Free Essay

Case – Basel Iii: an Evaluation of New Banking Regulations

In:

Submitted By aalmandeel
Words 8576
Pages 35
Finding Love in the Wreckage: Estimating Spousal Altruism with Data on Fatal Car Accidents Ilya Beylin, Anup Malani, and David Abrams1 Abstract. This paper estimates the degree of altruism among spouses by examining how often the driver of a car sacrifices himself or herself in order to save a spouse. Holding constant the magnitude of a collision, a driver can maneuver the car to distribute the risk from a collision between the driver and a passenger. We quantify spousal altruism by the degree to which drivers riding with their spouse redistribute the risk from a fatal accident to themselves – as measured by ex post mortality – as compared to drivers not traveling with their spouse. We find that drivers with their spouses are at least 37% more likely to sacrifice themselves. This implies that they value the lives of their spouses at least 37% more than the lives of other individuals.

A driver’s position in a car provides him with exclusive control over the pedals and steering wheel. At the time of an impending accident, this control enables him to adjust the total amount of risk facing the car’s occupants and how that risk is distributed. In other words, his maneuvers will have allocative and distributive effects on the occupants’ risk. The driver’s distributive choices reveal his relative preferences for himself over his passengers. The manifestation of injuries amongst the occupants allows observation of those relative preferences. A theory of spousal altruism – indeed any romantic notion of marriage – would predict that a husband is more willing to sacrifice himself for his passenger when the passenger is his wife.2 The central purpose of this paper is to test this prediction. We compare the probability that drivers travelling with spouses sacrifice their own life to the probability that drivers traveling with other women sacrifice their own life to estimate how much altruism drivers exhibit towards their spouses. We perform this comparison in a sample of two-occupant cars in which only the driver or the front seat passenger died. (We call these “one-death” cars). Assuming rational expectations, this selection guarantees that the drivers we compare are facing the same amount of risk, namely the death of one and only one occupant.

1

University of Chicago Law School, University of Chicago Law School, and University of Pennsylvania Law School, respectively. Please send comments to amalani@uchicago.edu. We thank Edward Morrison for his comments. Malani thanks the Milton and Miriam Handler Foundation for financial support. To keep the prose simple, we use the male pronoun to describe the driver and the female to describe the passenger.

2

1

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1119379

Prior literature has proposed two motivations for interspousal transfers, reciprocity and altruism (Kolm & Ythier 2006). The former explains transfers as motivated by the transferor’s expectation of compensation from his or her spouse, whereas the latter explains transfers as motivated by a transferor’s “other regarding” preferences (i.e. preferences for others’ utility). This paper offers an indirect test of these two theories. By focusing on a transfer that occurs at the end of a spouse’s life, this paper rules out reciprocity as a motivation for altruism. If a driver is more willing to sacrifice himself for his spouse, then that transfer must be altruistic. Our accident data comes from the Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS), which is a census of US auto fatalities that includes information on the context of the accident, the vehicles involved, and the occupants of those vehicles. The FARS data set does not identify the marital status of a car’s occupants. To address this we merged the FARS data set with the Multiple Cause of Death (MCOD) data, which is a census of US decedents that includes their marital status. Because the MCOD is exclusively a census of decedents, we were unable to directly identify whether the surviving occupant in a one-death car was married. To solve this identification problem, we use a two-sample instrumental variable (TSIV) design (Angrist & Krueger 1992). In the first stage of the TSIV analysis, we estimate whether drivers and passengers are married using a sample of cars where both the driver and the front passenger died (“two-death cars”). Our excluded instrument is the square of the driver’s age. Then we use that model to predict the probability that the driver and front passenger in one-death cars are married. Our main second-stage structural equation is a linear probability model in which the dependent variable is whether the driver in a one-death car died and the independent variables include the predicted probability that the driver was traveling with his spouse. The spousal altruism hypothesis predicts that the coefficient on the probability of being married is positive. This is indeed what we find. In our base model, males are roughly 37 percent and females roughly 54 percent more likely to sacrifice themselves for spouses than for non-spouses. In more refined specifications, that treatment effect rises to approximately 53-83 percent for men and 92105 percent for women. As a falsification test, we check if altruism disappears when a driver lacks control over his or her vehicle. We find that this is indeed the case when drivers are intoxicated, when the accident occurs in bad weather, when the car is struck from the rear (and the opposite if from the front), and when men drive on a wet surface. 2

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1119379

Section 1 surveys the literature on spousal altruism. Section 2 describes the data we employ. Section 3 offers a theoretical justification for our method of estimating spousal altruism. Section 4 reports our empirical results. Section 5 concludes.

1. Literature review Our study joins a great number that have looked at the distribution of resources within the family.
3

A brief survey of preceding theories and the results of their validations helps

contextualize our own study as well as isolate its specific contributions to the field. Samuelson (1956) proposed a “unitary” model of intrahousehold exchange in which the head of household had exclusive control over resources that he then allocated. The allocation was directed by the head of household’s utility function, which was itself dependent on the utilities of others in the household. A series of papers challenging the unitary model followed. (Lundberg 1988; Fortin and Lacroix 1997). These proposed a “collectivist” model under which household members separately controlled resources and transferred these resources through a process of negotiation with other members. Tests of the collectivist model have, for example, varied a household members’ options outside the household (Chiappori et al 2002) or income within the household (Duflo and Udry 2003) to note that household expenditures shift to benefit the spouse with the decreased cost of exit, or increased income. These results are inconsistent with a unitary model under which only the aggregate household budget and the household members’ preferences for consumption affect expenditures.

3

Kolm and Ythier (2006) produced the Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity organizing

much of the preceding literature on intrafamilial transfers and their explanations. A number of papers have studied interspousal exchange without making claims as to its motivation. Agarwal and Horowitz (2002) and de Laat (2005) present data on remittances from migrant workers. These studies do not seek to apportion the remittances between amounts due to altruism and amounts due to reciprocity. A second category of papers takes a different angle and examines domestic violence among married couples. For example, Dee (2003) and Stevenson and Wolfers (2006) find that easier access to divorce reduces domestic violence. These papers also do not distinguish between altruistic and egotistic motivations.

3

While the collectivist model may have displaced the unitary, the collectivist model without more does not predict intrafamilial transfers. That is because the collectivist model is consistent with both “altruistic” and “egotistic” preference structures (Chiappori 1992). The former allow for utility functions that depend on other family members’ utilities such as that of Samuelson’s original benevolent patriarch, whereas the latter only permit non-interdependent utilities amongst family members. Distinguishing between altruistic and egotistical motivations for transfers is difficult because compensatory transfers may occur at a different time or take a different form than the original transfer, or may never even manifest if the transfer functions as a premium paid for an informal insurance policy (Coate and Ravalion 1993, Thomas and Worral 1995, Ligon 2003). Disentangling the motivations is important because they determine the extent to which availability of market substitutes will crowd out intrafamilial transfers. If, for example, transfers are explained solely by an egotistic mutual insurance motivation the development of formal insurance markets will crowd them out when the benefits of diversification through contracts with unrelated parties overcome the information deficits of such unrelated parties (Foster and Rosenzweig 2001). Because we choose a context where the transfer by nature is expected to take place near the end of life, our results provide evidence of interspousal altruism as distinct from reciprocity. In the intergenerational context, models of upward and downward indirect reciprocity have developed (Rapoport and Docquier 2006). Under the former model, children help their parents so that grandchildren help the children. Under the latter model, parents help children so that children help grandchildren. Either dynamic rests on generational pipelining, which has no obvious analog in the interspousal context. Prior studies of interspousal transfers have rejected that spouses’ preference structures reflect “perfect altruism.” An agent exhibits perfect altruism when he is indifferent between personal consumption providing a unit of utility and another’s consumption providing a unit of utility to that other. In other words, a husband will be perfectly altruistic if he vicariously experiences whatever his wife does. Papers have rejected the hypothesis of perfect interspousal altruism observing that exogenous increases of spousal income are followed by inadequate transfers from the affected spouse. For example, Chiappori et al (2002) estimate that a $1,740 ($2,240) increase in a wife’s (husband’s) annual income is followed by a $1,634 ($600) annual 4

transfer from the wife (husband) to the husband (wife). Duflo and Udry (2003) report that rainfall patterns helpful to jointly controlled crops increase household expenditures on education and food consumption, whereas weather helpful to crops controlled separately by husbands (or wives) increases expenditures on adult and prestige goods (and food).4 This paper adds to the preceding debate by being the first to provide evidence that perfect egotism (like perfect altruism) fails to explain interspousal tranfers.

2. Data The results derive from two national censuses: the Fatality Analysis Reporting System (FARS) and the Multiple Cause of Death (MCOD) file. Our treatment and control populations come from FARS, which reports all fatal traffic accidents occurring on public roadways that result in at least one fatality within 30 days of the crash so long as police were notified of the crash. (NHTSA 2005). The National Center for Statistics and Analysis of the National Highway Safety Administration (NHTSA/NCSA) administers FARS. Under agreements between the NHTSA/NCSA and individual states (as well as the District of Columbia and Puerto Rico), state agents trained in FARS protocols gather, translate and transmit data to NHTSA/NCSA, which publishes the data annually from 1975 until the present. The FARS data include information on the location and circumstances of the accident, the vehicles involved in the accident and the occupants of each of those vehicles. Accident data include the date and time of day of the accident, as well as the weather, lighting and road conditions. Vehicle data include the car’s model and year, its direction and speed of travel, and the angle of impact measured in clock angles (e.g. 12 o’clock for a frontal collision, 5 o’clock for back right). Person data include gender, age, seat position, whether an air bag and/or seat belt was used, and extent of injury. The data do not include the marital status of occupants. Though
4

This class of studies is paralleled by several that reject perfect altruism between parents and children. For

example, Altonji et al (1997) find that a $1.00 reduction in parental income reduces the amount transferred to children by only $.05 and a $1.00 increase in children’s income reduces the transfer by only $.08.

5

unavailable to the public, the FARS dataset also includes the death certificate number of every decedent. A combination of the death certificate number and the state of death provided a unique identifier used to merge FARS data to MCOD data, which are described next. The MCOD is a census of all deaths occurring within the United States. The National Center for Health Statistics (NCHS) maintains the MCOD dataset, publishing it annually since 1983. The dataset contains the cause(s) of death for each fatality, as well as personal information about the decedent including marital status. At our request, the Department of Transportation provided a dataset merging FARS and MCOD for each FARS fatality between 1990 and 1998.

3. Empirical method An ideal field experiment to test for spousal altruism in car crashes would begin with a random sample of married individuals who are asked to drive a car. Each would be randomly assigned a passenger who was either (1) his or her spouse or (2) another person of the opposite gender. Each individual would then be exposed to a car crash where the aggregate mortality risk is held constant but the driver was able to distribute this mortality risk between him or herself and the passenger. The outcome would be the amount of risk the driver chose to retain. The treatment effect would be the difference between (1) the risk borne by the driver when driving with a spouse and (2) the risk borne by the driver when driving with a random partner of the opposite gender. The average treatment effect would amount to: E(yd | sd, sp, sd ≠ sp, d = married, p = spouse) – E(yd | sd, sp, sd ≠ sp, d = married, p = random non-spouse) where yd is the mortality risk borne by the driver, sd and sp are the sex of the driver and passenger, respectively, and d and p are the identity of the driver and front-right passenger, respectively. Fortunately for the subjects, we are not able to run this ideal experiment. Our experiment departs from the ideal in four ways:

6

1. We do not observe a random sample of opposite-sex driving companions. Instead we have a sample of companions that were in car accidents: E(yd | sd, sp, sd ≠ sp, d, p, accident). Moreover, FARS only includes cars involved in accidents with at least one fatality. We cannot avoid the non-randomness due to selection of companions into accidents, fatal or not. But to limit the effect of the fatality selection criterion of the FARS data, some of our specifications will examine only cars involved in accidents in which there was at least one fatality in some other car. This subset of cars is one that is more random a selection from all cars in accidents than is the entire FARS dataset. 2. We do not observe the same person driving once with his or her spouse and once with some other, similar person of the opposite gender. What we have is observations on people who choose to drive together. This is a hurdle we cannot overcome. Therefore, our comparisons of spouses and non-spouses includes the effect of spousal status and selection effects due to the non-random sorting of driving partners. The selection bias is E(yd | sd, sp, sd ≠ sp, d = married, p = random non-spouse, ) – E(yd | sd, sp, sd ≠ sp, d = married, p = chosen non-spouse) Assuming that the altruism towards chosen driving partners is greater than altruism towards randomly-selected driving partners, this suggests that our estimate of altruism will underestimate spousal altruism. 3. We do not know the precise amount of mortality risk the driver thought he was free to distribute in an accident. We only observe an ex post realization of mortality, which is a mix of allocative effects, distributive effects, and uncontrollable effects. We bridge the gap between the driver’s expectations about distributable risk and ex post realization of mortality in three steps. First, we assume the driver has rational expectations and rely on the law of large numbers. This implies that the driver’s expectation of mortality risk is equal to the expected value of ex post realizations over a large number of accidents.5 Second, we assume that the degree of control

5

This is similar to the approach taken in Finkelstein and Poterba (2006), who assume ex post realizations of

mortality are a good proxy for ex ante expectations of health risks in the context of annuity purchases. An implicit assumption embedded in our use of ex post mortality to proxy for ex ante expectation of mortality is that the

7

over the distribution of risks does not depend on spousal status. Third, we restrict our analysis to cars with two occupants and only one death. (We call these “one-death” cars.) The fact of one death is intended to control for the magnitude of risk that the driver distributed between herself and the passenger. Specifically, we assume that in every car accident where only one out of two total occupants died, the driver expected that he had the same amount of mortality risk to distribute between himself and the passenger and that this amount was less than one.6 4. The FARS data does not indicate whether the driver and passenger were married to each other. We address this problem in two steps. First, we merge the FARS data with the MCOD data to identify the marital status of the deceased occupant. Because the MCOD data do not provide the marital status of passengers who survived in one-death cars, it cannot identify spouses in these cars. We remedy this by using a two-sample instrumental variables (TSIV) design to identify whether the deceased occupant was married to the surviving occupant. The first stage of the TSIV analysis uses a subsample of cars where both the driver and the passenger died (“two-death cars”). By definition each occupant is deceased, so the MCOD may be used to identify whether each is married. We define a driver and passenger paid as married to each other if they are both simply married.7 Our excluded instrument for whether the driver and passenger are married is the square of the driver’s age. The justification for this

function that describes how mortality risk can be transferred from driver to passenger is linear. In other words, we have assumed that a 1% decrease in risk for the driver is associated with a 1% increase in risk for the passenger.
6

Moreover, the nature of the risk distributed is not cumulative but alternative. In other words, although the driver is

choosing p0 for himself and p1 for the passenger, p0 (p1) is not the probability that the driver (passenger) dies, but rather the probability that the driver (passenger) dies instead of the passenger (driver).
7

This overestimates the number of driver-passenger pairs that are married to each other. Since the both-married

variable is the left-hand side variable in stage one of the TSIV analysis, there is no bias so long as the overestimate does not depend on included or excluded instruments and there is a constant in the first stage model. Therefore, the important, implicit assumption in our first stage is that age or age-squared do not predict whether two people who are married, but not to each other, drive together. If this is not true, our second stage estimate will measure how much a married driver prefers another married passenger to a non-married passenger, whether or not the two are married to each other. If married drivers prefer their spouses to other married people, then our second stage result will underestimate the degree of spousal altruism.

8

instrument is that the fraction of cases in which the driver and passenger in a two-death car are both married rises and then falls with the age of the driver. This is illustrated in Figure 1. Moreover, while the probability that the driver dies in our second-stage model may depend on the age of the driver, it does not depend on the square of age.8 To sum up, the first stage is a linear regression of whether the driver and passenger are married on, among other things, age squared in a subsample of two-death cars. The second stage of the TSIV analysis returns to a sample of one-death cars. The outcome variable is whether the driver died. We use the estimated first stage parameters to predict the probability that the driver and passenger are married in one-death cars. This probability is the treatment variable. We employ a number of controls for characteristics of the driver and passenger (including other gender combinations, age, intoxication, and driving history), characteristics of the car, and characteristics of the accident (including whether the car rolled, the angle of collision, time of day, and location). Thus, our second stage is a linear regression of whether the driver died on the predicted probability of the occupants being married and controls. We adjust our second stage standard errors for the fact that our treatment variable is a predicted value. We conduct our TSIV analysis separately for male and female drivers. To ensure our treatment and control groups are as similar as possible, we confine the sample to drivers who are married and driving with a passenger of the opposite gender. So, for example, our analysis compares male drivers with high probability of being married to their female passengers with male drivers with a low probability of being married to their female passengers to identify the effect of that probability on whether the driver dies, which we attribute to spousal altruism. Finally, to address well-known problems with the linear probability model, we also generate TSIV estimates using a logit model for both stages.

4. Empirical analysis
8

We verify this by regressing the second stage residual on age squared and cannot reject the hypothesis that

coefficient age squared is zero. Indeed, the estimated coefficient on age squared is very close to zero and has a small standard error (both usually orders of magnitude less than 1 x 10-5).

9

Table 1 presents summary statistics for the control variables we include in our regressions. The columns present means (and standard errors) by subsamples, divided first by whether the driver was male (and passenger female) or the driver was female (and the passenger male) and subdivided further by whether the traveling companions are likely to be spouses or not.9 The purpose of calculating means for these subpopulations is to determine whether the sorting of driving companions into the spouse and non-spouse groups and the sorting of spouses and non-spouses into accident scenarios is really random. It is apparent that spouses are likelier to drive younger, heavier cars, and use seat belts (but not airbags). Spouses are less likely to have traffic violations, drive drunk, drive fast, drive in the dark (but not bad weather). Spouses are more likely to be involved in head on or rear end collisions as well as side swipes in which vehicles were headed in opposite directions. On the other hand, spouses are less likely to be involved in side swipes with the vehicles heading in the same direction, less likely to be at fault in the accident, and less likely to attempt to avoid the collision by a maneuver other than a swerve. Spouses also tend to be older. Comparing spouses to non-spouses in cars with male drivers and female passengers (i.e. MF pairings), we observe that accidents are less likely to be caused by vehicular defects or involve angled collisions. MF pairs also tend to be driving faster relative to the velocity of the other vehicle involved in the accident, and more likely to swerve. The opposite tendencies are observed among FM pairs. These differences suggest significant non-random sorting that could affect the propensity of the driver (rather than the passenger) to die in a fatal crash. Fortunately we can control for the non-random sorting documented in Table 1. The question is whether there are variables we do not observe that are non-randomly distributed and are correlated with spousal altruism in a manner that is not captured by variables we do observe. This is a weakness we have previously identified and that Table 1 does not resolve. A. Basic results and robustness checks

9

The subsamples only include one-death cars where the driver and passenger are of opposite sex. For the purposes

of table 1 only, male (female) drivers are deemed likely to be married to their passengers if their predicted probability of being married from our TSIV analysis is above the median predicted probability for all cars in the male (female) driver subsamples.

10

Our main, stage 2 regression results for FM and MF pairs are reported in Table 2. Specification (1) includes just the basic indicators for gender pairings and those pairings interacted with our spousal indicator. Specification (2) adds controls for whether the drive was intoxicated, whether the vehicle is an SUV or truck, and the age of the vehicle; (3) adds whether the road was dry and lit, whether driver and passenger were using safety devices, whether the driver was free from fault, whether the vehicle rolled over and the relative orientations of the vehicles involved in the accident; and (4) adds whether the weather was bad, whether the road was in an urban area, the number of traffic violations the driver received in the prior twelve months, whether the vehicle had a defect, and the speed and weight of the vehicle. Stage 1 results for each specification have R-squareds above 0.5 and pass weak instruments tests. The second stage results confirm that both wives and husbands are likelier to sacrifice themselves for a spouse than another passenger. The first panel uses a spousal indicator based solely on the estimate from the first stage of the TSIV. Results from the first panel show that wives are 40 to 54 percent more likely to die when driving their husbands and husbands are 10 to 47 percent more likely to die when driving their wives. Subsequent panels and Table 3 act as robustness checks on these results. The second panel reduces the false positives from the TSIV by allocating all cars where the decedent is not married according to the MCOD decisively to the control group (i.e. setting the parameter estimated in the first stage to zero). The correction reduces both the standard errors and amplifies the treatment effect, increasing the credence of the claim that the presence of spouses drives our results. Wives become 74 to 86 percent more likely to die when driving husbands and husbands become 56 to 76 percent more likely to die when driving wives. The third and fourth panels repeat the two above after reducing the selection effect of the FARS sampling frame. These panels include only those vehicles that were involved in accidents in which at least one fatality occurred outside the vehicle, in other words, they only include those vehicles that would appear in FARS independent of whether an occupant died. Results in the third panel lose significance as sample size decreases by 95 percent. Coefficients are comparable in the first and third panels, but standard errors increase by a factor between two and three in the third panel. Significance returns in the fourth panel once false positives are removed. The fourth panel reports the highest estimate of spousal altruism with wives becoming 92 to 105 11

percent more likely to die when driving husbands, and husbands becoming 53 to 83 percent more likely to die when driving wives. The fifth panel seeks to expand the sample size for the first stage by including cars with three and four occupants when estimating the likelihood of marriage.10 Results in panel five are very close to panel one, with the measure of altruism decreasing up to three percent among wives and increasing up to four percent amongst husbands. The sixth panel shows results for the sample from first panel using a logit regression rather than a linear regression. It presents coefficients expressed as odds ratios along with pvalues. The results are consistent with those in the first panel, showing that they do not depend on a linear probability model.11 We can use the preceding results to estimate how much more spouses value each others’ lives than the lives of other passengers. If we assume that drivers face risk exchange rates under which the sum of driver and passenger risk remains constant, the product of the additional risk borne by the driver when driving with a spouse with the driver’s value of his own life provides an estimate of how much the driver would pay to preserve a spouse. If we use $10 million as the driver’s value of his own life and apply that to the increased mortality observed under the third specification appearing in the base panel, a wife values her husband an additional $5.4 million over another passenger, while a husband values his wife $3.7 million more than another passenger. B. Falisfication tests A natural question is whether our findings of altruism are spurious. To address this concern, we run a series of falsification tests reporting their results in Table 3. Specifically, we repeat the analysis in contexts where drivers are likely to exercise less or more control over the distribution of risks. If spousal altruism does not increase with control, then one might suspect a
10

The cost of increasing the sample size is introduction of a potential bias as married pairs driving with others in the

back (e.g. children) may be older or younger than non-married pairs driving with passengers in the backseat.
11

Estimation of logit regressions using samples from other panels yield similar results to corresponding linear

regressions.

12

spurious correlation. On the other hand, if control increases the likelihood drivers die when driving their spouses, our results gain in credibility. Each panel in Table 3 focuses on a different subsample of observations taken from the first panel in Table 2. The first panel focuses on intoxicated drivers. Our prior is that intoxication impairs a driver’s responsiveness to risk thus decreasing his distributive activities and leading to a convergence of results between spouses and non-spouses. The results confirm our hypothesis, as the likelihood the driver dies when driving with a spouse falls between 20 and 33 percent for female drivers, and between 37 and 58 percent for male drivers. The second panel focuses on vehicles struck in the rear. Drivers in such vehicles are less likely to be see the impact coming and be able to respond. Moreover, even if the driver is able to redirect the impact, the driver’s and passenger’s interests are aligned in that neither would benefit from the impact being shifted forward. In the absence of a conflict of interests between driver and passenger, the relative preference a driver may have for a spouse over another passenger would not be expressed. The results in panel two confirm our hypothesis, as the likelihood the driver dies when driving with a spouse falls by between 28 and 55 percent for female drivers, and 23 and 71 percent for male drivers. (Note that the sample size falls precipitously in these contexts because cars hit from behind rarely suffer fatalities and thus do not show up in our subsample of cars with at least one fatality.) The third panel exploits the same intuitions by focusing only on those vehicles that were involved in head-on collisions. The orientation of the impact makes it more likely that the driver sees it. At the same time, there is a conflict between the interests of the driver who wants to rotate the impact towards the right and those of the passenger who would be likelier to survive when the impact was shifted to the left. The results in panel three confirm our hypothesis: the likelihood the driver dies when driving with a spouse increases by between 7 and 10 percent for female drivers, and 6 and 14 percent for male drivers. The fourth panel is limited to vehicles that did not have a defect at the time of the accident. Assuming that a defect interferes with control, we would expect the limitation to amplify spousal altruism. These expectations are not met as the likelihood the driver dies when

13

driving with a spouse decrease between 1 and 3 percent for female drivers, and between 0 and 3 percent for male drivers. The fifth panel includes only those accidents that occurred on a wet surface. We would expect to see the measure of spousal altruism decrease as drivers enjoy less control on a wet surface. The results for female drivers contradict our expectations. The likelihood the driver dies when driving with a spouse increases by between 24 and 40 percent for female drivers, but decreases between -2 and 17 percent for male drivers. The sixth panel uses only those accidents that occurred in bad weather, based on the same intuition as the fifth panel. Weather is identified as bad when there is rain, sleet, snow, or fog. In line with expectations, the loss of control in bad weather decreases the measure of altruism. The likelihood the driver dies when driving with a spouse decreases by between 2 and 6 percent for female drivers, and between 3 and 6 percent for male. The seventh (last) panel looks only at those accidents occurring at night on unlit roads. The expectation is that in the absence of light, the driver will be less likely to see the threat and thus to respond to it by distributing risk. Though the effect of treatment is expected to decrease, the opposite occurs. The likelihood a driver dies when driving with a spouse increases by 20 to 40 percent for females drivers, and by 1 to 25 percent for male drivers. Our falsification tests on balance support our finding of spousal altruism. Results observed when drivers lose control to intoxication or bad weather support our results by showing that altruism decreases as drivers lose the ability to act on their preferences. Results from rearend and head-on collisions likewise support our hypothesis, whether because drivers are better able to see (and respond to) what is in front of the car than what is behind, or because alignment of interests removes distributive choices. On the other hand, results based on accidents occurring in the dark and on wet surfaces (with female drivers) suggests that reducing the driver’s control may increase the gap between spouses and non-spouses.

5. Conclusion

14

It has been said that one death is a tragedy, a million are a statistic. Without denying that our data are an aggregate of tragedies, we present the aggregate as something more. A tragedy can be appreciated. A statistic can also be learned from. Like other papers before it (Klasen 1998; Dee 2003) this paper finds evidence of spousal exchange in death. We use that evidence to reconstruct tens of thousands of real life dictator games that played out before fatal car crashes. In such contexts, drivers are natural dictators having exclusive control over the amount of risk faced by the occupants and how it is distributed between them. We provide evidence that drivers’ distributive choices depend on the identity of their passenger. Though our measures of altruism vary with panel and specification, a conservative model observes wives saving husbands 54 percent as often as other passengers, and husbands saving wives 37 percent as often as other passengers. On net, our theory survives a battery of falsification tests as the relative difference between spouses and non-spouses declines in contexts where the driver is less likely to distribute risk. If we assume that total risk faced by the occupants remains constant while the driver distributes it, our results show that wives would die for approximately two husbands, and husbands would die for approximately three wives. Even without an assumption as to the form of the risk exchange function, we provide evidence that spouses continue transfers in the moments before death – evidence that is inconsistent with a purely egotistic explanation of spousal transfers.

References

Adreoni, James, and Lise Vesterlund. Which is the Fair Sex? Gender Differences in Altruism. Q. J. Econ. 116(1) 293-312 (2001). Agarwal, Reena, and Adrew Horowitz. Are International Remittances Altruism or Insurance? Evidence from Guyana Using Multiple-Migrant Households. World Development, 30(11): 2033–2044 (2002).

15

Angrist, Joshua D., and Alan B. Krueger. The Effect of Age at School Entry on Educational Attainment: An Application of Instrumental Variables with Moments from Two Samples. J. Amer. Stat. Assoc., 87(418): 328-326 (1992). Altonji, Joseph G., Fumio Hayashi, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. Is the Extended Family Altruistically Linked? Direct Tests Using Micro Data. Am. Econ. Rev. 82(5): 1177-1198 (1992). Altonji, Joseph G., Fumio Hayashi, and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. Parental Altruism and Inter Vivos Transfers: Theory and Evidence. J. Pol. Econ 105(6): 1121-1166 (1997). Barro, Robert. Are government bonds net wealth? J. Pol. Econ., 82: 1095-1117 (1974). Becker, Gary S. Theory of Marriage: Part II. J. Pol. Econ., 82(2): S11-26 (1974). Becker, Gary S, Elisabeth M. Landes, Elisabeth M. and Robert T. Michael, An Economic Analysis of Marital Instability, J. Pol. Econ., 85: 1141-87 (1977). Becker, Gary S. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press (1981). Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Oded Stark, Altruism within the Family Reconsidered: Do Nice Guys Finish Last? Amer. Econ. Rev. 78(5): 1034-1045 (1988). Bergstrom, Theodore. A fresh look at the rotten kid theorem, J. Pol. Econ., 97: 11381159 (1989). Bergstrom, Theodore C. A Survey of Theories of the Family. In M.R. Rosenzweig and 0. Stark, eds., Handbook of Population and Family Economics. Elsevier (1997). Bonsang, Eric. How Do Middle-Aged Children Allocate Time and Money Transfers to Their Older Parents in Europe? Empirica 34(2): 171-88 (2007). Buerkle, Jack V., and Robin F. Badgley. Couple Role-Taking: The Yale Marital Interaction Battery. Marriage and Family Living. 21(1): 53-58 (1959). Chami, Ralph, and Jeffrey H. Fischer. Atruism, Matching and Nonmarket Insurance. Econ. Inquiry, 34: 630-647 (1996).

16

Chiappori, Pierre-André, Bernard Fortin, and Guy Lacroix. Marriage Market, Divorce Legislation, and Household Labor Supply. J. Pol. Econ. 110(1) 37-72 (2002). De Laat, Joost. Moral Hazard and Costly Monitoring: The Case of Split Migrants in Kenya. Job Market paper, Brown University (Nov. 2005). Dee, Thomas S. Until death do you part: The effect of unilateral divorce on spousal homicides. Econ. Inquiry, 41(1): 163-182 (2003). Finkelstein, Amy and James Poterba. Testing for Adverse Selection with “Unused Observables”. MIT Working Paper (2006). Fortin, Bernard, and Guy Lacroix. A Test for Unitary and Collective Models of Household Labor Supply. Econ. J. 107(443): 933-955 (1997). Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig. Imperfect commitment, altruism, and the family: evidence from transfer behavior in low-income rural areas. Rev. Econ. & Stat., 83(3): 389-407 (2001). Khwaja, Ahmed, Frank Sloan, and Sukyung Chung. The effects of spousal health on the decision to smoke: Evidence on consumption externalities, altruism and learning within the household. J. Risk & Uncertainty 32: 17-35 (2006). Klasen, Stephen. Marriage, Bargaining, and Intrahousehold Resource Allocation: Excess Female Mortality among Adults during Early German Development, 1740-1860. J. Econ. Hist. 58(2) 432-467 (1998). König, Markus, and Peter Zweifel. Willingness-to-pay Against Dementia: Effects of Altruism Between Patients and Their Spouse Caregivers. Unpublished manuscript (Sept. 2004). Laitner, John, and F. Thomas Justner. New Evidence on Altruism: A Study of TIAACREF Retirees. Am. Econ. Rev. 86(4) 893-908 (1996). Lundberg, Shelley, and Robert A. Pollack. Separate Spheres Bargaining and the Marriage Market. J. Pol. Econ., 100(6): 988-1010 (1993).

17

Lundberg, Shelley, and Robert A. Pollack. Noncooperative Bargaining Models of Marriage. Amer. Econ. Rev. (Papers & Proc.), 84(2): 132-137 (1994). Manser, Marilyn, and Murray Brown. Marriage and Householder Decision-Making: A Bargaining Analysis. Int’l Econ. Rev., 21(1): 31-44 (1980). McElroy, Marjorie B., and Mary J. Horney. Nash-Bargained Householde Decisions: Toward a Generalization of the Theory of Demand. Int’l Econ. Rev., 22(2): 559-583 (1981). Nordblom, Katarina. Precautionary Savings and Altruism. Uppsala - Working Paper Series, No. 19 (1997). Powdthavee, Nattavudh. I Can’t Smile Without You: A Multi-level and Fixed Effects Simultaneous Equations Analysis of Spousal Correlation in Life Satisfaction. Institute of Education, University of London working paper (Oct. 2007). Stevenson, Betsey, and Justin Wolfers. Bargaining in the shadow of the law: divorce laws and family distress. Q. J. Econ., 267-288 (2006). Zhang, Junsen, and William Chan. Dowry and Wife’s Welfare: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. J. Pol. Econ. 107(4): 786-808 (1999).

18

Table 1. Descriptve statistics for outcome and control variables in base sample, by predicted probability that married driver is riding with spouse. Female driver Below median Above median probability probability Mean SE Mean SE 0.37 0.48 0.40 0.49 Male driver Below median Above median probability probability Mean SE Mean SE 0.35 0.48 0.43 0.50

Units Driver died Specification 1 includes Age of driver Specification 2 adds Driver intoxicatred Vehicle is a car Age of vehicle Specification 3 adds Vehicle rolled over Driver-side airbag Passenger airbag Driver used seatbelt Passenger belt use Driver at fault Driver not at fault Dark out Surface was dry Rear-end collision Head-on collision Angled collision Side-swipe, same direction Side-swipe, opp direction Specification 4 adds Speed Vehicle defect Vehicle weight Bad weather Urban road Traffic viols. in last 12 mo. 0/1

Yrs

37.78

24.68

52.92

13.19

47.04

28.29

54.41

12.93

0/1 0/1 Yrs

0.31 0.68 7.06

0.46 0.47 5.20

0.23 0.60 6.57

0.42 0.49 5.20

0.28 0.67 7.40

0.45 0.47 5.55

0.23 0.53 7.15

0.42 0.50 5.90

0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1

0.40 0.22 0.17 0.47 0.38 0.76 0.29 0.31 0.85 0.028 0.104 0.164 0.064 0.005

0.49 0.42 0.37 0.50 0.48 0.43 0.46 0.46 0.36 0.165 0.305 0.370 0.245 0.070

0.39 0.22 0.16 0.56 0.46 0.72 0.34 0.24 0.81 0.053 0.118 0.181 0.055 0.007

0.49 0.41 0.37 0.50 0.50 0.45 0.47 0.43 0.39 0.225 0.323 0.385 0.228 0.083

0.32 0.21 0.16 0.46 0.44 0.71 0.34 0.28 0.82 0.047 0.104 0.231 0.069 0.006

0.46 0.41 0.36 0.50 0.50 0.45 0.47 0.45 0.38 0.213 0.305 0.421 0.253 0.080

0.32 0.20 0.15 0.51 0.50 0.71 0.35 0.26 0.78 0.062 0.172 0.204 0.053 0.008

0.46 0.40 0.35 0.50 0.50 0.45 0.48 0.44 0.41 0.241 0.377 0.403 0.223 0.089

Mph 0/1 Lb 0/1 0/1 #

66.62 0.06 3035.7 0.09 0.32 0.30

28.03 0.25 717.3 0.29 0.47 0.73

60.98 0.06 3217.2 0.14 0.27 0.21

27.81 0.25 736.4 0.35 0.44 0.63

62.70 0.07 3111.6 0.12 0.33 0.36

29.94 0.25 698.1 0.33 0.47 0.82

61.74 0.06 3281.6 0.16 0.28 0.25

28.14 0.24 748.0 0.36 0.45 0.69

Note. Dirver at fault and driver not at fault do not sum to one because there are cases where driver fault is uncertain.

19

Table 2. Results from stage 2 of TSIV estimation. Female 1 2 3 4 1 2 Male 3 4

1. Base model (linear probability model) Coeff 0.45 *** 0.40 *** Std err 0.16 0.14 R-squared 0.40 0.40 N Stage 1 296 296 N Stage 2 6174 6134 2. Base model with refined prediction Coeff 0.86 *** 0.84 *** Std err 0.10 0.10 R-squared 0.45 0.45 N Stage 2 6174 6134 3. Stage 2 excludes selected cars Coeff 0.58 Std err 0.41 R-squared 0.50 N Stage 2 244

0.54 ** 0.25 0.44 271 4897

0.52 ** 0.25 0.47 271 2008

0.47 *** 0.12 0.40 897 16954

0.42 *** 0.12 0.40 889 16864

0.37 *** 0.11 0.44 826 14591

0.10 0.09 0.48 826 5229

0.86 *** 0.11 0.49 4897

0.74 *** 0.16 0.49 2008

0.76 *** 0.05 0.45 16954

0.76 *** 0.04 0.45 16864

0.69 *** 0.04 0.48 14591

0.56 *** 0.06 0.49 5229

0.48 0.39 0.50 243

0.43 0.50 0.56 232

0.16 0.68 0.57 102

0.40 0.26 0.48 888

0.38 0.28 0.49 882

0.33 0.27 0.54 859

0.15 0.39 0.61 348

4. Stage 2 excludes selected cars and uses refined predictions Coeff 1.02 *** 0.95 *** 1.05 *** 0.92 ** Std err 0.23 0.21 0.23 0.36 R-squared 0.54 0.55 0.61 0.60 N Stage 2 244 243 232 102 5. Base model with stage 1 including 3 and 4 occupant cars Coeff 0.44 *** 0.39 *** 0.52 ** 0.49 ** Std err 0.14 0.12 0.21 0.22 R-squared 0.40 0.40 0.44 0.47 N Stage 1 336 336 309 309 N Stage 2 6174 6134 4897 2008 6. Base model estimated with logit regression Odds ratio 1.65 1.54 1.85 P-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 N Stage 2 6174 6134 4897

0.83 *** 0.11 0.52 888

0.81 *** 0.11 0.52 882

0.75 *** 0.11 0.57 859

0.53 *** 0.20 0.62 348

0.51 *** 0.13 0.40 1056 16954

0.46 *** 0.13 0.40 1047 16864

0.41 *** 0.12 0.44 978 14591

0.11 0.11 0.48 978 5229

1.80 0.00 2008

1.64 0.00 16954

1.57 0.00 16864

1.50 0.00 14591

1.11 0.27 5229

20

Table 3. Stage 2 results from falsification tests. Female 3 Male 4 5 1 2 3 4 5

1 1. Intoxicated drivers Coeff 0.17 Std err 0.20 R-squared 0.46 Obs 1670 2. Car struck in back Coeff 0.13 Std err 0.33 R-squared 0.36 Obs 231

2

0.20 0.25 0.46 1660

0.34 0.26 0.53 1270

0.19 0.37 0.59 464

0.05 1.04 0.86 47

-0.11 0.14 0.40 4255

-0.10 0.12 0.40 4243

0.00 0.13 0.46 3396

-0.33 0.27 0.56 1039

-1.40 0.79 0.64 102

0.12 0.32 0.37 230

0.00 0.41 0.47 226

0.08 0.61 0.53 103

-3.84 0.00 1.00 27

0.22 0.26 0.44 709

0.19 0.29 0.44 702

0.13 0.27 0.51 693

-0.61 0.42 0.56 296

-0.76 0.79 0.71 91

3. Cars in straight-on collisions Coeff 0.53 *** 0.50 *** Std err 0.19 0.18 R-squared 0.39 0.39 Obs 2286 2275 4. Excluding cars with defects Coeff 0.45 *** Std err 0.15 R-squared 0.40 Obs 5775 5. Wet surface Coeff Std err R-squared Obs

0.64 ** 0.30 0.44 2242

0.62 ** 0.31 0.50 866

0.33 0.45 0.58 175

0.59 *** 0.15 0.41 6806

0.56 *** 0.16 0.42 6776

0.45 *** 0.14 0.46 6692

0.16 0.14 0.50 2346

-0.22 0.29 0.54 541

0.39 *** 0.13 0.40 5738

0.52 ** 0.24 0.44 4618

0.51 ** 0.25 0.47 1900

0.43 0.33 0.51 408

0.46 *** 0.12 0.41 15860

0.42 *** 0.12 0.41 15775

0.36 *** 0.11 0.44 13741

0.08 0.09 0.48 4969

-0.04 0.19 0.51 1209

0.76 *** 0.28 0.41 1045

0.65 *** 0.24 0.42 1041

0.94 ** 0.43 0.46 918

0.90 0.69 0.56 112

1.43 0.94 0.77 61

0.49 *** 0.16 0.40 3308

0.35 ** 0.15 0.41 3293

0.37 ** 0.15 0.44 2944

-0.08 0.33 0.47 378

0.23 0.49 0.50 212

6. Bad weather Coeff 0.43 *** Std err 0.15 R-squared 0.40 Obs 5457 7. Accident was in darkness Coeff 0.70 *** Std err 0.26 R-squared 0.42 Obs 1671

0.38 *** 0.13 0.40 5420

0.49 ** 0.23 0.45 4258

0.46 * 0.24 0.48 1757

0.35 0.33 0.51 371

0.44 *** 0.11 0.40 14619

0.39 *** 0.11 0.41 14542

0.32 *** 0.10 0.44 12494

0.04 0.10 0.49 4519

-0.09 0.20 0.51 1110

0.60 *** 0.23 0.42 1662

0.90 ** 0.43 0.47 1286

0.92 * 0.53 0.52 484

1.78 1.66 0.74 74

0.47 *** 0.15 0.40 4550

0.46 *** 0.16 0.40 4527

0.53 *** 0.18 0.45 3709

0.34 * 0.21 0.51 1321

0.58 0.45 0.53 236

21

Figure 1

Married female drivers
.8 0 18-24 .2 Probability .4 .6

25-29

30-34

35-39

40-44

45-49

50-54

55-59

60-64

65-69

70-74

75-79

80-84

85+

Married male drivers
.6 0 18-24 .2 Probability .4

25-29

30-34

35-39

40-44

45-49

50-54

55-59

60-64

65-69

70-74

75-79

80-84

85+

22

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Case Study

...S w 910N29 BASEL III: AN EVALUATION OF NEW BANKING REGULATIONS1 David Blaylock wrote this case under the supervision of David Conklin solely to provide material for class discussion. The authors do not intend to illustrate either effective or ineffective handling of a managerial situation. The authors may have disguised certain names and other identifying information to protect confidentiality. Richard Ivey School of Business Foundation prohibits any form of reproduction, storage or transmission without its written permission. Reproduction of this material is not covered under authorization by any reproduction rights organization. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, contact Ivey Publishing, Richard Ivey School of Business Foundation, The University of Western Ontario, London, Ontario, Canada, N6A 3K7; phone (519) 661-3208; fax (519) 661-3882; e-mail cases@ivey.uwo.ca. Copyright © 2010, Richard Ivey School of Business Foundation Version: 2013-03-11 INTRODUCTION The world’s biggest banks have a combined 1,730 (US$2,287 billion) gap in liquid investments that they must fill within four years, according to the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, the international banking watchdog. Under the Basel III rule book, finalized by the committee on Thursday, December 16, 2010, 91 of the world’s biggest banks — tested in an impact assessment...

Words: 1769 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Banking

...Banking Research & Writing Table of content Introduction 3 Structure and functioning of UK banking system: 3 Performance measurement system 5 Trading revenues and Value-at-Risk 7 Evaluation of Regulatory Challenges of UK Universal Banking Model 9 Micro and macro prudential regulation 9 Basel II, III regulation 10 Global Financial Crises in UK 12 Conclusion 13 References 14 Introduction The UK managing an account has experienced considerable change in the course of the most recent 20 years, essentially determined by local deregulation and different strengths that have changed supply and interest qualities of the money related administrations industry. Elaboration of structure and functioning of the UK banking industry, Evaluation of Regulatory Challenges of UK Universal Banking Model and Global Financial Crises in UK is discussed further in this paper. Structure and functioning of UK banking system: The UK banking system is regularly said to be very focused and subsequently deficiently aggressive. The UK banking sector contains one market and not many markets. The UK banking system is indeed a mix of numerous separate product markets with rivalry originating from distinctive regions and diverse contenders. The High Street banks are all sizeable members in each of the business sector fragments and giving administrations to the overall population, the leading bank in each one fragment has a tendency to appear as something else. Business banking...

Words: 2870 - Pages: 12

Free Essay

Finance

...N0. 470 WORKING PAPER NO: 470 BASEL BANKING NORMS – A PRIMER Akshay Uday Shenoy PGP Student Indian Institute of Management Bangalore Bannerghatta Road, Bangalore – 560076 akshay.shenoy@iimb.ernet.in Yatin Balkrishna Mohane PGP Student Indian Institute of Management Bangalore Bannerghatta Road, Bangalore – 560076 yatin.mohane@iimb.ernet.in Charan Singh RBI Chair Professor Economics & Social Science Indian Institute of Management Bangalore Bannerghatta Road, Bangalore – 5600 76 Ph: 080-26993818 charansingh@iimb.ernet.in Year of Publication-October 2014 Basel Banking Norms – A Primer1 Abstract This paper aims to first build a deeper understanding of the emergence of Basel banking norms (Basel I), and the transition to each of the subsequent regulations (Basel II and Basel III). The primary purpose of developing this understanding is to further analyze the extent of effectiveness of the Basel norms. To explore how such regulations impact an economy, we have specifically looked at five economies of the world (including India), which are geographically apart, in this context. The idea here is to study how, for instance, banking institutions have shaped up to these norms – and whether the effects were favorable or adverse. We then conclude by conceptually looking at the future direction of regulations such as the Basel norms in the banking industry. Keywords: Banking, Financial Services, Regulation, Basel Norms, Capital Adequacy, Liquidity ...

Words: 13616 - Pages: 55

Premium Essay

Is Basel Iii a Better Support to Islamic Banks Than Basel Ii?

...Is Basel III a better support to Islamic banks than Basel II? International Interdisciplinary Conference On Changes, Challenges and Consequences In Commerce, Engineering, Technology and Social Science. Institute of Business Management and Research, Chakan & Choice Institute of Management Studies and Research, pune, 15th March, 2014. Dr. Atmaram palnitkar Research Guide& Principal of Dayanand College OF Commerce, Latur. palnitkarav@rediffmail.com&9423347478 Abdul-Jabbar Qasem Ali Al-badaani Research Scholar of Com and Magt Sci, SRTM University, Nanded. Amaf3600@gmail.com&7709670130 ------------------------------------------------- ------------------------------------------------- ABSTRACT Banking activities involve many risks calculated and otherwise. Banks have to take appropriate measures and require management of their capital and credit and implementation procedures in keeping with the best international practices, to mitigate potential losses and avoid projected pitfalls. In view of the recent financial crisis, due to wrong management or improper implementation as well as the collapse of large economies has had a cascading effect all round the world in the form of collapses of famous institutions and banks, and thus arose a decision to have a better financial control in the form of Basel I to be later followed by Basel II and Basel III. Thus a new culture in financial controls and risk management has arisen to safeguard the banking industry...

Words: 3374 - Pages: 14

Premium Essay

Avimnvygvhvbjkbvkjb

...inputs are designed to accomplish the following objectives. * To help students to understand the role and functions of Commercial Banks, main strategic issues in retail and corporate banking and the risks faced by the Banking Industry in India. * To familiarise the students with the new Banking Practices and Processes including new banking technologies. * To familiarise the students with the legal and regulatory framework for banks in India. * To equip the students with the tools and techniques used in interpreting and evaluating the performance, profitability, productivity, and efficiency of the Commercial Banks. * To equip the students with the in-depth knowledge of Bank Financial Management Process including Treasury, Investment, Asset Liability Management & Risk Management. * To equip the students with the in-depth knowledge and skills in Credit Analysis & Appraisal Processes relating to the banks’ lending decisions like Working Capital Financing, Term Loan & Project Financing, Domestic & International Trade Finance including Export-Import Finance, BG (LG) & LC, Retail Asset Financing like Home Loans, Car Loans, Educational Loans, Gold Loans, Loans ag. Securities, Personal and Credit Card Loans. * To understand and appreciate customer-focused banking, integrated risk management like interest-rate risk, liquidity risk, market risk,...

Words: 2603 - Pages: 11

Free Essay

The Effects of Bank Regulation on the Relationship Between Capital and Risk

...palgrave-journals.com/ces/ Survey Article The Effects of Bank Regulation on the Relationship Between Capital and Risk ALESSANDRA TANDA Department of Economics, Management and Quantitative Methods, Università degli Studi di Milano, Via Conservatorio, 7, Milan 20122, Italy. E-mail: alessandra.tanda@unimi.it Capital regulation acts as an external force in the determination of bank capital and risk levels. Changes in the regulatory framework can influence banks’ decisions. Starting from the debate of the prudential regulation after the financial crisis, this paper reviews the main empirical contributions on the role of capital regulation in the determination of banks’ capital ratios and risk exposure to evaluate bank behavior. Capital and risk decisions seem to be effectively influenced by regulation, although results may vary according to factors such as time period, country, and the type of capital analyzed. Comparative Economic Studies (2015) 57, 31–54. doi:10.1057/ces.2014.35; published online 22 January 2015 Keywords: bank regulation, capital, Basel, risk, literature review JEL Classification: G2 INTRODUCTION The latest financial crisis has highlighted how bank capital regulation is necessary for the stability of the financial system. But also, it appears that it is not sufficient to ensure that banks’ decisions, in terms of risk and capital, are consistent with the aims of regulation. Regulation acts as an external force in the capital optimization process...

Words: 4380 - Pages: 18

Free Essay

Basel (I Ii Iii)

...THE BASEL CAPITAL ACCORDS BY JOE LARSON APRIL 2011 I. Introduction Banks are a vital part of a nation’s economy. In their traditional role as financial intermediaries, banks serve to meet the demand of those who need funding. As such, banks make it possible for people to buy homes and for businesses to expand. Banks therefore facilitate spending and investment, which fuel growth in the economy. However, despite their important role in the economy, banks are nevertheless susceptible to failure. Banks, like any other business, can go bankrupt. However, unlike most other businesses, the failure of banks, especially very large ones, can have far-reaching implications. As we saw during the Great Depression and, most recently, during the global financial crisis and the ensuing recession, the health of the bank system (or lack thereof) can trigger economic calamities affecting millions of people. Consequently, it is imperative that banks operate in a safe and sound manner to avoid failure. One way to ensure this is for governments to provide diligent regulation of banks. Yet, with the advent of globalization, banking activities are no longer confined to the borders of any individual country. With cross-border banking activities rapidly increasing, the need for international cooperation in bank regulation has likewise increased. Ready to meet this need is the Basel Committee on Bank Supervision (BCBS). In its role as the international advisory authority on bank regulation, the BCBS...

Words: 9857 - Pages: 40

Premium Essay

Strategic Analysis of Danske Bank

...&  strategic  analysis  regarding  the  post-­‐financial-­‐crisis  environment     3  December  2014           Strategic  Management   Fall  2014     Authored  by:     Stefan  Garval   040594STG1     Collin  Gibbons   281293COG1     Spencer  Gliddon   260394SPG1       Table  of  Contents   1.  Introduction  ......................................................................................................................................  3   1.1  Background  ................................................................................................................................................  3   1.2  Problem  formulation  ..............................................................................................................................  3   1.3  Market  definition  .....................................................................................................................................  4   1.4  Methodology  ..............................................................................................................................................  4   2.  The  External  Environment  ...........................................................................................................  4   ...

Words: 4783 - Pages: 20

Premium Essay

Basel 3 Norms Rbi

...Regional Rural Banks) Madam / Dear Sir, Guidelines on Implementation of Basel III Capital Regulations in India Please refer to the paragraph 90 (extract enclosed) of the Monetary Policy Statement 2012-13 announced on April 17, 2012. It was indicated that the final guidelines on the implementation of Basel III capital regulations would be issued by end - April 2012. It may be recalled that draft proposals on Basel III capital regulations were issued vide circular DBOD.No.BP.BC.71/ 21.06.201/ 2011-12 dated December 30, 2011. 2. The final guidelines on Basel III capital regulations are enclosed. These guidelines would become effective from January 1, 2013 in a phased manner. The Basel III capital ratios will be fully implemented as on March 31, 2018. 3. The capital requirements for the implementation of Basel III guidelines may be lower during the initial periods and higher during the later years. While undertaking the capital planning exercise, banks should keep this in view. 4. RBI is currently working on operational aspects of implementation of the Countercyclical Capital Buffer. Guidance to banks on this will be issued in due course. Besides, certain other proposals viz. ‘Definition of Capital Disclosure Requirements’, ‘Capitalisation of Bank Exposures to Central Counterparties’ etc., are also engaging the attention of the Basel Committee 1    at present. Therefore, the final proposals of the Basel Committee on these aspects will be considered for implementation, to...

Words: 15967 - Pages: 64

Free Essay

Washinton Consensus

...THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW SOUTH WALES AUSTRALIAN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS SCHOOL OF BANKING & FINANCE FINS 3650 / FINS 5550 INTERNATIONAL BANKING Course Outline Semester 2, 2011 This Part A is specific to this course. Part B relating to general bumpf is separately posted. TABLE OF CONTENTS   1.  Lecturer Contact Details 2.  Course Details 2.1.  Teaching Times and Locations — FINS 3650 2.2.  Teaching Times and Locations — FINS 5550 2.3.  Units of Credit 2.4.  Summary of Course 2.5.  Course Aims and Relationship to Other Courses — FINS 5550 2.6.  Course Aims and Relationship to Other Courses — FINS 3650 2.7.  Student Learning Outcomes 2.8.  ASB Graduate Attributes 3.  Learning and Teaching activities 3.1.  Lectures, Preparation, and Postparation (a new work I just made up) 3.2.  Course Materials 3.3.  The Lectures Themselves 4.  Assessment 4.1.  General Approach 4.2.  Formal Requirements 4.3.  Examination Details 4.4.  Assignment Submission Procedure 4.5.  Late Submission 4.6.  Quality Assurance 5.  Course Evaluation and Development 6.  Other Thoughts 6.1.  Inappropriate Behaviour 6.2.  Workload 6.3.  Attendance 7.  Course Topics 7.1.  Introduction to International Banking 7.2.  Bank Regulation, Risk, and Capital Management 7.3.  Interest Rates 7.4.  Liquidity 7.5.  Credit 7.6.  Trading and Investment Banking 7.7.  Securitisation and the Global Financial Crisis 7.8.  Payments 7.9.  Operational Risk 7.10.  Money Laundering 1  1  1  1  1  1  2  2  2  2  3  3  3  4  4  4  4  5  6  6 ...

Words: 3334 - Pages: 14

Premium Essay

Risk Management Cw1

...Marylebone Bank is currently holdings investments in five FTSE companies in banking industry, also holdings certain assets of cash and equity. The report sets the bank’s capital requirement with the requirement of Basel Accords in order to build up sustainable positive capital frequently to avoid losses, liabilities and liquidity. Firstly, the report analyzes the risk management under current assets of Marylebone by applying the VaR methods, such as Variance – Covariance, Historical Simulation and Extended Historical Simulation, in order to have criticisms under each method on the effectiveness. The reports will continuously measure and manage each category under Basel Accords regulation: Market Risk, Credit Risk and Operational Risk. Furthermore, all five Basel Accords including: Basel 1(1988 BIS Accord), Basel 1 (1996 Amendment), Basel 2, Basel 2.5 and Basel 3 will be taken into account in order to develop the framework in details. Finally, the report concludes with the core concept of capital, the influences of risk management and capital requirement under the banking regulation using example of the most recent Global Recession. TABLE OF CONTENT I. Introduction 4 II. Market Risk Capital Charge Estimation 4 1. Variance - Covariance Method 4 2. Historical Simulation Method 5 III. Credit Risk and Operational Risk Estimation under different Basel Accords 6 3. Under Basel 1 (1988 BIS Accord) 6 1.1 On-balance-sheet calculation 7 ...

Words: 4074 - Pages: 17

Free Essay

Business

...Risk Based Capital (Basel II) for Banks in Bangladesh: A straightforward Journey Abu Hena Mohd. Razee Hassan K. M Abdul Wadood Abstract Banks operating in Bangladesh are much enthusiastic for maintaining risk based capital in line with Basel II. Self audit report 2008 on compliance with Basel Core Principles (BCPs) shows, Operational independence of Bangladesh Bank, supervisory tools, existing prudential regulations for core risk management as introduced in banking industry by BB has developed an environment is favorable for implementing Basel II. Bangladesh Bank (BB) has commenced the implementation of Basel II from January 2009 and has provided banks guideline for computing Minimum Capital requirement (MCR) on the basis of Risk Weighted Assets (RWA). The techniques of calculation of RWA will follow Standardized Approach for Credit Risk, Standardized (Rule Based) Approach for Market Risk and Basic Indicator Approach for Operational Risk. In Standardized Approach risk weight of exposures will be differentiated based on external credit assessments and the risk weights will be inversely related to the credit rating of the counter party. Calculation of RWA under Standardized Approach is supported by External Credit Assessment Institute (ECAI). The recognition process of BB will ensure ECAIs eligibility criteria as required by the Basel II document. In addition to computing MCR banks have to calculate adequate capital with the procedure as stated in the section second pillar or...

Words: 4270 - Pages: 18

Free Essay

Credit Rating Agency of Bangladesh

...Internship Report Impact of Credit Rating on Corporate and Banking Sectors of Bangladesh A Study based on Ratings of Credit Rating Agency of Bangladesh Limited (CRAB) Exam Roll: 091127 Internship Report on Impact of Credit Rating on Corporate and Banking Sector of Bangladesh A Study based on Ratings of Credit Rating Agency of Bangladesh Ltd. (CRAB) Prepared For: Chairman Internship Placement Committee Prepared by: Exam Roll Number: 019927 Class ID: 892 4th year, 8th semester Batch Number: 18th, BBA Program Academic Session: 2008-09 Institute of Business Administration (IBA-JU) Jahangirnagar University, Savar, Dhaka 1342 Date: 16.02.2013 Letter of Transmittal February 16, 2013 Chairman Internship Placement Committee Institute of Business Administration Jahangirnagar University Savar, Dhaka 1342. Subject: Submission of Internship Report Dear Sir, It is an event of great pleasure for me to prepare and present the internship report on ‘Impact of Credit Rating on Corporate and Banking Sectors of Bangladesh: A Study based on Rating of Credit Rating Agency of Bangladesh Limited (CRAB)’ which is a requirement for the completion of BBA program. In this report I have tried to identify different aspects of the credit rating service and its impact on the corporate and banking sectors of the country. I have tried my best to organize all relevant information and do according to the instructions of preparing...

Words: 12313 - Pages: 50

Free Essay

Basel Iii: an Evaluation of New Banking Regulations

...Case#1 Page 1 Basel III: An Evaluation of New Banking Regulations Q#1 – Discuss the relationship between the capital base of banks and the 2007-2010 financial crisis and Great Depression (120 words)  Most Economists would agree that the 2007-2010 crisis, was the worst global financial crisis since the great depression. During both of these times, the capital base of banks was severely compromised. Therefore, bank regulations are needed to improve the quality of banks’ capital base to become more resilient during economical crisis. During the Great Depression, major banks failures resulted after the stock market crash. These failures began as debtors defaulted on loans and depositors withdrew their deposits en masse. Outstanding debt increased as prices and income fell. Bank failures increased as desperate banks called loans yet, borrowers did not have the time or money to pay. In addition, capital investment slowed and banks struggled to build up their capital reserves by making fewer loans. Many would say that the Federal Reserve allowed the money supply to shrink to 1/3 and transformed what was a normal recession to the Great Depression by restricting emergency lending to failing banks. However, the Federal Reserve could not react in part because the Federal Reserve Act, which required 40% gold backing of Federal Reserve notes issued. During this time, the Federal Reserve hit this allowable credit limit. Reduced capital reserves resulted in many...

Words: 526 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Bala

...RBI/2013-14/70 DBOD.No.BP.BC.2 /21.06.201/2013-14 July 1, 2013 All Scheduled Commercial Banks (Excluding Local Area Banks and Regional Rural Banks) Madam / Sir, Master Circular – Basel III Capital Regulations Please refer to the Master Circular No.DBOD.BP.BC.16/21.06.001/2012-13 dated July 2, 2012, consolidating therein the prudential guidelines issued to banks till that date on Capital Adequacy and Market Discipline - New Capital Adequacy Framework (NCAF). 2. As you are aware, Basel III Capital Regulations is being implemented in India with effect from April 1, 2013 in a phased manner. Accordingly, instructions contained in the aforesaid Master Circular have been suitably updated / amended by incorporating relevant guidelines, issued up to June 30, 2013 and is being issued as Master Circular on ‘Basel III Capital Regulations’. 3. The Basel II guidelines as contained in the Master Circular DBOD.No.BP.BC.9/21.06.001/2013-14 dated July 1, 2013 on ‘Prudential Guidelines on Capital Adequacy and Market Discipline- New Capital Adequacy Framework (NCAF)’ may, however, be referred to during the Basel III transition period for regulatory adjustments / deductions up to March 31, 2017. Yours faithfully, (Chandan Sinha) Principal Chief General Manager Encl.: As above Department of Banking Operations and Development, Central Office, 12th Floor, Central Office Building, SBS Marg, Mumbai-1 , , 12 , , , , – 400 001 Tel No: 022-2266 1602 /Fax No: 022-2270 5691 Email ID:...

Words: 72826 - Pages: 292