries can be discussed under two broad categories: economic and socio-cultural. The economic impact of the IMFIs’ services is reflected on employment, economic activity, and assets of the beneficiaries’ household. These are shown in Tables 16 and 17. Table 16 reveals that the IMFIs’ funds have been successful in increasing the time spent on income generating activities by the beneficiaries and other members of the household. Al-Fallah appears to have the highest impact on the employment of beneficiaries and their spouses, followed by Rescue. Table 17 shows that funds from the IMFIs have helped the beneficiaries to increase output and diversify productive activities. The impact on output is the largest in case of Noble (53.8 percent) while a large number of beneficiaries of AlFallah have diversified production (36 percent). Majority of the beneficiaries of AlFallah have also increased their asset base and improved their premises (68 percent and 88 percent respectively). The economic impact on beneficiaries of Rescue appears to be relatively small in all respects. Table 15 Group Dynamics: What Beneficiaries do if Others Arrears*
Al-Fallah Help pay (with money) Pressurize Ask spouse/other household members Do Nothing 46 (92%) 0 8 (16%) 0 Noble 34 (65.4%) 0 0 1 (1.9%) Rescue 48 (96%) 1 (2%) 1 (2%) 1 (%)

* The percentage may add up to more than 100 percent, as multiple cases are possible.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Table 16 Economic Impact: IMFI’s Fund’s Effects on Employment of Beneficiaries Increase in Time Used* Self Other Household Members Al-Fallah 30 (60%) 31 (62%) Noble 20 (38.5%) 21 (40.4%) Rescue 25 (50%) 26 (52%)

*The percentage may add up to more than 100 percent, as multiple cases are possible.

Table 17 Economic Impact: IMFI’s Fund Effects on Economic Activity and Assets of Beneficiaries Effect of Fund Increase in Volume of Goods/Services Diversification into new Goods/Services Increase in Assets Improved Premises Al-Fallah 2 (4%) 18 (36%) 34 (68%) 44 (88%) Noble 28 (53.8%) 2 (3.8%) 8 (15.4%) 9 (17.3%) Rescue 5 (10%) 2 (4%) 12 (24%) 14 (28%)

Table 18 examines the social impact of IMFIs through their Social Development Program. Other than the overall view about IMFIs, the dealings related to IMFIs are included in this Table. Majority of beneficiaries indicate that association with IMFIs has not only benefited them financially but also in several other ways. As a result, they have a positive outlook towards the IMFIs. As Table 18 indicates, a large percentage of beneficiaries from all three IMFIs also have better relationship with their spouses and group members. This builds the solidarity within the family unit and group lowering the probability of default. The Islamic education content of the Social Development Program can be an input to this. Beneficiaries also maintain that they have a better understanding of Islam after joining the IMFIs.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

Table 18 Social/Educational Impact on Beneficiaries Al-Fallah 49 (98%) 49 (98%) 49 (98%) 49 (98%) Noble 51 (98%) 52 (100%) 52 (100%) 47 (90.4%) Rescue 48 (96%) 48 (96%) 35* (70%) 50 (100%)

Knowledge of Islam increased Better relationship with Group Members Better relationship with spouse Have benefited (other than financially)

*While 13 members said that the relationship with spouse was the same, one respondent said the relationship worsened.

The officials of the IMFIs inform that beneficiaries and the community at large have a positive outlook towards their activities. The main reason given is that, unlike the conventional MFIs, the Islamic orientation of the Social Development Program conforms to their values. In matters related to financial dealings, beneficiaries admire IMFI practice of not deducting anything from the sanctioned amount as done by conventional MFIs. Beneficiaries also believe that IMFIs have a more humane approach in dealing with arrears than that of conventional MFIs. 6. PROBLEMS FACING IMFI S Interviews with the officials of IMFIs reveal that they face the following problems in their operations. 6.1 Dilution in the Application of Islamic Modes of Financing The main mode of financing used by the IMFIs is bay[ mu’ajjal. To make the transaction Islamically acceptable, the IMFIs should ideally buy the good/asset from the market and sell it to the beneficiary at a mark-up. The officials indicate that during initial stages of their operations, IMFIs have tried to follow this principle. With the expansion of their operations, however, IMFIs have gradually given up this practice. The reasons mentioned are that it is too costly (in terms of man-hours) and at times impossible to buy the goods/assets that beneficiaries want. For example, it becomes very difficult to accompany a beneficiary who may want a particular kind of good sold in a far off market. Instead of giving money to the beneficiary, the IMFIs now delegate someone else to buy the good/asset. 25 The
25

Al-Fallah delegates center chief and a group member to buy the good/asset, Rescue delegates group leader, and Noble asks either the husband or son to do the same.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

officials of IMFIs then inspect if the money was spent on the good/asset during the weekly meeting that follows. It is apparent the Islamic mode of financing is being diluted by not providing the goods/assets. One way to overcome this is to use other profit-sharing modes of financing. The sharing modes of financing, however, have their own problems. 26 The main problem is the moral hazard problem arising from underreporting of profit. This problem can be mitigated by supervising the operations and monitoring accounts of beneficiaries. Supervision and monitoring, however, is costly. As pointed out above, additional obstacles arising in developing countries can further raise the supervision/monitoring costs. Some of the problems that officials of IMFIs indic ate they face in supervision and monitoring are given in Table 19. Officials from all IMFIs indicate difficulty in assessing the financial accounts as one of the main factors that may hinder monitoring. Other factors that also obstruct monitoring include l ck of personnel and equipment (vehicles to go around) and a physical barriers (like distance). Table 19 Problems Faced in Monitoring by IMFIs* Al-Fallah 5 (100%) Noble 4 (100%) 1 (25%) 3 (25%) 3 (75%) Rescue 2 (100%) 2 (100%) 2 (100%) -

Lack of Personnel Physical Barriers Difficult to Assess Financial Flows Other (Lack of Vehicles)

*The number of branches covered under the survey were 5,4, and 2 for Al-Fallah, Noble and Rescue respectively.

6.2 Lack of Funds Officials of all three IMFIs state that expansion of their activities is hampered by lack of funds. The problem of generating funds is inherent in the very nature of these institutions. MFIs cannot attract deposits as commercial banks do. Other than the initial start-up capital provid ed by a few volunteers, most of the funds for conventional MFIs come from external sources and beneficiary savings. Need for funds is the greatest during the initial stages of operations of MFIs when the
26

See Khan (1995) for a discussion.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

beneficiaries’ savings are nil or small. As the MFIs grow, the savings of beneficiaries accumulate. The savings can then be recycled in financing microenterprises. The time needed for an MFI to operate its activities based only on beneficiaries’ savings may be very long. 27 Officials of IMFIs attest that there are certain problems in obtaining funds from external sources. First, the Islamic educational content of IMFIs deters some external sources from funding them. Second, though some funds are available from government agencies, they impose certain terms a conditions. These terms and nd conditions not only limit the flexibility in the operations of IMFIs, but may also be contrary to Islamic principles. For example, the funds are given on interest and the IMFIs are required to get a certain fixed rate of return on their investments to ensure repayment. As a result, certain Islamic modes of financing (like mudarabah and musharakah) cannot be used employing funds received from these sources. One implication of lack of funds is, as the officials of IMFIs indica that the te, benefits package given to employees in IMFIs is not as good as the one given by the established MFIs operating in the neighborhood. This sometimes induces employees with experience to move to other MFIs paying better pay and benefits. Findings from the field survey, however, indicate that IMFIs have not yet tapped the sources of funds from Islamic institutions of zakah, charity, and waqf. The ways in which these instruments can be used have been discussed before (section 4.2). 6.3 Training Efficiency in operations can be improved by giving training on different aspects of MFIs’ operations. Training in case of Islamic MFIs requires some unique features. These include training on different Islamic modes of financing and contents of Social Deve lopment Program. The officials of the IMFIs inform that while training on conventional topics (like accounting and administrative issues) was offered from time to time by the government agencies, training sessions on Islamic aspects are lacking. Association of Muslim Welfare Associations in Bangladesh (AMWAB) organized a few training sessions, but high costs of attending these courses hindered participation of IMFI officials. 7. IMFI S : A SYNTHESIS AND CONCLUSION Microfinance initiative is widely acclaimed as a new approach to alleviate poverty and bring about development. While conventional MFIs have expanded their operations in the last two decades, poverty-focused MFIs based on Islamic
27

Majority of the funds of large well- established conventional MFIs (e.g. Grameen Bank) still comes from external sources.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

principles are yet to be developed. This paper provides the theoretical basis, operational framework, and empirical support for the establishment of Islamic MFIs. The theoretical discussions emphasize on the importance of social financial intermediation to finance microenterprises and a need to develop specialized institutions to do the same. Problems facing conventional MFIs include nongraduation from poverty, debt trap, high dropout rate, asymmetric information and economic viability of the project. Discussions in different sections above have focused on various aspects of IMFIs’ operations. In this section we assemble different elements to arrive at main findings and conclusions. We also attempt to explain some of the findings. The important elements related to IMFIs are summarized below: a) The theoretical part of the p aper shows that there is great potentiality of IMFIs to cater for the needs of the poor. IMFIs are potentially richer, both, on the liability side and the asset side. On the liability side, IMFIs can tap some alternative sources of funds, like zak ah, charity, and waqf. These institutions can be integrated into microfinance program to effectively alleviate absolute poverty. Similarly, IMFIs can use diverse financial instruments. Different Islamic modes of financing may be used for various activities. The case studies, however, show that IMFIs have not yet tapped some sources of funds, nor have they used variety of financial instruments in their operations. b) IMFIs appear to have performed better than Grameen Bank, a wellestablished conventional MFI. One possible explanation for this may be that IMFIs benefit from the social capital derived from Islamic values and principles. On the supply side, the employees have an incentive to work hard for the betterment of the lives of the poor in an Islamic financial inst itution. On the demand side, Islamic teachings increase solidarity among beneficiaries and thereby improve the quality of social collateral (see discussion in Section 5.3 above). Furthermore, the moral teachings of Islam make the beneficiaries better debtors as they consider repayment of debt as a religious obligation. The effect of this Islamic orientation induced social capital is the improvement in the profitability and viability of IMFIs. This occurs because, on the one hand there is an increase in the productivity of employees (i.e. reducing the costs), and on the other hand, it reduces the default rate (i.e., increasing the revenue). c) The Islamic approach of targeting the family and using Islamic modes of financing eliminates to a large extent asymmetric information problems arising in conventional microfinancing. As IMFIs deal with the family (via women), it mitigates the adverse selection and moral hazard problems resulting from the fact that the intended use and user are different from the

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

actual use and user of funds respectively. As Islamic modes of financing involve a real transaction, the moral hazard problem arising from the use of funds for purposes other than those intended is to a large extent eliminated. d) Some IMFIs have performed well rela tive to others in terms of profit. In particular Rescue has performed poorer than its counterparts. One possible explanation of the difference in performance is the dilution in the use of Islamic financial instruments. Giving away cash to the beneficiary i stead n of supplying goods or assets can result in diversion of funds to other uses causing moral hazard problem. This can be a possible explanation for Rescue’s relatively poor performance. Rescue gives cash to the group leader who is responsible to ensure its proper use. Without proper supervision, however, diversion of funds is possible. As Table 10 shows, Rescue has the most cases of diversion of funds resulting in the highest arrears in payment of installments (see Table 14). e) The IMFIs can potentially benefit from varied sources of income and use of financial instruments but they have not yet exploited these means. The institution of zakah, waqf and other charities can be integrated into the program to finance the poorest. The IMFIs surveyed, however, have not yet incorporated other sources of funds available from Islamic institutions in their operations. One way to start doing this is to arrange collection of zakah and other charities locally. Furthermore, other modes of financing (like leasing and profit-loss-sharing) can be employed for certain kind of activities. Other than Noble, the two IMFIs surveyed use bay[ mu’ajjal only. In some cases, like farming and fisheries, funds can be provided under sharing (output or profit) modes. The growth and sustainability of IMFIs largely depend on the availability of external funds and their efficient operations. External funds are needed particularly during the initial stages of operation, when the savings of members are small. With the passage of time as savings of beneficiaries accumulate and get recycled, the dependence on external funds reduces. The IMFIs can operate efficiently if the employees are trained on a regular basis to acquire and upgrade relevant skills. IMFIs have a special need for Islamic oriented training courses. Nascent IMFIs’ lack of funds prevents them from benefiting from costly training courses. Institutions like Islamic Development Bank (IDB) can play an important catalytic role to expand the activities of IMFIs. IDB can provide much-needed external funds to IMFIs on a commercial basis. By providing or financing training courses to the employees of IMFIs, IDB will be essentially increasing their efficiency and indirectly ensuring the return on its investment. Noting that financing microenterprises involves meager amounts of investment, a relatively small amount provided to IMFIs can go a long way in affecting the lives of a large number of poor households in member countries.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

APPENDIX I Organizational Structure of IMFIs

Board of Directors

Executive Director

Manager (Accounts)

General Manager

Manager (Administration)

Branch Manager Branch Manager Branch Manager

Supervisor

Supervisor

Supervisor

Field Worker Field Worker Field Worker

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

REFERENCES Ahmad, Aka Firowz (1998), “The Management System of NGOs Microcredit Program for Poverty Alleviation in Bangladesh”, paper presented at the First International Conference on Islamic Development Management, Penang, December 1998. Ahmad, Ausaf (1993), Contemporary Practice of Islamic Financing Techniques, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank, Research Paper No. 20. Ahmed, Habib (1998), “Microfinance Schemes in Bangladesh: Virtuous Circles or Vicious Cycles?” manuscript. Ahmed, Razia A. (1983), Financing the Rural Poor: Obstacles and Realities, Dhaka: University Press Limited. Assaduzzaman (1997), “Role of Microcredit in Poverty Alleviation”, in Rushidan I. Rahman (ed.), Poverty and Development: Bangladesh Perspective, Dhaka: BIDS, (in Bengali). Basar, Hasmet (ed.) (1987), Management and Development of Awqaf Properties, Research-Seminar-Workshop Proceedings No.1, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank. Bennett, Lynn (1998), “Combining Social and Financial Intermediation to Reach the Poor: The Necessity and the Dangers” in Kimenyi, Mwangi S., Robert C. Wieland, and J.D.V. Pischke (eds), Strategic Issues in Microfinance, Hants, England: Ahsgate Publishing Ltd., pp.99-117. Berger, Allen N. and Gregory F. Udell (1998), “The Economics of Small Business Finance: The Roles of Private Equity and Debt Markets in the Financial Growth Cycle,” Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 22, pp.613-73. Bornstein, David (1996), The Price o a Dream: The Story of Grameen Bank and f the Idea that is Helping the Poor to Change their Lives, Dhaka: University Press. Buckley, Graeme (1996), “Rural and Agricultural Credit in Malawi, A Study of the Malawi Muzdi Fund and the Smallholder Agricultural Credit Administration”, in Hulme, David and Paul Mosley, Finance Against Poverty, London: Routledge, Volume 2, pp. 333-407. Cizakca, Murat (1996), “The Relevance of the Ottoman Cash Waqfs (Awqaf al Nuqud) for Modern Islamic Economics” in M.A. Mannan (ed.), Financing Development is Islam, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank, Seminar Proceedings Series No. 30.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Cizakca, Murat (1998), “Awqaf in History and Implications for Modern Islamic Economics”, paper presented at Intern ational Seminar on Awqaf and Economic Development, Kuala Lumpur. Dichter, Thomas W. (1996), “Questioning the Future of NGOs in Microfinance”, Journal of International Development, No. 8, pp. 256-69. El-Ashker, Ahmed Abdel-Fattah and Muhammad Sirajul Haq (1995), Institutional Framework of Zakah: Dimensions and Implications, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank, Seminar Proceedings No. 23. El-Ghazali, Abdel Hamid (1994), Man is the Basis of the Islamic Strategy for Economic Development, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank, Islamic Economics Translation Series No. 1. Fuglesang, Andreas and Dale Chandler (1993), Participation as Process – Process as Growth: What We can Learn from Grameen Bank, Dhaka: Grameen Trust. Goetz, A. Marie and Rina S. Gupta (1996), “Who Takes the Credit? Gender, Power, and Control over Loan Use in Rural Credit Programmes in Bangladesh”, World Development, No. 24, pp.45-63. Hashemi, Syed M. (1997), "Building up Capacity for Banking with the Poor: The Grameen Bank in Bangladesh," in Schneider, Hartmut (ed.), Microfinance for the Poor, Paris: Development Centre of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD, pp.109-128. Hashemi, Syed M., Sidney R. Schuler, and Ann P. Riley (1996), “Rural Credit Programs and Women’s Empowerment in Bangladesh”, World Development, No. 24, pp. 635-53. Hossain, M. (1983), Credit Programme for the Landless: The Experience of Grameen Bank Project, Dhaka: Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies. Hossain, M. (1984), Credit for the Rural Poor: The Experience of Grameen Bank Project, Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies, Dhaka. Hossain, M. (1987), “Employment Generation Through Cottage IndustriesPotentials and Constraints: The Case of Bangladesh” in Rizwanul Islam (ed.), Rural Industrialisation and Employment in Asia, ILO, New Delhi: Asian Employment Programme. Huppi, M., and Gershon Feder (1990), “The Role of Groups and Credit Cooperatives in Rural Lending”, World Bank Research Observer, No. 5, pp. 187204. Hulme, David and Paul Mosley (1996a), Finance Against Poverty, Volume 1, London: Routledge.

Habib Ahmed: Financing Microenterprises

Hulme, David and Paul Mosley (1996b), Finance Against Poverty, Volume 2, London: Routledge. Kahf, Monzer and Tariqullah Khan (1992), Principles of Islamic Financing, A Survey, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank, Research Paper No. 16. Karim, Md. Rezaul and Mitsue Osada (1998), “Dropping Out: An Emerging Factor in the Success of Microcredit-based Poverty Alleviation Programs”, The Developing Economies, Vol. 36, No. 3, pp. 257-88. Khandker, Shahidur R., Baqui Khalily and Zahed Khan (1995), Grameen Bank: Performance and Sustainability, World Bank Discussion Papers, No.306, Washington DC: The World Bank. Khandkar, Mubina (1998), Women’s Access to Credit and Gender Relations in Bangladesh, Ph. D. Thesis, University of Manchester. Khandker, Shahidur R. (1996), “Grameen Bank: Impact, Costs, and Program Sustainability.” Asian Development Review, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 97-130. Khandker, Shahidur R. and Mark M. Pitt (1998), “The Impact of Group-Based Credit Programs on Poor Households in Bangladesh: Does the Gender of Participants Matter?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106, No. 5, pp. 958996. Kimenyi, Mwangi S., Robert C. Wieland, and J.D.V. Pischke (eds) (1998), Strategic Issues in Microfinance, Hants, England: Ahsgate Publishing Ltd. Mohsin, Mohammad (1995), Economics of Small Business in Islam, Visiting Scholar Research Series No. 2, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/ Islamic Development Bank. Montgomery, Richard (1996), “Disciplining or Protecting the Poor? Avoiding the Social Costs of Peer Pressure in Microcredit Schemes”, Journal of International Development, No.8, pp. 289-305. Morduch, Jonathan (1999), "The Microfinance Promise," Journal of Economic Literature, No. 37, pp. 1569-1614. Moududi, Abul A. (1985), Fatawa al-Zakah, (in Arabic), Jeddah: Center for Research in Islamic Economics, King Abdul Aziz University. Osmani, S.R. (1989), “Limits to the Alleviation of Poverty through Non-Farm Credit,” The Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp.1-19. Otero, Maria and Elisabeth Rhyne (eds), (1994), The New World of Microenterprise Finance, West Hartford, Connecticut: Kumarian Press. Parker, Mushtak (1998), “Credit where credit is really due.” Islamic Banker, Issue No. 33, pp. 8-9.

Islamic Economic Studies, Vol. 9, No. 2

Quardawi, Yusuf (1980), Fiqh al-Zakah (in Arabic), Beirut: Muassasah al-Risalah. Rahman, Aminur (1996), “Microcredit For Women in Rural Bangladesh: Retrenchment of Patriarchal Hegemony as a Consequence”, Chicago Anthropology Exchange, No. 23, pp. 6-22. Rahman, Aminur (1999), “Microcredit Initiatives for Equitable and Sustainable Development: Who Pays?” World Development, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 67-82. Rahman, R.I., and S. R. Khandker (1994), “Role of Targeted Credit Programmes in Promoting Employment and Productivity of the Poor in Bangladesh.” The Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol. 22, Nos. 2 & 3, pp. 49-92. Reed, Larry R. and David R. Befus (1994), “Transformation Lending: Helping Microenterprises Become Small Businesses” in Otero, Maria and Elisabeth Rhyne (eds), The New World of Microenterprise Finance, West Hartford, Connecticut: Kumarian Press, pp.185-204. Schneider, Hartmut (Editor) (1997), Microfinance for the Poor, Paris: Development Centre of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1990), “Peer Monitoring and Credit Market”, World Bank Economic Review, No. 4, pp. 351-66. Yaron, Jacob (1997), "Performance of Development Finance Institutions: How to Access It?" in Schneider, Hartmut (ed.), Microfinance for the Poor, Paris: Development Centre of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD. Yousri, Abdel Rahman Ahmad (1995), Small Industries in Developing Countries: Development and Problems of Financing from Conventional and Islamic Perspectives, (in Arabic), Visiting Scholars Research Series No. 1, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute/Islamic Development Bank. World Bank (1978), Employment and Development of Small Enterprises, Sector Policy Paper, Washington DC: World Bank.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...In the name of Allah, the Most- Merciful, the Very-Merciful Looking for New Steps in Islamic Finance jìÑíá=jìÜ~ãã~Ç=q~èá=rëã~åá Islamic banking industry has grown rapidly during the past three decades spreading its operations in many parts of the globe. Making its first debut in the small Savings Association of Mitghamr (Egypt) in 1963, its strength has now reached over 250 financial institutions operating in more than 40 countries with assets valuing USD 750 billions, and an annual growth rate of 15 per cent. Almost all the giant conventional banks are in queue to establish their Islamic units to capture the new emerging market. This rapid growth of Islamic financial industry is, no doubt, encouraging for those who wished to relieve themselves from the prohibition of interest on the one hand and to remain a part of the modern market economy on the other. Now that a substantial period of more than three decades has passed on the experience of Islamic Banks and Financial Institutions, it is imperative to review what they have achieved so far and what they have missed. It is, no doubt, a great achievement of these institutions that they relieved the Muslims from clear prohibition of riba, and came up with some alternatives that might be adopted in financial market without indulging in interest. In an atmosphere entirely dominated by interest-based transactions, it was really a formidable task. I do not agree with those who criticize them on the basis of utopian idealism, and...

Words: 1576 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...MP A R Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Islamic Inter bank Money Market and a Dual Banking System : The Malaysian Experience Bacha, Obiyathulla I. INCEIF the Global University in Islamic Finance 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/12699/ MPRA Paper No. 12699, posted 13. January 2009 / 09:41 The Islamic Inter bank Money Market and a Dual Banking System: The Malaysian Experience. (1st Draft : June 2007) (1st Revision : September,2007) (This revision: March, 2008) Obiyathulla Ismath Bacha Dept. of Business Administration College of Economics and Management Sciences International Islamic University, Malaysia obiya@iiu.edu.my ………………………………………………………………………………………….. The author gratefully acknowledges Rahmatina Kasri for her research assistance, as well as that of participants of the 2nd International Islamic Financial Markets Conference, Bahrain, for the useful comments Abstract This paper examines the operation of an Islamic Inter-bank Money Market (IIMM), within a dual banking system. The paper argues that even though an Islamic money market operates in an interest-free environment and trades Shariah-compliant instruments, many of the risks associated with conventional money markets, including interest-rate risks are relevant. The empirical evidence, based on Malaysian data, points to Islamic money market profit rates/yields that are highly correlated and move in tandem with conventional money market rates. Given the dynamics of fund flows and...

Words: 7886 - Pages: 32

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...analysis of Mudarabah & a new approach to equity financing in Islamic finance Shaikh, Salman Ahmed International Association of Islamic Banks 01. July 2011 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/19697/ MPRA Paper No. 19697, posted 19. September 2011 / 12:03 A Critical Analysis of Mudarabah & A New Approach to Equity Financing in Islamic Finance Journal of Islamic Banking & Finance, ISSN 1814-8042 By Salman Ahmed Shaikh Project Director, Islamic Economics Project islamiceconomicsproject@gmail.com www.islamiceconomics.viviti.com Abstract Financial intermediation serves a valuable purpose, but it can also be structured using equity modes of financing. This can relieve the financee and increase diversity of entrepreneurial undertakings as in debt based commercial financing, there is little room for diversity with obligatory and stipulated servicing of debt. Using Islamic equity modes of financing poses the challenge of the agency problem and moral hazard. The extent of this agency problem in Mudarabah and its impact on economic payoffs between counterparties is analyzed in this study with a simulation model. Based on review of alternate solutions proposed, the author presents two possible covenants which could make Mudarabah mode of financing more acceptable and widely usable in financial intermediation. This would also further the egalitarian objectives of an Islamic economic order. Keywords: Interest free economy, Islamic Economic System, Mudarabah, Agency Problem, Moral Hazard...

Words: 5078 - Pages: 21

Free Essay

Islamic Finance

...history in Islamic finance that dates back to 1978 when the Islamic Banking System Holdings Limited Luxembourg was established as the first Islamic financial institution in Europe. This was followed by the establishment of Takafol S.A. in 1982, the first Islamic insurance company in Europe. Such history has improved the attractiveness of Luxembourg within Islamic finance industry. There are some recent developments: Since April 2008, the Minister of Finance has set up a task force bringing together key actors of the Islamic finance industry in Luxembourg. Its mission is to look at how Islamic finance can be further developed in Luxembourg. In 2008, the Association of the Luxembourg Funds Industry (ALFI) launched a working group focusing on the development of Luxembourg as a center of excellence for Shariah compliant funds. In early 2009, the Luxembourg Deutsche Bank launched "Al Mi'yar", a Luxembourg domiciled platform which aims at smoothing the issuance of Shariah compliant securities. In 2009, the Central Bank of Luxembourg became a member of the Islamic Financial Services Board (IFSB) and, as such, is the first Central Bank of the European Union to become a member of that institution. In January 2010, the Luxembourg Tax Authority published a circular, the object of which is to clarify the tax treatment of Murabaha and Sukuk transactions and ensure that they benefit from the same tax treatment as conventional financing products. In April 2010, Luxembourg for Finance (LFF) issued...

Words: 1079 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...an Introduction to Islamic Finance = = = jìÑíá=jìÜ~ãã~Ç=q~èá=rëã~åá `çåíÉåíë= Foreword Some Preliminary Points _ÉäáÉÑ=áå=aáîáåÉ=dìáÇ~åÅÉ= qÜÉ=_~ëáÅ=aáÑÑÉêÉåÅÉ=ÄÉíïÉÉå=`~éáí~äáëí=~åÇ=fëä~ãáÅ= bÅçåçãó= ^ëëÉíJÄ~ÅâÉÇ=cáå~åÅáåÖ= `~éáí~ä=~åÇ=båíêÉéêÉåÉìê= mêÉëÉåí=mê~ÅíáÅÉë=çÑ=fëä~ãáÅ=_~åâë= 6 9 V NM NO NQ NR Musharakah qÜÉ=`çåÅÉéí=çÑ=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü= qÜÉ=_~ëáÅ=oìäÉë=çÑ=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü= Distribution of Profit Ratio of Profit Sharing of Loss 17 NV OP 23 24 24 qÜÉ=k~íìêÉ=çÑ=íÜÉ=`~éáí~ä= j~å~ÖÉãÉåí=çÑ=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü= qÉêãáå~íáçå=çÑ=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü= Termination of Musharakah without Closing the Business OR OU OU 29 Mudarabah _ìëáåÉëë=çÑ=íÜÉ=jìÇ~ê~Ä~Ü= aáëíêáÄìíáçå=çÑ=íÜÉ=mêçÑáí= qÉêãáå~íáçå=çÑ=jìÇ~ê~Ä~Ü= `çãÄáå~íáçå=çÑ=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü=~åÇ=jìÇ~ê~Ä~Ü= 31 PO PP PQ PR ÅçåíÉåíë= Musharakah & Mudarabah as Modes of Financing mêçàÉÅí=cáå~åÅáåÖ= Securitization of Musharakah Financing of a Single Transaction Financing of the Working Capital 37 PU 39 42 43 pçãÉ=lÄàÉÅíáçåë=çå=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü=cáå~åÅáåÖ= Risk of Loss Dishonesty Secrecy of the Business Clients’ Unwillingness to Share Profits House Financing on the Basis of Diminishing Musharakah Diminishing Musharakah for Carrying Business of Services Diminishing Musharakah in Trade RO aáãáåáëÜáåÖ=jìëÜ~ê~â~Ü= 52 54 55 56 RT 59 63 63 Murabahah fåíêçÇìÅíáçå= Some Basic Rules of Sale Bai’ Mu’ajjal (Sale on Deferred Payment Basis) 65 SR 66 70 jìê~Ä~Ü~Ü= pçãÉ=fëëìÉë=fåîçäîÉÇ=áå=jìê~Ä~Ü~Ü= Murabahah...

Words: 61209 - Pages: 245

Free Essay

Islamic Finance

...SECTION A: LIST OF SYARIAH COMPLIANCE COMPANY In Malaysia, Kuala Lumpur Stock Exchange Shari’ah Index (KLSESI) was introduced in 1997 by Securities Commission (SC). KLSESI was introducing to provide an avenue for Muslims investors to participate in equity investment in accordance to Shari’ah principle. This index comprised of firms listed on both the Main and the Second Board, and Masdeq at KLSE (Bursa Malaysia). KLSESI is the tool in Islamic capital market (ICM) plan where the activities carried out in that market are not conflict with the conscience of Muslims and religion of Muslim. Besides, the ICM represents an assertion of religious law in capital market transactions where the market should be freed from the involvement of prohibited activities by Islam. Under this index, it focuses on the core activity and level of interest income of company to determine whether a particular company is permissible or not in the index. Before companies listed on KLSE, they should make sure that their investments are permissible under Shari’ah law. The activities are considered impermissible if the operations are based on the interest; involve gambling, manufacture or sale haram products or contains elements of gharar. Furthermore, for companies that compromised both permissible and non-permissible elements, there are several additional criteria. The criteria are: a) The core activities of the companies must not contravene the principles of Shari’ah as outlined in the four criteria...

Words: 1620 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...between Islamic Finance and conventional Finance principles. In order to do this, firstly it is necessary to determine the scope and establish some of the fundemental concepts that define Islamic Finance, or "Sharia compliant banking" as it is often referred to. After this, it will be possible to discuss some of the advantages that Islamic Finance institutions have over the typical conventional banks. As of 2014, Islamic Financial institutions represented around 1% of the total assets throughout the world, with an estimated value of around $2 trillion. There exist in the region of around 300 institutions throughout the world that adopt a financial approach dictated by the principles of Islam. This number has been growing as a result of the financial crash in 2008 where many conventional banks faced liquidity issues; investors disillusioned with the performance and practices of conventional banks increasingly sought to invest their assets with Islamic Finance institutions. However, the fact that only 1% of institutions currently adopts the Islamic Finance approach shows that conventional banking methods are still more popular with investors and institutions alike. Most of the Islamic Finance institutions are based in the Middle East, but there has been a significant increase in Islamic Finance institutions in the main financial centres of this world (London, Shanghai and New York). The following table displays some of the similarities and differences between Islamic and conventional...

Words: 590 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Islamic Finance

...Islamic Banking and Finance To Dr Mohammad Omar Zubair, who is a source of inspiration for all those working in the field of Islamic economics and finance Islamic Banking and Finance New Perspectives on Profit-Sharing and Risk Edited by Munawar Iqbal Islamic Development Bank, Saudi Arabia David T. Llewellyn Loughborough University, UK Edward Elgar Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA In association with: International Association of Islamic Economics Islamic Development Bank The Islamic Foundation © Dr Munawar Iqbal and Professor David T. Llewellyn 2002 (on behalf of the Steering Committee for the Fourth International Conference on Islamic Economics and Banking held at Loughborough University, UK, August 13–15, 2000) All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by Edward Elgar Publishing Limited Glensanda House Montpellier Parade Cheltenham Glos GL50 1UA UK Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc. 136 West Street Suite 202 Northampton Massachusetts 01060 USA A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication Data Islamic Banking and Finance: New Perspectives on Profit-Sharing and Risk / edited by Munawar Iqbal, David T. Llewellyn p. cm. “Some of the papers were presented...

Words: 106697 - Pages: 427

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...1 Muslim Bank enters into Modaraba transaction with five Modarib, workout the transactions on prescribe format on the following terms: ➢ Ali Associates Rs.800,000 MF@10%, Profit 40:60 proceeds Rs.810,000 ➢ Scan Group Rs.700,000 MF@7% Profit 35:65 Expected Proceeds 812,000 ➢ Golden Spot Rs.600,000 MF @8% profit 55:45 Proceeds Rs.770,000 ➢ Karachi Electric Rs.400,000 MF @9% profit 50:50 Proceeds Rs.578,000 ➢ Sailor Services Rs.100,000 @5% Profit 60:40 Proceed 55,000. 2 Muslim Bank enters into Modaraba transaction with five Modarib, workout the transactions on prescribe format on the following terms: ➢ Ali Associates Rs.100,000 MF@7%, Profit 40:60 proceeds Rs.210,000 ➢ Scan Group Rs.200,000 MF@8% Profit 35:65 Expected Proceeds 312,000 ➢ Golden Spot Rs.300,000 MF @9% profit 55:45 Proceeds Rs.470,000 ➢ Karachi Electric Rs.400,000 MF @10% profit 50:50 Proceeds Rs.578,000 ➢ Sailor Services Rs.500,000 @5% Profit 60:40 Proceed 455,000. 3 Muslim Bank enters into Modaraba transaction with five Modarib, workout the transactions on prescribe format on the following terms: ➢ Ali Associates Rs.20,000 MF@7%, Profit 40:60 proceeds Rs.40,000 ➢ Scan Group Rs.70,000 MF@9% Profit 35:65 Expected Proceeds 92,000 ➢ Golden Spot Rs.50,000 MF @6% profit 55:45 Proceeds Rs.70,000 ➢ Karachi Electric Rs.90,000 MF @10% profit 50:50 Proceeds Rs.12000,000 ➢ Sailor Services Rs.40,000 @5.5% Profit 60:40 Proceed 35,000. 4 Skyline Services is holding 1 million shares of...

Words: 1053 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance: a Summary

...Islamic finance A brief summary ------------------------------------------------- Islamic Finance One of the most innovative trends in our Islamic world is our Islamic banking system. This industry is growing in manner that lead most of the large conventional banks like J.P.Morgan and MorganStanly to open divisions concerned with Islamic finance products. According to Middle East newspaper, Middle-East Newspaper (30/05/2008) there are around 300 Islamic banks around the world ,130 of them are in GCC countries. Global Trader (19/07/2011) This industry has grown from $ 150 million in 1990, to around $ 1 trillion. Moreover, Islamic banking sectors currently holding more than $ 1.3 trillion in Assets. ABNA (31/03/2012) Most of those assets are located in Malaysia, Saudi Arabia, Iran and Sudan. banking operations are based on three fundamental Principles: * Prohibition of Riba * Prohibition of Gharar * Principles of Islamic Share'a This chapter would insight more on these three philosophy and going to explain each them in details. ------------------------------------------------- Riba Riba can be defined as “any Contractual increase above what is required”. It can be divided into two main points: 1. Ribba Al Nassiah: Riba that is related to Time ( e.g. If you did not pay on time there will be an penalty to pay with the debt) 2. Ribba Al Fadhel: which is related to unequally exchange of commodities that was mention by the prophet...

Words: 428 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Islamic Finance

...Case Study: National Bank of Kuwait - Islamic Global Real Estate Securities Fund – Class A Objective The objective of the Fund is to provide its shareholders with long-term growth through investing in a diversified portfolio of global real estate securities. The fund offers two Portfolios: - Class A Portfolio: The Class A Portfolio of the Fund will invest substantially all of its assets in the Class A Portfolio of the Wafra-Pramerica Fund. Class A Portfolio of the Wafra-Pramerica Fund may incur Portfolio Leverage on a Shariah compliant basis. Such Portfolio Leverage would be in addition to any Property Leverage affecting the entities in which the Wafra-Pramerica Fund invests. The two portfolios of the Wafra-Pramerica Fund will seek to make investments in a diversified portfolio of real estate securities in compliance with the Shariah Criteria. Real estate securities include securities of real estate investment, development and operating companies, including real estate investment trusts, and the securities of companies providing management and investment advisory services to real estate investment, development and operating companies. Fund Features • Well diversified Global Real Estate Securities • Monthly liquidity • Two different Classes of Shares • All Investments are in accordance with the Islamic Shariah Principles Task: Reference to the documents available in NBK website about Islamic Global Real Estate Securities Fund – Class A, answer 3 of the...

Words: 419 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Islamic Banking and Finance

...Islamic Modes of Finance Theory and Key Shariah Principles Modes Of Finance • Two are ideal modes which provide an alternative to interest banking and if implemented on a national level will result in much fairer distribution of wealth in society 1. Mushaarakah – ‫رآ‬ (equity finance) 2. Mudhaarabah - ‫ر‬ (equity finance - sleeping partner) • Two are not ideal as they replicate the effects of conventional banking but nevertheless are tolerated in Shariah 3. Ijaarah - ‫( إ رة‬leasing) 4. Muraabahah - ‫( ا‬cost plus pricing) We will also briefly analyse Salam - , Istisnaa‘ – ‫ع‬ Tawarruq – ‫رق‬ ‫ ا‬and 1 Mushaarakah • “Mushaarakah” literally means sharing • “Mushaarakah” is derived from “shirkah” which means “being a partner”. • Mushaarakah is “a joint enterprises formed for conducting business in which all partners share the profit according to an agreed ratio while the loss is shared according to the ratio of investment” • It is an ideal alternative for interest based financing with far reaching effects on the economy. Types of Shirkah SHIRKAH SHIRKAT-UL-MILK joint ownership SHIRKAT-UL-‘AQD joint enterprise OPTIONAL via joint purchase NON OPTIONAL inheritance SHIRKATUL-AMWAAL SHIRKATUL-‘AMAL SHIRKATUL-WUJOOH mushaarakah Mushaarakah • The term Mushaarakah has been introduced recently by those who have written on the subject of Islamic modes of financing • It is normally restricted to a particular type of “Shirkah”, i.e. Shirkat-ul-amwaal...

Words: 2768 - Pages: 12

Free Essay

Islamic Finance in Bangladesh

...Bangladesh is the first country in the Southeast Asia to have an Islamic bank. The idea to have an Islamic banking system is recommended by Organisation of the Islamic Conference (OIC) in 1978. The founder of this successful establishment is late Fouad Abdul Hameed Al-Khateeb. He is the Saudi Arabia’s first ambassador stationed at Bangladesh from 1977- 1982. He also organized a team with other scholars to start a project to establish Islamic bank and financial institutions based on shariah. In 1983, Islami Bank Bangladesh Limited (IBBL) was established and followed by the others such as Al-Arafah Islami Bank and Shahjalal Islami Bank Ltd. However, to trigger the effort that can make this idea come true is not easy. Bangladesh is also facing the challenges regarding the problem that comes through this phenomenon in this Islamic world. First of all, the modes of investments like Mudarabah and Musharakah are not really practices in Islamic banking services. It is because there are insufficient factors such as committed entrepreneur and committed professional who can create new instruments. Furthermore, the absence of Islamic money market have made banks cannot invest their surplus fund so their profit will be affected. The ability of Islamic bank in Bangladesh to use tradable financial instrument is also not clear because the absence of suitable long term assets. The progression of Islamic finance in Bangladesh has growth in positive value in last few decades. It is because...

Words: 319 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Case Study of Islamic Finance

...F ing nk e Introduction to Islamic Capital Market P. 32 Islamic Wealth Management Opportunities Review Part II: GCC P. 28 GIF Magazine Special Report: Takaful in 2010 and Beyond P. 23 gif Interview Interview with Dr. Alberto Brugnoni: “Islamic Finance is not the exception, but the rule of normal financial behaviour” . Dr. Alberto Brugnoni is an international consultant in Islamic finance and ethics and is Founder and Director General of AASAIF, an organisation that participates in some of the most important international initiatives in Islamic finance. Dr. Brugnoni acted as Chair for the recent International Takaful Summit 2010 in London and moderated the session entitled “Enabling and Expanding the Scope of Takaful”. Here, Dr. Brugnoni speaks with Global Islamic Finance Magazine about why the Summit was such a big success, his work with Islamic microfinance, and the state of the Islamic finance industry in Europe. How did you find the International Takaful Summit? It was a great success for two reasons. 1) It was very well attended, with more than 450 delegates signing in. 2) We had institutional support. Nick Anstee, the Lord Mayor of London attended the opening session and spoke, as well as sitting in on several sessions. We also had dinner in the House of Lords at the invitation of Lord Mohamed Sheikh, which added credibility to the event. It was nice weather, nice atmosphere: It was 38 Global Islamic Finance September 2010 not just a formal...

Words: 1698 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Potential of Islamic Finance in Africa

...The potential of Islamic infrastructure finance in Africa Summary: Lack of funding for infrastructure has been identified as one of the key hurdles hindering African infrastructure development. Africa ranks on the bottom of developing regions in access to infrastructure services and the continent’s total infrastructure financing needs amounts to a staggering circa. USD 93 billion per year until 2020 (Africa Infrastructure Country Diagnostic, 2009). Five years have since lapsed since these estimates were published and the gap continues to widen. Islamic financial institutions that offer Islamic financial products are required by Sharia Law to establish a Shariah Supervisory Board made of Islamic jurists known as fuqha.  Over the years, Islamic finance has become an important source of capital for large infrastructure projects. It is estimated that global Islamic assets stood at USD1.6 trillion as of December 2011 (Islamic Development Bank, 2011). In order to attract Islamic Infrastructure funds, a financier is obliged to find ways of overcoming challenges associated with Islamic Finance through innovation (McMillen, 2011).  Sharia law prohibits Islamic financial institutions from leveraging their balance sheets through the use of debt for liquidity purposes. Islamic banks use retail banking deposits from devoted Muslims and tend to avoid the bond markets. High risks associated with Islamic financing and infrastructure finance makes Islamic financing uncompetitive...

Words: 630 - Pages: 3