Free Essay

The Causes of Busniness Cycles

In:

Submitted By adrianmusss
Words 11051
Pages 45
THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES: AN ESSAY IN ECONOMIC HISTORIOGRAPHY
Peter Temin*

This paper surveys American business cycles over the past century. Its task is to identify the causes of these cycles; other papers in this collection address the nature of policy responses to these causes. This paper can be seen as a test to discriminate between two views of the American economy. The first is expressed in a characteristically vivid statement by Dornbusch, who proclaimed recently: “None of the U.S. expansions of the past 40 years died in bed of old age; every one was murdered by the Federal Reserve” (Dornbusch 1997). This stark view can be contrasted with its opposite in the recent literature: “[N]one of the popular candidates for observable shocks robustly accounts for the bulk of business-cycle fluctuations in output” (Cochrane 1994, p. 358). I expand the time period to consider the past century, but it is easy to distinguish the past 40 years, that is, the period since World War II. A survey of business cycle causes over an entire century runs into several problems, of which three seem noteworthy. First, it is not at all clear what “cause” means in this context. Second, the Great Depression was such a large cycle that it cannot be seen as just another data point. Third, the survey relies on the existing literature on business cycles, which is why I have entitled it an essay in economic historiography. The paper proceeds by discussing each of these problems in turn, then turning to the data, and finally drawing some conclusions from the preceding efforts.

*Elisha Gray II Professor of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The author would like to thank Caroline Richards for research assistance. All errors remain the author’s alone.

38

Peter Temin

BUSINESS CYCLES: DEFINITION

AND

ANALYSIS

The cause of a business cycle typically is taken to be a shock or innovation to a relationship in the economy. Myriad relationships operate in a complex economy like ours, and some way needs to be found to impose order on the analysis of shocks. Order typically is imposed by abstracting from the actual economy to an abstract model. A more operational definition of cause, therefore, is a shock to a relationship in a macroeconomic model. It follows that shocks may be specific to models, which differ both in their level of detail and in their basic assumptions. With differing levels of inclusiveness, one person’s shock may be another’s movement of an endogenous variable. Government actions are a case in point. Variation in government purchasing is taken to be exogenous in many economic models, and it is eligible as a business cycle cause in these models. But the growth of political economy has led people to endogenize government actions. Only deviations from the rule then would be admissible as a shock. Brown (1956) long ago looked for Keynesian stimuli during the Great Depression. He sanitized government spending to eliminate automatic stabilizers, that is, variations due to the state of the economy, to find the high-employment surplus. Keynesian stimuli then were changes in his calculated budget, not the actual budget. As Brown recognized half a century ago, the stimulus— or shock—was specific to the specification of the normal budgetary rule, that is, to the correction used. Actions by the Federal Reserve fall into the same category. The Fed tries to respond to economic conditions. Are Fed actions endogenous or exogenous? Various authors have tried to endogenize the Fed. Wheelock (1991) and Toma (1997) have modeled the Fed in the interwar period. Taylor and others have proposed monetary policy rules to analyze Fed behavior since the Second World War (Taylor 1993a, 1993b). A typical policy rule indicates that the Fed raises interest rates when inflation rises and when the economy is operating above its trend level. Such Fed actions would be considered endogenous in a model that treated the Fed symmetrically with Brown’s treatment of the budget. An example may make this distinction clear. OPEC countries raised the price of oil sharply following the Yom Kippur War in the fall of 1973. Prices began to rise in the United States as a result, and the Fed sharply restricted monetary growth. A recession followed that Paul Samuelson quipped had “Made in Washington” stamped on its bottom. Was the recession “caused” by the oil shock or by monetary policy? The answer to this question depends on the model. If we are using a model that regards Fed actions as exogenous (perhaps because we are searching for policies that can insulate the American economy from external shocks), then the Fed is the appropriate cause. If we are instead using a model that endogenizes the Fed (looking for sources of instability

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

39

in the U.S. or world economy), then the oil shock is the obvious candidate. Causes, in other words, do not have independent existences. They are functions of the models being used and the questions being asked. They are exogenous events whose identification is endogenous to intellectual inquiry. Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1998) survey monetary shocks. They are interested in the response of the economy to exogenous shocks. But they recognize that the very identification of these shocks is specific to the model being used. They survey, for example, the narrative approach used by Romer and Romer (1989) to identify exogenous shocks coming from the Fed. Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans argue that even these shocks are specific to the implicit model underlying Romer and Romer’s narrative. This ambiguity is present within any class of similar economic models, but further ambiguities come from the variety of theories that support macro models. Real business cycle theories find technology shocks to be the source of fluctuations. Demand shocks like Fed actions and oil price rises do not figure in these models. Technology shocks, however defined, are the underlying causes of fluctuations in income. If one is agnostic about which model is most accurate and useful, then the very idea of cause is ill-defined. Cochrane (1994) started from this unstructured position, employing a sequence of progressively more tightly specified VARs to indicate what kinds of shocks cause business cycles. He concluded that technology shocks were not an important source of variation in output. This is less ideological than it seems; as noted above, Cochrane concluded that no single class of exogenous shock—from either supply or demand—was the main source of business cycles. If time-series analysis shows variety rather than uniformity of shocks, another approach may be more useful. I propose here to use a historical account. I examine American business cycles over the last century to inquire into their causes. Because this paper will be followed by others on policies, I interpret “cause” to mean the shock that initiates a downturn, trying to identify the source of instability rather than policy responses that may have aggravated the contraction. The Federal Reserve and the national government are endogenous. This view is consistent with Dornbusch’s implicit framework, since murder is a willful deviation from normal behavior. In the 1970s, the oil shock is the identified villain, not the Fed. This approach differs from that of Romer and Romer (1989). They looked for monetary shocks in the postwar period, “to identify episodes when there were large shifts in monetary policy or in the behavior of the monetary sector that were not driven by developments on the real side of the economy” (p. 122). But they implemented this search by looking for “times when concern about the current level of inflation led the Federal

40

Peter Temin

Table 1

A Two-by-Two Classification of the Causes of Business Cycles
Domestic Real Monetary
Source: See the text.

Foreign FR FM

DR DM

Reserve to attempt to induce a recession” (p. 134). The problem with their approach, for my paper, is whether a monetary contraction in response to inflation is a shift in policy or simply policy itself. I interpret most actions by the Fed to reduce inflation as the job of the Fed and therefore endogenous. The Fed’s response to the first oil shock in 1973 did not represent a break with previous Fed policy. I therefore classify the Fed’s contractionary actions as endogenous and attribute the recession to the oil price shock. I work with an elementary open-economy model: an augmented IS-LM model or Mundell-Fleming model. The model distinguishes domestic and foreign shocks as well as real and monetary shocks. The model recognizes demand shocks far more easily than supply shocks, which appear as shifts in the aggregate supply curve and are classified as real shocks. This level of abstraction and general orientation of underlying assumptions about the economy is typical of the historical literature on business cycles in the United States. This simple two-by-two classification is shown in Table 1. Mention of the Fed brings up the second problem that must be cleared away. The Great Depression was the largest contraction in our history. It dwarfs all other contractions in the past century. Output lost in the Depression was almost one-half of the sum of output lost in all downturns during the past century (Romer 1994, p. 604). If one is interested in minimizing losses from forgone income, it may make more sense to explain the Great Depression than to worry about other, smaller fluctuations in output. Policies that avoid similar catastrophes may be more important than policies that fine-tune the economy. The literature on the Great Depression also is larger than the literature on all other business cycles combined. The Great Depression has stood as a challenge to economists since the severity of the Depression became clear. Keynes (1936) was an important response to this challenge, but not the only one. Generations of macroeconomists have attempted to incorporate this massive fluctuation into their theories. Only recently, as prosperity appears more and more permanent, has explaining the Depression become part of history rather than economics. Historians, however, distrust current visions of a New Era that are so reminiscent of

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

41

the 1920s—pride goes before a fall. We cannot afford to ignore or belittle the Great Depression. This paper is concerned with shocks. Was the Great Depression due to a larger shock than all others? Was the economy simply unlucky in the 1930s? Should we be keeping our eyes open for similar dreadful shocks in the future? I have argued that the shock that produced the Great Depression was the First World War (Temin 1989). It surely is good advice to avoid world wars—and not just for the economic consequences of the subsequent peace. But the story is not so simple. The Second World War was an even bigger shock to the world economy than the First. This can be seen easily by comparing the maximum share of national output devoted to the war effort in the two wars. The United States devoted 45 percent of its output to the war effort at the high point of expenditures in World War II, compared to only 13 percent at the similar point in World War I. For Britain, the maximum shares of output in the two wars were 57 percent in World War II and 38 percent in World War I. For Germany, the country most heavily involved in both wars, the comparable numbers are 76 percent and 53 percent. In addition to devoting a great share of production to war in the second global conflict, these countries also maintained high war expenditures longer (Feinstein, Temin, and Toniolo 1997, p. 189). Yet the larger shock of World War II was not followed by the same economic strains as the interwar period. Economic (and political) policies were very different in the aftermath of the two world wars. The United Nations, the International Monetary Fund, and the World Bank were all planned while the second great war was still going on. It became apparent by 1947 that even these new institutions were not going to be sufficient to guarantee economic—and therefore political—stability in Europe. President Truman, in one of the great actions of an international leader in our century, then extended aid to Europe in the form of the Marshall Plan. The First World War followed the economically tranquil Victorian and Edwardian periods; there was no expectation and no preparation for the forces unleashed by the war. The Second World War, by contrast, followed the Russian Revolution, the Great Depression, and the Nazi domination of Europe. Policymakers had ample warning—if they cared to learn from history—that the world economy would not heal itself from the injury of the war quickly or smoothly without help. Current thought attributes the Great Depression to the inability of interwar policymakers to deal with the shock of the First World War. Their solution to the immediate postwar chaos represented by hyperinflations in Eastern Europe was to revive the gold standard. But this solution froze the major industrial economies into insupportable positions and allowed little flexibility to deal with strain. The inability of policymakers to abandon the gold standard then produced the Great Depression (Temin 1989; Eichengreen 1992; Bernanke 1995).

42

Peter Temin

Sins of omission can be just as harmful as sins of commission, but they are not exogenous shocks. Of course, if a behavioral equation predicts a change in policy that did not take place, then one can attribute the inaction to a negative shock to this relation. But the Depression was marked by governments and central banks acting in character, doing what they had been doing before even though conditions had changed. Historians of the Fed have been more struck by the consistency of its policies during the slide into the Great Depression than by its innovations. Wheelock (1991, p. 115) concluded, for example, “[I]f member-bank borrowing was low, as it was in the early 1930s, the Fed bought few securities because it appeared that the proximate objective of purchase— monetary ease— had already been achieved. The Fed seems to have employed this strategy consistently from 1924 to 1933.” In keeping with the resolution to the first problem described above, I focus on the shocks that precipitated the contraction in the early 1930s. We need to remember that these shocks only had the effects attributed to them because of the context in which they came. Context here means both the strains on the international economy that derived from the world war and the policy rules that dictated national policies in the United States and other countries. These factors are critical to an understanding of the Great Depression, but they are put to one side here. There is an additional complication. It is hard to think that a single shock in the late 1920s, however large, could have plunged the United States and the world into the Great Depression. In addition, economists and historians have been unable to find a shock in the late 1920s that seems to be anywhere near large enough to have had this effect, even in the interwar context that magnified the effects of economic shocks. This corresponds with our understanding of the economy. A century or more of evidence shows that the economy generally functions at close to full employment. The combinations of shocks and policies that characterize the economy keep productive resources generally employed. It follows that a single shock, even in the unfavorable interwar environment, was unlikely to have led to the Great Depression. Friedman and Schwartz (1963) distinguished two stages in the Great Depression, and writers since then have followed their lead. Perhaps two shocks occurred that together knocked the economy out of this normal equilibrium. I recall studying a model of this sort by James Duesenberry when I was a graduate student and just before he became Chairman of the Board of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. He started from a simple accelerator-type model where both output and capital were functions of the previous year’s output and capital. The rate of growth of income in such a model depends linearly on the capital-output ratio, while the rate of growth of capital is a hyperbolic function of the same ratio. It follows that the two relations intersect twice or not at all. If twice, then the intersection at the higher rate of growth (and lower capital-output ratio)

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

43

is stable, and the intersection at a lower rate of growth is unstable. A small shock lands the economy between the two equilibria, returning it to the high-growth point. Multiple shocks— or a single larger shock— could push the economy below the lower equilibrium. In that case, the economy would continue to decline and not return quickly to its high-growth equilibrium (Duesenberry 1958, pp. 203– 8). Just such a framework appears to fit the need here, brought up to date with appropriate bells and whistles. As just noted, no spectacular shock occurred in the late 1920s to drive the economy far from its high-growth, near-full-employment equilibrium. Instead, there was a sequence of shocks that drove the economy ever further from this equilibrium. The Great Depression should be thought of as a sequence of two (or more) recessions coming on top of one another. A recession starting in 1931 contracted the economy from its already depressed state. It required only the addition of a breakdown of the banking and legal systems, as described in Bernanke (1983) and Field (1992), to make the sequence of recessions large and durable enough to add up to the Great Depression. The general literature on business cycles has made great strides since Duesenberry wrote his book. Progress may be seen in myriad journal articles and in any macro text where various mechanisms that might lead to recessions are described. Theoretical arguments are tested for fluctuations in general by sophisticated time-series techniques which generally confirm their validity. This literature, however, shies away from discussion of any specific business cycle. The accompanying text often refers to a recession or two, but as illustration rather than as the subject of careful analysis. The causes of interest here show up as errors, shocks, and innovations in these abstract models. In Cochrane’s (1994) analysis, for example, it is hard to discover even what period the data are from. It is possible to map statistical errors into historical events (Temin 1969, 1976). But one can do this exercise only relative to a specific model. Different models clearly give different residuals. If the goal is to find events that can be represented by the residuals, it may be possible to find events to explain one set of residuals as easily as another. But the variety of models extant today makes that kind of exercise unrealistic as a way to identify causes for multiple cycles. As a result of the focus on general explanations, the literature on specific cycles is surprisingly sparse. Only occasionally do economists turn their attention to the explanation of a single downturn. The literature on earlier recessions, not surprisingly, is even more sketchy than the literature on recent ones. An inquiry that looks for specific shocks therefore is condemned to mine a narrow seam of literature. This raises the third problem mentioned at the start: This essay draws on the existing literature, with all of its shortcomings. For example, it is no accident that Friedman and Schwartz (1963) found monetary causes to be important.

44

Peter Temin

Similarly, R.A. Gordon (1961) found real causes to dominate. This turns out not to be a problem because most authors, including these, focused on the transmission of cycles, the endogenous factors that turned shocks into cycles, rather than the exogenous shocks themselves. The more serious problem is the short shrift often given to the shocks. Another characteristic of the narrative literature is its age. Almost all of it, including the sources I have just cited, was written before rational expectations became central to macroeconomics and before technology shocks were recognized as possibilities. The narratives do not highlight expectations, and they generally do not distinguish between anticipated and unanticipated changes in any careful way. That is not to say the historical authors were innocent babes in the woods. They were sophisticated observers, and they were aware of the various influences that have been modeled in the past two or three decades. But without a formal model, these authors were imprecise in their identification of shocks to the American economy. The lack of attention in the recent economics literature to specific business cycles is curious. It could reflect the difficulty of assigning causes to any single cycle. Economists differ on such large downturns as the Great Depression and smaller ones like 1990. But controversy generally has encouraged contributions, not discouraged them. The lack may be a reflection of disinterest in history among economists. In this case, only the latest recession is of interest, and only for a short while. With the exception of macroeconomic texts which need illustrations, this hypothesis is consistent with the observations. The lack also may be a reflection of economic methodology in which general structures are more important than individual events. This methodological bias of course supports the ideological stance of the previous hypothesis. I do not aim to disentangle this knot. I only want to set the stage for my historiographic exercise. Given the scarcity of sources, however, I could not resist speculating on the source of this scantiness.

BUSINESS CYCLES

OF THE

PAST CENTURY

The first task in collecting data is to define the population to be studied. I use Romer’s (1994) dates for business cycles. She dated cycles by the previous peak and utilized a consistent algorithm to find cycles in industrial production before and after World War II. The algorithm has two steps. First, cumulate “lost” industrial production between a peak and the subsequent attainment of this peak level of production, where lost production is the difference between the actual production in any month and the previous peak level. Second, classify periods where the cumulative loss exceeds 0.421 as recessions. This filter is designed to omit minor fluctuations in output; the cutoff value is the loss in the smallest

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

45

postwar NBER reference cycle. Like Romer, I focus on the contractionary phase of cycles. I restrict the sample further to include only the century 1890 to 1990, albeit including the recession of 1990. I also decompose the Great Depression into two recessions, in 1929 and 1931, respectively. I distribute the cumulative loss of output during the Great Depression between them as one-third and two-thirds. This division shows that the recession of 1929 would have been the deepest of the century even without the following economic collapse. But the bulk of the loss is attributed to the Great Depression itself. There were eight cycles in each of three periods—1890 to World War I, from then to the end of World War II, and from then to 1990 —with one more in 1990. The four largest cycles were all in the middle period, in the interwar years. In other words, even without the Great Depression, the cumulative loss in production was far higher between the world wars than in comparable years either before or after. Business cycles clearly did not vanish after World War II, but they were less frequent than before World War I. The three periods have the same number of cycles despite their varying length. I searched the economic history literature for discussions of these cycles. Only a few sources were found, since individual cycles generally have not been a concern of economic historians or economists generally—as noted above. The Great Depression of course is a notable exception to this general pattern. The causes of cycles then were classified in the simple two-by-two matrix shown in Table 1: domestic or foreign, real or monetary. Table 2 shows the causes listed in the literature for each cycle of the past century except 1916, the second smallest downturn, for which no sources could be found. Also listed in Table 2 are the losses of industrial production (in months of production) from Romer (1994, Table 7) to show the relative sizes of the different cycles. I was able to select a single dominant cause for all the cycles except one (1981). Given the diversity of causes represented in Table 2, adding subsidiary causes for individual cycles only reinforces the conclusion that shocks are diverse. I classify shocks by the loss of output in the subsequent recession, but I do not want to suggest that there was a tight correspondence between the size of the shock and the size of the subsequent economic decline. Some economic institutions and policies transmitted and even augmented shocks more than others. But that is not the topic of this essay. I therefore ignore the transmission of economic shocks and focus only on their origins. Consider first the differences between the columns of Table 2. There is a preponderance of domestic causes. Cycles in the interwar period were mainly domestic, although the largest (1931) was international. Weighted by number of cycles, the interwar period was insulated from

46

Peter Temin

Table 2

Causes of Business Cycles in the United States
Peak 1893 1896 1900 1903 1907 1910 1914 1918 1920 1923 1927 1929 1931 1937 1939 1948 1953 1957 1960 1969 1973 1980 1981 1990 Production Loss (months) 2.60 1.36 .80 1.16 3.04 1.53 .75 .71 6.64 1.89 .68 10.40 20.78 5.79 .65 1.17 1.20 1.39 .92 .99 2.47 .42 1.68 .93 Domestic Real Foreign Real Domestic Monetary ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Foreign Monetary

● ● ●



● ● ● ● ● ● ● ●

● ●







Source: See the text and Table 1. Production loss taken from Romer (1994). The loss is the cumulative reduction during a recession in the level of industrial production from its peak value, between the peak and the subsequent attainment of this peak level of production.

the world. Weighted by lost production, the interwar period was more vulnerable to international shocks than the years either before or after the wars. Consider now the rows of Table 2. There are roughly the same number of real and monetary causes, slightly more real. My convention has been to regard a change in the price of real assets, whether oil or equities, as real. Another classification might yield somewhat different results, but I doubt if the conclusion of a roughly equal number of monetary and real shocks would change. The trend is toward real causes, particularly if the period before the First World War is compared with the period after the Second. To go beyond these general conclusions requires a deeper level of analysis. I turn to the literature on individual cycles. They are discussed in order of their size, to give the largest cycles pride of place. Not

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

47

surprisingly, the largest cycles also have been the subject of the most sustained inquiry, and it is possible to say more about them than about cycles at random. The Four Largest Cycles The largest cycle by far in Table 2 is 1931, the downturn that started in the midst of an already depressed economy. This cycle, it should be recalled, is not derived from Romer’s (1994) algorithm. Her cycles are dated from the previous peak. This cycle acquired much of its power from coming on top of an earlier contraction. In her classification, this “cycle” is the second part of the cycle beginning in 1929, a true peak of economic activity. The negative shock explains how a recession was turned into a depression. This shock may well have been the most potent single shock of the last century—measured by its effects as transmitted through endogenous policies—and it deserves to be classified as its own cycle. The contraction starting in 1931 has been laid squarely at the door of the Fed. Friedman and Schwartz argued forcefully for this position 35 years ago. In their dramatic words: “On October 9, the Reserve Bank of New York raised its rediscount rate to 21⁄2 per cent and on October 16, to 31⁄2 per cent—the sharpest rise within so brief a period in the whole history of the System, before or since” (Friedman and Schwartz, 1963, p. 317). This sharp rise followed a gradual decline in the discount rate from its peak of 6 percent in 1929 to its low of 1.5 percent in April 1931. The Fed’s actions then more than doubled the discount rate in two weeks— like raising the discount rate today by 5 or 6 percentage points. This should be contrasted with stock market jitters today on the rumor of a possible one-quarter percentage point rise. Friedman and Schwartz continued that the Fed’s action “intensified internal financial difficulties and was accompanied by a spectacular increase in bank failures and runs on banks.” Friedman and Schwartz characteristically did not say that the Federal Reserve’s action caused the bank failures and runs on banks, only that the Fed’s action “was accompanied by a spectacular increase in bank failures and runs on banks.” We, however, can bite the bullet and say what Friedman and Schwartz presumably intended and have been quoted for over 30 years as saying, namely, the Fed’s dramatic increase in the discount rate sent the already depressed economy into a tailspin. For Friedman and Schwartz and for countless others, it was the Fed’s mistaken policy that was the cause of the Great Depression. As explained above, the model within which shocks are defined in this paper includes an endogenous Federal Reserve. Only if the Fed acted out of character, or failed to act when it normally would have, can Fed action or inaction be classified as a shock to the economy. In this case, the

48

Peter Temin

Fed was acting in character. The problem was that the Fed acted totally traditionally and predictably under stress, not that it deviated from any existing norm. Friedman and Schwartz also noted, “The Fed reacted vigorously and promptly to the external drain, as it had not to the previous internal drain” (p. 317). In other words, the Fed did its job in response to an external drain, while it had not done so in response to an internal drain. Several other authors have argued that the Fed’s inaction was business as usual. The Fed read low interest rates and the lack of member-bank borrowing as monetary ease (Wheelock 1991; Toma 1997). Its action in October 1931 was in character as well. The Fed acted “vigorously and promptly” to preserve the gold value of the dollar. It was the inability of central banks and political leaders to free themselves from this inflexible monetary arrangement that led them to undertake contractionary actions as the economy declined. The Great Depression was the inevitable result of sustained and cumulative deflationary policies in almost all the major industrial countries (Temin 1989). This view has received ample support from econometric analyses of the world depression and has become widely held (Eichengreen and Sachs 1985; Bernanke 1995). Friedman and Schwartz, although they saw the Great Depression as a primarily American affair, agreed with this characterization of the Fed’s action in October 1931. Their detailed discussion of the decision to raise the discount rate so dramatically reveals that the Fed was concerned overwhelmingly with the preservation of the dollar. None of the directors of the New York Reserve Bank thought that the Fed was doing anything other than being a traditional and responsible central banker. Friedman and Schwartz reported also that the Fed’s decision was widely supported throughout the American financial community (Friedman and Schwartz 1963, pp. 380 – 84). More recently, Romer (1993, p. 26) concurred, characterizing the Fed as having a “slavish adherence to the gold standard.” Romer (1993), like most other economists, also cites the sequence of banking panics first emphasized by Friedman and Schwartz (1963) as intensifying the Great Depression. There is no doubt that banking panics are bad for economic activity. But were the banking panics of the early 1930s a cause of the 1931 cycle? There is first the problem of definition, whether bank runs should be thought of as exogenous shocks that precipitate economic decline or whether they are part of the transmission mechanism by which economies can contract. More important is the question whether banking panics would have continued if the Fed in October 1931 had expanded instead of contracting. Commentators from Friedman and Schwartz to the present have asserted that they would not. Grossman (1994) found that the only variable consistently associated with the presence of banking crises was adherence to the gold standard. Bank

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

49

failures and Fed policy were both endogenous. The external gold drain was the exogenous cause of the 1931 cycle in America. What then was the cause that led to the Fed’s action? It was the external gold drain that followed Britain’s departure from gold in September 1931. The British action was in turn a result of the German financial crisis in July 1931. Hot money was moving around the industrial world, speculating against currencies that looked increasingly weak as other currencies failed (Eichengreen 1992; Eichengreen and Temin 1997). The sequence of speculative attacks, loss of reserves, and devaluation or currency controls in a sequence of countries in 1931 differed from the parallel sequence in 1997 only by being European and American instead of Asian. The cause of the cycle beginning in 1931, then, was foreign monetary, FM. It has been entered as such in Table 2. Because this cycle is an outlier, the way it is treated in any quantitative analysis determines the importance of international monetary shocks in precipitating American cycles. Turning to the second largest cycle, 1929, the consensus among economic historians is that the shock was domestic, and agreement that it was real is growing. I argued for a real shock 20 years ago in the form of an autonomous fall in consumption from 1929 to 1930 (Temin 1976). Some authors have claimed that consumption did not fall unusually, but others have confirmed that it did (Mayer 1980; Hall 1986; Lebergott 1996). It has been explained in part as a result of the stock-market crash, which increased both consumers’ leverage and their uncertainty (Mishkin 1978; Romer 1990). A new paper provides a stronger explanation for this fiscal shock. Olney (1998) argues that the structure of consumer credit made consumption highly volatile at this moment in history. If a consumer defaulted on an automobile loan, to take the most important form of consumer credit, he or she did not retain any equity in the automobile used as security. Consumers therefore cut back consumption in an effort to retain their equity in their new cars. A dramatic fall in consumption was the result. The exogenous fall in consumption in 1930 has been transformed into an endogenous fall in consumption by the research just cited. Being endogenous, it does not qualify as a cause of the cycle. We must move further back in the chain of causation. Two events of 1929 appear to have precipitated the sharp fall in consumption: the stock-market crash in October 1929, and the decline in industrial production which began in mid 1929. While these events are not satisfactorily explained, they have been regarded as bubbles, whose end is indeed exogenous (De Long and Shleifer 1991; Rappoport and White 1993). And since they involve the real economy, they are classified here as domestic real shocks. This view is opposed by studies that document the slow growth of the money supply in 1928 and 1929 and the high interest rates that accompanied the stock market boom (Friedman and Schwartz 1963; Field

50

Peter Temin

1984; Hamilton 1987). But Romer (1993, p. 29) observed that the slowdown in monetary growth was not large by historical standards and that real interest rates fell after the stock market crash. She concluded, “The source of this sharp decline is almost surely not contractionary monetary policy.” In addition, this literature contains little discussion about whether the Fed was acting in or out of character in the late 1920s. The implicit assumption appears to be that the Fed was acting in its traditional fashion. If so, then for this reason also, the rate of growth of the money supply does not qualify as a shock to the economy. I therefore list 1929 in Table 2 as resulting from a domestic real shock, DR. The next two largest cycles, 1920 and 1937, are best considered together. They were the other large cycles of the interwar years, and they have been discussed together in the literature. For both of them, as for 1929, there is agreement that the shock was domestic. And for both of them, there is disagreement about whether the shock was fiscal or monetary. The fiscal shock in 1920 was the cancellation of many war contracts when the Armistice ended the First World War. The fiscal shock in 1937 was the budget contraction after payment of the second soldiers’ bonus in 1936. The monetary shock in 1920 was a contraction by the Fed, facing its first postwar test. The monetary shock in 1937 was the rise in the reserve ratio mandated by the Fed in order to sop up the tremendous rise in unborrowed reserves among member banks. The Fed apparently thought it was in a liquidity trap and that these excess reserves were the sign of a perfectly elastic supply of money. Romer (1992) tested these explanations against each other. She used a simple reduced-form model in which income this year responds to fiscal and monetary shocks last year. The coefficients on fiscal and monetary shocks were unknown coefficients to be determined by the data. She constructed two equations with two unknowns by inserting values in the reduced form for 1920 and 1937. Solving, she found that the coefficient on fiscal shocks was essentially zero; monetary shocks were the cause of both cycles. It is easy to criticize this simple model, but it is hard with the limited available data to improve upon it. I accept Romer’s conclusion and cite domestic monetary, DM, shocks for 1920 and 1937. This treatment of 1920 is faithful to the literature, but it may not approach the ultimate cause of this cycle. It was the end of the war that led to all of these domestic actions. If the domestic actions were endogenous, then the cause of the cycle was the cessation of hostilities, which produced a negative international fiscal shock. This was the view of an early Keynesian analysis of this cycle, performed during the Second World War to predict if there would be a repetition after that war (Samuelson 1943). Romer (1988) took a different approach to the end of the war. She argued that “a positive supply shock in 1921” came from accumulated stocks of raw materials during the war. They appeared in the United States only after the release of shipping capacity from wartime

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

51

controls and use. But Romer argued in her later paper that this was only a negligible part of the cause of the 1920 cycle (Romer 1992, p. 764). This abbreviated survey of the literature on the four largest cycles of the past century shows several aspects of the literature. First, no single type of shock was responsible for them all. Three out of the four possible kinds of shocks distinguished in Table 1 are represented as causes of the four largest cycles of the century. This is a very strong conclusion. If one rejects the results of recent scholarship and reverses the causes of the contested cycles in 1920, 1929, and 1937, the conclusion still stands. And people who wish to remain agnostic and cite multiple causes for these cycles obviously preserve the conclusion of many different kinds of shocks. Second, three out of four cycles were responses to domestic shocks. While instability in the international economy was capable of wreaking havoc at home, most often cycles originated in domestic disturbances. Third, the evidence adduced by economists and economic historians to identify the shocks causing these cycles ranges from formal models to informal narratives, with various quantitative and qualitative explorations in the middle. It is possible that we find so many different causes because we use so many different lenses to view the world. This is a persistent problem, but the correlation between the research method used and the conclusion reached does not appear to be good. The Remaining Cycles I turn now to a survey of the other cycles of the past century. I provide briefer narratives of the next 10 cycles, ordered by production lost. This list includes all but one of the cycles for which the cumulative loss exceeded one month of industrial production. The remaining 10 smaller recessions are surveyed in an Appendix. This division has no economic content. I want to expose enough narratives to show their varied nature, but not enough to bore my audience excessively. And we have better stories about larger cycles. The cycle of 1907 started in the European money market. Problems in Europe had led to restriction by the Bank of England and the Reichsbank. The Bank of England additionally looked with disfavor on bills financing trade with America—as the Old Lady of Threadneedle Street had done before, most notably in 1836 (Temin 1969). The resultant monetary stringency in the United States was enough to generate a cycle, but it was augmented by a domestic banking panic. The banking panic in turn led banks to suspend payments, that is, to refuse to change bills into specie at par (Sprague 1910). Friedman and Schwartz regarded the suspension of payments as another cause of the cycle. They argued that the suspension turned a mild contraction into a severe one (Friedman and Schwartz 1963, p. 163). De Long

52

Peter Temin

and Summers (1986) argued to the contrary that the financial panic was contained by the suspension, reducing its effects on production. Both sets of authors agree that the domestic expectations changed in response to the foreign stimulus. The expectations were endogenous, leaving only the foreign monetary cause. The cycle of 1893 also was involved with international finance, but its origin appears firmly domestic. The Sherman Silver Purchase Act of 1890 set the stage for a possible American devaluation in the form of shifting from a gold to a silver standard. Silver had decreased in price in the course of the preceding two decades as new discoveries and technology vastly increased the supply of that metal. Cleveland’s election in 1892 made this possibility into a probability, and a run on the dollar occurred in 1893. Interest rates rose as people rushed to sell government bonds, and banks suspended payment, as they would do again in 1907. The decade of the 1890s was marked by many dislocations in the economy, but the cycle of 1893 was caused by flirting with devaluation (Calomiris 1993; Fels 1959; Hoffman 1970). The next largest cycle was 80 years later in 1973. There can be no doubt that the cause of this cycle was the quadrupling of oil prices by OPEC. This oil shock was clearly apparent at the time and has been the object of countless studies since. Many commentators at the time and later as well argued that Fed was excessively aggressive in its attempt to limit the resulting inflation (R.J. Gordon 1980; Zarnowitz 1992). This policy choice—poor policy from the point of view of industrial production—was the reason Samuelson regarded the Fed as the villain in this cycle. From the point of view of this paper, in which central bank actions are endogenous if in character, the Fed’s action must be regarded as the inevitable result of an inflationary shock. A respectable central bank resists inflation, just as it resisted devaluation in 1931. The cause of this cycle then was foreign real, FR. The 1923 cycle, with the next largest loss of production, followed hard on the heels of the 1920 cycle. Recovery was rapid, and the boom led to bottlenecks, inflation, rising interest rates, and expectations of another recession (R.A. Gordon 1961, p. 423). Even though this was a large cycle, it came in the middle of sustained expansion of production and has received little attention. To the extent that this cycle reflected strains in the preceding expansion, it must be judged to have been caused by domestic real causes. It is clear where this review of the intermediate-sized individual cycles is going. The first four cycles in this extended review are listed as the result of four different kinds of shocks. All of the types of shocks distinguished in Table 1 are represented. As with the larger interwar cycles, no single kind of shock has been the origin of American cycles. The 1981 cycle clearly was caused by the second oil shock, just as the 1973 cycle was caused by the first. But the rise in oil prices and the

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

53

beginning of the downturn were separated by an election that confirmed the hard-line monetary policy undertaken by the Fed under President Carter. Paul Volcker was appointed by Carter, and his fiercely contractionary, “monetarist” policies led both to Carter’s disgrace and defeat at the polls and then to President Reagan’s apotheosis and subsequent great victory in his reelection. Since this was a departure from Fed policy during the 1970s, it must be regarded as a cause of the 1981 cycle (De Long 1998). This cycle then had two causes: foreign real and domestic monetary. Not much is known about the cycle of 1910. Although relatively large, it was not accompanied by a breakdown of the financial system. It consequently did not receive much contemporary attention and has not been the focus of subsequent research. Friedman and Schwartz (1963, p. 174) commented that a drop in wholesale prices contributed to the recession, and I classify the shock as domestic real as a result. The cycle of 1957 was caused by a decline in federal government expenditures as the federal debt neared its legal limit. The Eisenhower Administration made the decision not to ask for an increase in this limit, presumably in the interests of fiscal responsibility. Defense expenditures had been high in the first half of 1957, and the decline in the second half was large. Both durable and nondurable investment decreased, and production fell (Brown 1960; Freeman 1960; R.A. Gordon 1961; R.J. Gordon 1980, Moore 1959; Osborne 1958). Although monetary policy during the 1950s has been criticized as unnecessarily restrictive (Romer and Romer 1989), a real shock was the cause of this cycle. Moving back half a century, the cycle of 1896 appears in the literature as a coda to the cycle of 1893, much as the cycle of 1923 is seen as a continuation of the process begun in the cycle of 1920. Uncertainty about the exchange rates was increased by the Democratic Party’s nomination of Bryan for President. He proclaimed in ringing words at the convention, “You shall not crucify mankind upon a cross of gold.” This was not calculated to calm the financial markets. As with 1893, the cause must be seen as domestic monetary. The threat was to the exchange rate, but it came from within the United States, not from foreign sources. Returning again to the 1950s, the cycle of 1953 followed the end of the Korean War. It was caused by the decrease in government spending that resulted from the sharp cutback in military activity (Brown 1960; Freeman 1960; R.A. Gordon 1961; R.J. Gordon 1980; Zarnowitz 1992). This cycle therefore was like that of 1920 in having its cause in the fiscal shock of peace. It differed from 1920 in coming directly after the war and not having an intermediate boom. The more direct link between the end of hostilities and a cycle in 1953 may reflect the smaller size of the preceding war. The cycle of 1948 also resembled that of 1920 in following a war. The parallel appears more direct than for 1953 because the war was far larger and because the downturn followed an immediate postwar boom. But

54

Peter Temin

Table 3

Causes of American Business Cycles, 1890 to 1990
Domestic Real Number of Cycles Months of Lost Production
Source: Table 2.

Foreign Real 2.5 3.73

Domestic Monetary 5.5 18.15

Foreign Monetary 5 26.02

11 22.05

while the cycle of 1920 was one of the largest of the past century, that of 1948 was quite small. Commentators have regarded the contraction as an inventory recession (Freeman 1960; R.J. Gordon 1980; Hamberg 1952). The economic scene in Europe after the war was ever-changing, but the realignment of European currency values in 1948 was accomplished without turmoil in the international financial markets. As with the four largest cycles, there is variety to spare in the causes of these 10 cycles. All four types of causes are listed, although a foreign monetary cause was important in only one cycle, 1907. In fact, monetary causes of any sort are not prominent in this intermediate tier of cycles. Real causes outnumber monetary ones by two to one. Foreign real shocks were confined to the period after World War II for these intermediatesized cycles. This is a good place to end this review of individual cycles. The literature on smaller cycles lacks the intensity of the discussion of larger fluctuations. Consequently it is harder to discriminate among the suggested causes advanced by different authors. The Appendix contains short narratives of the 10 smallest cycles of the past century, omitting 1916 about which no information could be found. All four types of causes were represented among these smaller cycles, although domestic real and foreign monetary shocks were most numerous. There were slightly more real than monetary causes, and more domestic than foreign causes, as with larger cycles. Smaller cycles do not appear to have different causes than larger cycles.

SUMMARY

AND

CONCLUSIONS

The results of this study are summarized in Table 3. The first row shows the unweighted distribution of shocks over the past century, where each cycle is counted as one observation. The second row weights the cycles by the loss of production shown in Table 2 to show the months of production lost in cycles started by different causes. (In both rows, the cycle of 1981 with its dual cause is divided in two.) As noted above in examining subsamples, all four types of causes played a role in American cycles of the past century. It is not possible to

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

55

identify a single type of instability as the source of American business cycles. This is true for the century as a whole, for each subperiod, and for each size class. The dominant conclusion of this inquiry is that sources of instability are not homogeneous. The literature on American business cycles provides no basis for Dornbusch’s stark indictment of the Fed. Instead, this informal survey supports the results of Cochrane’s (1994) time-series tests on postwar data. Domestic real shocks were the most numerous, simply counting cycles (as in the first row of Table 3). These shocks ranged from inventory adjustments to the changes in expectations that led to the dramatic fall in consumption in 1930. Even though they are grouped together in this classification, domestic real shocks were themselves quite diverse. Nonetheless, this conclusion may be surprising. The anti-Fed view is not even supported as an approximation. Foreign real shocks were not an important source of American instability, with the exception of the two oil shocks. The oil shocks represent a new kind of instability for the American economy. It is unlikely that this change is due simply to the growing importance of international trade. It appears to come also from increased concentration in various markets that allow dramatic price changes to take place. But we have had only two oil shocks, which is not enough to test hypotheses. We do not know if more such shocks will occur or whether OPEC will turn out to be a transitory source of instability. Monetary shocks, both domestic and foreign, appear to have decreased over time. The difference between this conclusion and the opposite view represented by Dornbusch’s statement may come from the model I am using, in which the Fed is endogenous. If the Fed “caused” a downturn by responding to some other shock, then I regard the other shock as the cause, while someone regarding the Fed as exogenous might classify the Fed’s action as the shock. But this interpretation may not be true to Dornbusch’s intent. His use of the term, “murdered,” suggests exogenous acts by the Fed. I did not find evidence that they were important in the period since World War II. This comparison has taken all cycles to be equal. It is instructive to ask whether large cycles were caused by different shocks than small cycles. The narratives of cycles suggested this was not the case; the second row of Table 3 takes another look. Foreign monetary shocks emerge as the most important type of shock, measured by the amount of production lost. The contrast between the weighted and unweighted sums is due to the great size of the 1931 cycle. This downturn, which dwarfs all others of the past century, accounts for 21 of the 26 months of production lost as a result of foreign monetary shocks. If the Great Depression is seen as a special case, then the weighted and unweighted sums provide more similar pictures. With the exception of the Great Depression, domestic shocks were

56

Peter Temin

much more important in the past century than foreign shocks. Aside from the Great Depression, foreign monetary shocks led to very small losses in output. And foreign real shocks led to even less. The view of the American economy that sees it as largely independent of the rest of the world gets abundant confirmation in the record of the past century— leaving the Great Depression to one side. The losses due to real and monetary shocks are surprisingly similar. As noted above in the narratives, each kind of shock caused both large and small cycles. There appears to have been little bias in their incidence. Real shocks were slightly more important, as suggested by the unweighted sum. This conclusion appears stronger for the postwar years than for the century as a whole. For the past 40 years, production lost in business cycles has been caused more by real shocks than monetary ones. For only one, small cycle—the most recent—was the real shock possibly a productivity shock. Finally, I reiterate that this has been an exercise in historiography. I have examined the secondary literature on business cycles in America over the past century and found the patterns exhibited here. The conventional call for more research is particularly apt here. Macroeconomic theory has developed in many directions since most of the research surveyed here was performed. The history of American business cycles offers a fertile field for empirical research.

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

57

Appendix
This appendix contains short narratives of the smallest 10 cycles of the past century, omitting 1916 about which no information could be found. This is not a discontinuity; the literature on small cycles often approaches zero. The cycles are discussed chronologically on the grounds that the range of size—from one-half to one month’s production lost—is too small to be interesting. Chronological order also preserves some continuity in economic conditions as the narrative progresses. 1900: This small cycle was caused by a mild monetary stringency following the start of the Boer War (Friedman and Schwartz 1963, p. 148). Its cause is FM. 1903: This “rich man’s panic” followed the great merger wave at the turn of the century. No specific cause for the cycle has been identified in the literature. I judge it to have resulted from a readjustment of equity prices after the enthusiasm of the merger wave had cooled a bit. This shift of expectations about the real economy makes the cause DR. 1914: This cycle followed the outbreak of the First World War. As usual, there was a brief panic that raised interest rates and led to a contraction of economic activity. The cause is FM. 1918: This cycle was caused by the decline in spending at the conclusion of World War I (R.A. Gordon 1961). It was the immediate effect of the war’s end, limited in scope and followed by a brief boom and then the larger cycle of 1920. The cause of this cycle is a reduction in domestic spending, DR, even though this spending was related to the United States’ activities in Europe. The cycle was not a response to a fall in the demand for exports. 1927: This cycle is attributed to the Ford Motor Company shutdown in 1927 for a model change (R.A. Gordon 1961, p. 424). This is not supported by anything more than temporal correspondence. Nonetheless, in the absence of other causes, I classify this cause as DR. 1939: Like those of 1900 and 1914, this cycle was the result of financial stringency caused by panic at the beginning of a war. The cause is FM. 1960: This cycle took place during the Eisenhower tight budgetary regime. While some people have regarded the budget surplus as a cause of contraction, the surplus was planned—in conjunction with expansionary monetary policy—as a stimulus to private investment. The cause of the contraction was “the drastic tightening of money that occurred in 1959 – 60” (R.J. Gordon 1980, p. 131). The cause is DM. 1969: Like 1918’s, this cycle was caused by the decline in government spending attending the end— or at least the winding down— of the Vietnam War (R.J. Gordon 1980, p. 145; Zarnowitz 1992, p. 114). The cause is DR. 1980: This cycle is the smallest downturn classified as a cycle. It is a precursor of the larger cycle in 1981; no separate cause for it is noted in the literature. The following cycle, starting in 1981, is rightly attributed in part to Volcker’s influence; this one, simply the result of the oil shock, FR. 1990: Blanchard (1993) and Hall (1993) said that this cycle was due to an exogenous fall in consumption—like 1929. Cochrane (1994) objected that consumption is endogenous; the consumption fall must have been caused by a change in expectations. Blanchard labeled these expectations “animal spirits,” and both he and Hall referred to the invasion of Kuwait as a shock that discouraged consumption. Hansen and Prescott (1993) claimed a technology shock as the cause of the recession. Without resolving this disagreement, I classify the cause as DR.

58

Peter Temin

References
Bernanke, Ben. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression.” The American Economic Review, 73 (June), pp. 257–76. _____. 1995. “The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27, pp. 1–28. Blanchard, Olivier J. 1993. “Consumption and the Recession of 1990 –91.” The American Economic Review, 83 (May), pp. 270 –74. Brown, E. Cary. 1956. “Fiscal Policy in the Thirties: A Reappraisal.” The American Economic Review, 46 (December), pp. 857–79. _____. 1960. “Federal Fiscal Policy and the Postwar Period.” In Ralph E. Freeman, ed., Postwar Economic Trends in the United States, pp. 141– 88. New York: Harper. Calomiris, Charles W. 1993. “Greenback Resumption and Silver Risk: The Economics and Politics of Monetary Regime Change in the United States, 1862–1900.” In Michael D. Bordo and Forrest Capie, eds., Monetary Regime Transformations, pp. 86 –132. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans. 1998. “Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and to What End?” NBER Working Paper No. 6400. Cochrane, John H. 1994. “Shocks.” Carnegie Conference Series on Public Policy, 41, pp. 295–364. De Long, J. Bradford. 1998. “Fiscal Policy in the Shadow of the Great Depression.” In Michael D. Bordo, Claudia Goldin, and Eugene N. White, eds., The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy in the Twentieth Century. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. De Long, J. Bradford and Andrei Shleifer. 1991. “The Stock Market Bubble of 1929: Evidence from Closed-end Mutual Funds.” Journal of Economic History, 51 (September), pp. 675–700. De Long, J. Bradford and Lawrence Summers. 1986. “The Changing Cyclical Variability of Economic Activity in the United States.” In Robert J. Gordon, ed., The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, pp. 679 –734. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1997. “How Real Is U.S. Prosperity?” Column reprinted in World Economic Laboratory Columns, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, December. Duesenberry, James S. 1958. Business Cycles and Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill. Eichengreen, Barry. 1992. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression. New York: Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, Barry and Jeffrey Sachs. 1985. “Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s.” Journal of Economic History, 45 (December), pp. 925– 46. Eichengreen, Barry and Peter Temin. 1997. The Gold Standard and the Great Depression. Cambridge, MA: NBER Working Paper No. 6060. June. Feinstein, Charles, Peter Temin, and Gianni Toniolo. 1997. The European Economy Between the Wars. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Fels, Rendigs. 1959. American Business Cycles, 1865–1897. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina. Field, Alexander J. 1984. “Asset Exchange and the Transaction Demand for Money, 1919 –29.” The American Economic Review, 74 (March), pp. 43–59. _____. 1992. “Uncontrolled Land Development and the Duration of the Depression in the United States.” Journal of Economic History, 52 (December), pp. 785– 805. Freeman, Ralph E. 1960. “Postwar Monetary Policy.” In Ralph E. Freeman, ed., Postwar Economic Trends in the United States, pp. 53–90. New York: Harper. Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Gordon, Robert A. 1961. Business Fluctuations. Second Edition. New York: Harper and Row. Gordon, Robert J. 1980. “Postwar Macroeconomics: The Evolution of Events and Ideas.” In Martin Feldstein, ed., The American Economy in Transition, pp. 101– 82. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Grossman, Richard S. 1994. “The Shoe That Didn’t Drop: Explaining Banking Stability During the Great Depression.” Journal of Economic History, 54 (September), pp. 654 – 82. Hall, Robert E. 1986. “The Role of Consumption in Economic Fluctuations.” In Robert J. Gordon, ed., The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, pp. 237– 66. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

THE CAUSES OF AMERICAN BUSINESS CYCLES

59

_____. 1993. “Macro Theory and the Recession of 1990 –91,” The American Economic Review, 83 (May), pp. 275–79. Hamberg, D. 1952. “The Recession of 1948 – 49 in the United States.” Economic Journal, vol. 62 (March), pp. 1–14. Hamilton, James D. 1987. “Monetary Factors in the Great Depression,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 19 (March), pp. 145– 69. Hansen, Gary D. and Edward C. Prescott. 1993. “Did Technology Shocks Cause the 1990 –1991 Recession?” The American Economic Review, 83 (May), pp. 280 – 86. Hoffman, Charles. 1970. The Depression of the Nineties. Westwood, CT: Greenwood Publishing Co. Keynes, John Maynard. [1936] 1964. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World. Lebergott, Stanley. 1996. Consumer Expenditures: New Measures and Old Motives. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Mayer, Thomas. 1980. “Consumption in the Great Depression.” Journal of Political Economy, 86 (February), pp. 139 – 45. Mishkin, Frederic S. 1978. “The Household Balance Sheet and the Great Depression.” Journal of Economic History, 38 (December), pp. 918 –37. Moore, Geoffrey H. 1959. “The 1957–58 Business Contraction: New Model or Old?” The American Economic Review, 49 (May), pp. 292–308. Olney, Martha L. 1998. Forthcoming. “Avoiding Default: The Role of Credit in the Consumption Collapse of 1930.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. Osborne, Harlow D. 1958. “National Income and Product—A Review of the 1957–58 Decline and Recovery.” Survey of Current Business, 38 (November), pp. 9 –17. Rappoport, Peter, and Eugene N. White. 1993. “Was There a Bubble in the 1929 Stock Market?” Journal of Economic History, 53 (September), pp. 549 –74. Romer. Christina D. 1988. “World War I and the Postwar Depression: A Reinterpretation Based on Alternative Estimates of GNP.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 22 (July), pp. 91–115. _____. 1990. “The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105 (August), pp. 597– 624. _____. 1992. “What Ended the Great Depression?” Journal of Economic History, 52 (December), pp. 757– 84. _____. 1993. “The Nation in Depression.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7 (Spring) pp. 19 –39. _____. 1994. “Remeasuring Business Cycles.” Journal of Economic History, 54 (September), pp. 573– 609. Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer. 1989. “Does Monetary Policy Matter? A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 4, pp. 121–70. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Samuelson, Paul A. 1943. “Full Employment after the War.” In S. E. Harris, ed., Postwar Economic Problems, pp. 27–53. New York: McGraw-Hill. Sprague, O. M. W. 1910. History of Crises under the National Banking System. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. Taylor, John B. 1993a. Macroeconomic Policy in a World Economy. New York: W.W. Norton. _____. 1993b. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie Conference Series on Public Policy 39, pp. 195–214. Temin, Peter. 1969. The Jacksonian Economy. New York: W.W. Norton. _____. 1976. Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression? New York: W.W. Norton. _____. 1989. Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Toma, Mark. 1997. Competition and Monopoly in the Federal Reserve System, 1914 –1951. New York: Cambridge University Press. Wheelock, David C. 1991. The Strategy and Consistency of Federal Reserve Monetary Policy: 1924 –1933. New York: Cambridge University Press. Zarnowitz, Victor. 1992. Business Cycles: Theory, History, Indicators, and Forecasting. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Kao Strategy Business

...CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION 1.1 Background Cost management information consists of financial information about costs and revenues, and nonfinancial information about customer retention, productivity, quality, and other key success factors for the organization. Cost management is the development and use of cost management information. A strategic understanding of cost management is so important that many senior financial managers are coming back to school to learn more about strategy, competitive analysis, and new cost management techniques. Knowing how to do the accounting alone, no matter how well you do it, is by itself no longer sufficient. 1.2 Purpose of Writing The general purpose of writing is to complete the final task of the subject of Cost Management—module assignment—in the fifth semester. It shows how well and how far we have understood this subject. 1.3 Methodology * The method used in the process of completing this module assignment report is qualitative methods: analysis and assumption. I directly received the information from the annual report and website of Dell Inc. * I also used the theory from the text book of Cost Management – A Strategic Emphasis Sixth Edition by Blocher. Then, I compare the information that Ireceived with the theory that I know from the text book. 1.4 Systemization The format of our module assignment is as follows: * Chapter I is Introduction which consists of four major sub-chapters: Background, Purpose of Writing...

Words: 10426 - Pages: 42

Premium Essay

Corporate Governance

...THE INDONESIA CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MANUAL First Edition IFC Advisory Services in Indonesia In Partnership with: THE INDONESIA CORPORATE GOVERNANCE MANUAL First Edition Jakarta, January 2014 i Disclaimer IFC, a member of the World Bank Group, creates opportunity for people to escape poverty and improve their lives. We foster sustainable economic growth in developing countries by supporting private sector development, mobilizing private capital and providing advisory services. The Indonesia Corporate Governance Manual (CG Manual) was commissioned by IFC as part of the Indonesia Corporate Governance Program that IFC is implementing in Indonesia since 2012. This manual is distributed with the understanding that neither the authors, nor the organizations, countries they represent, nor the publisher are engaged in rendering legal or financial advice. The material in this Manual is set out in good faith for general guidance, and no liability can be accepted for any possible loss or expense in incurred as a result of relying on the information contained herein. This publication is not intended to be exhaustive. It should not be relied upon as a basis for formulating business decisions. On all financial issues and questions, an accountant, auditor, or other financial specialist should be consulted. A lawyer should be consulted on all legal issues and questions. As the laws in the Republic of Indonesia are constantly changing, legal rules referred...

Words: 131549 - Pages: 527