Free Essay

Good to Know

In:

Submitted By SKRITT
Words 30009
Pages 121
Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

The economics of small business ®nance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the ®nancial growth cycle
Allen N. Berger a a,b,*

, Gregory F. Udell

c

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC 20551, USA b Wharton Financial Institutions Center, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA c Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405, USA

Abstract This article examines the economics of ®nancing small business in private equity and debt markets. Firms are viewed through a ®nancial growth cycle paradigm in which different capital structures are optimal at di€erent points in the cycle. We show the sources of small business ®nance, and how capital structure varies with ®rm size and age. The interconnectedness of small ®rm ®nance is discussed along with the impact of the macroeconomic environment. We also analyze a number of research and policy issues, review the literature, and suggest topics for future research. Ó 1998 Published by Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classi®cation: G21; G28; G34; E58; L89 Keywords: Venture capital; Small business lending; Bank; Mergers

1. Introduction The role of the entrepreneurial enterprise as an engine of economic growth has garnered considerable public attention in the 1990s. Much of this focus

*

Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 202 452 2903; fax: 1 202 452 5295; e-mail: aberger@frb.gov.

0378-4266/98/$19.00 Ó 1998 Published by Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII S 0 3 7 8 - 4 2 6 6 ( 9 8 ) 0 0 0 3 8 - 7

614

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

stems from the belief that innovation ± particularly in the high tech, information, and bio-technology areas ± is vitally dependent on a ¯ourishing entrepreneurial sector. The spectacular success stories of companies such as Microsoft, Genentech, and Federal Express embody the sense that new venture creation is the sine qua non of future productivity gains. Other recent phenomena have further focused public concern and awareness on small business, including the central role of entrepreneurship to the emergence of Eastern Europe, ®nancial crises that have threatened credit availability to small business in Asia and elsewhere, and the growing use of the entrepreneurial alternative for those who have been displaced by corporate restructuring in the US. Accompanying this heightened popular interest in the general area of small business has been an increased interest by policy makers, regulators, and academics in the nature and behavior of the ®nancial markets that fund small businesses. At the core of this issue are questions about the type of ®nancing growing companies need and receive at various stages of their growth, the nature of the private equity and debt contracts associated with this ®nancing, and the connections and substitutability among these alternative sources of ®nance. Beyond this interest in the micro-foundations of small business ®nance is a growing interest in the macroeconomic implications of small business ®nance. For example, the impact of the US ``credit crunch'' of the early 1990s and the e€ect of the consolidation of the banking industry on the availability of credit to small business have also been the subject of much research over the past several years. Similarly, the ``credit channels'' of monetary policy ± mechanisms through which monetary policy shocks may have disproportionately large effects on small business funding ± has generated considerable analysis and debate. Other key issues, such as the link between the initial public o€ering (IPO) market and venture capital ¯ows, prudent man rules regarding institutional investing in venture capital, and the role of small ®rm ®nance in ®nancial system architecture are just beginning to attract research attention. The private markets that ®nance small businesses are particularly interesting because they are so di€erent from the public markets that fund large businesses. The private equity and debt markets o€er highly structured, complex contracts to small businesses that are often acutely informationally opaque. This is in contrast to the public stock and bond markets that fund relatively informationally transparent large businesses under contracts that are more often relatively generic. Financial intermediaries play a critical role in the private markets as information producers who can assess small business quality and address information problems through the activities of screening, contracting, and monitoring. Intermediaries screen potential customers by conducting due diligence, including the collection of information about the business, the market in which it operates, any collateral that may be pledged, and the entrepreneur or startup team. This may involve the use of information garnered from existing

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

615

relationships of the intermediary with the business, the business owner, or other involved parties. The intermediary then uses this information about the initial quality of the small business to set contract terms at origination (price, fraction of ownership, collateral, restrictive covenants, maturity, etc.). Contract design and payo€ structure are chosen on the basis of the ®nancial characteristics of the ®rm and the entrepreneur as well as the ®rm's prospects and the associated information problems. High risk-high growth enterprises whose assets are mostly intangible more often obtain external equity, whereas relatively low risk-low growth ®rms whose assets are mostly tangible more often receive external debt for reasons explored below. Finally, in order to keep the ®rm from engaging in exploitive activities or strategies, the intermediary monitors the ®rm over the course of the relationship to assess compliance and ®nancial condition, and exerts control through such means as directly participating in managerial decision making by venture capitalists or renegotiating waivers on loan covenants by commercial banks. The papers in this special issue were drawn from a conference held at New York University in May 1997 sponsored by the Berkley Center for Entrepreneurial Studies and the New York University Salomon Center. They consist of full-length research papers, discussants' comments on these papers, and shorter contributions based on panel discussions. The topics span a wide variety of key issues, including venture capital and going public (Trester, 1998; Thakor, 1998; Bergemann and Hege, 1998; Lerner, 1998b; Benveniste et al., 1998; Flannery, 1998), angel ®nance (Lerner, 1998a; Prowse, 1998; Acs and Tarpley, 1998), the impact of ®nancial institution consolidation on small business lending (Peek and Rosengren, 1998; Strahan and Weston, 1998; Rosen, 1998b; Goldberg and White, 1998; DeYoung, 1998), relationship lending (Berlin and Mester, 1998; Houston and James, 1998; Pagano, 1998; Angelini et al., 1998; Kashyap, 1998; Cole, 1998; Duca, 1998), issues in credit availability (Hancock and Wilcox, 1998; Eisenbeis, 1998; Avery et al., 1998; Mann, 1998), the availability of new data sources for research on small business (Wolken, 1998; Fenn and Liang, 1998; Dunkelberg, 1998), and the future of small business ®nance (Gompers, 1998; Rosen, 1998a; Meyer, 1998). This special issue and the conference on which it is based have several motivations. The ®rst is to provide as complete a picture as possible of the nature of the private equity and debt markets in which small businesses are ®nanced based on currently available research and data. The second is to draw connections between various strands of the theoretical and empirical literature that have in the past focused on speci®c aspects of small ®rm ®nance but often have not captured the complexity of small business ®nance and the alternative sources of funding available to these ®rms. The third goal is to extend research in key areas related to the markets, contracts, and institutions associated with small ®rm ®nance. Finally, we wish to highlight important issues for future research and the relatively new data sources available to address these issues.

616

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

We proceed in Section 2 with a discussion of the idiosyncratic nature of small business ®nance, the private markets that provide this ®nance, and an overview of key research issues. In Sections 3 and 4, we examine more closely the extant literatures on private equity markets and private debt markets, respectively. Section 5 discusses the vulnerability of small business ®nance to the macroeconomic environment. Section 6 draws some tentative conclusions and suggests areas for future research. 2. An overview of small business ®nance and key research issues Perhaps the most important characteristic de®ning small business ®nance is informational opacity. Unlike large ®rms, small ®rms do not enter into contracts that are publicly visible or widely reported in the press ± contracts with their labor force, their suppliers, and their customers are generally kept private. In addition, small businesses do not issue traded securities that are continuously priced in public markets and (in the US) are not registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). Moreover, many of the smallest ®rms do not have audited ®nancial statements that can be shared with any provider of outside ®nance. As a result, small ®rms often cannot credibly convey their quality. Moreover, small ®rms may have diculty building reputations to signal high quality or nonexploitive behavior to overcome informational opacity. The private equity and debt markets we study here o€er specialized mechanisms to address these diculties. As noted above, the ®nancial intermediaries that operate in these markets actively screen, contract with, and monitor the small businesses they invest in over the course of their relationships to help resolve these information problems. Indeed, it can be argued that the modern theory of ®nancial intermediation ± which motivates intermediaries as delegated monitors on behalf of investors (e.g., Diamond, 1984; Ramakrishnan and Thakor, 1984; Boyd and Prescott, 1986) ± is mostly a theory that applies to the provision of intermediated ®nance in private markets to small, informationally opaque ®rms. 2.1. Data on small business ®nance The feature of small business ®nance that makes it the most interesting to study, informational opacity, also has made it one of the most dicult ®elds in which to conduct empirical research until recently. Small businesses are generally not publicly traded and therefore are not required to release ®nancial information on 10K forms, and their data are not collected on CRSP tapes or other data sets typically employed in corporate ®nance research. Some data are collected on lending by regulated ®nancial institutions like commercial banks and thrifts, but these data traditionally were not broken down by the size

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

617

of the borrower. Although a few surveys have been conducted on small businesses, these data were not widely circulated among researchers. The lack of detailed micro data on small businesses and the funds they raise in private equity and debt markets is likely a major reason why ± until very recently ± small business ®nance has been one of the most underresearched areas in ®nance. However, this situation is changing rapidly, as several data sets have recently become available that make it much easier to describe the state of small business ®nance and to test the extant theories of ®nancial intermediation and informational opacity. Data sets with information on US small ®rms include the National Survey of Small Business Finances (NSSBF) and National Federation of Independent Business survey (NFIB), both of which canvas small businesses for their balance sheet and income data and their use of ®nancial intermediaries, trade credit, and other sources of funds. These data allow for tests of research questions regarding the cost and availability of di€erent types of external ®nance and how the cost and availability vary with the characteristics of the small ®rms. The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) collects detailed ®nancial information from households, including their ownership of small businesses, and whether they also lend to these ®rms or provide support through the pledging of personal collateral or through loan guarantees. These data allow for tests of the roles of personal wealth and other personal characteristics in ®nancing small businesses. The Survey of Terms of Bank Lending (STBL) provides detailed information since 1977 on the contract terms on some of the individual loans issued by a sample of banks, including the largest banks in the U.S. Beginning in 1997, the STBL includes the banks' risk ratings on their individual loans, and data on loans issued by agencies and branches of foreign banks (Brady et al., 1998). Bank call reports (CALL) since 1993 have provided data on the number and total dollar values of loans issued to businesses with small amounts of bank credit. Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) data that were ®rst collected in 1997 help augment these data by giving more information on the size of the borrowers (annual revenues above versus below $1 million), and their location by census tract (Bostic and Canner, 1998). The STBL, CALL, and CRA data sources allow researchers to test the empirical connections between bank characteristics and the supply of small business credit. Detailed data on private equity markets are considerably sparser than data on private debt markets, but some progress is being made here as well. Venture Economics and VentureOne provide information on venture capital markets, data on both venture capital and angel ®nance may be gleaned from the NSSBF, some data on angel ®nance is obtainable from the SCF, and the Small Business Administration (SBA) provides some information on Small Business Investment Companies (SBICs). Details about these data sets, their uses in research, and how to gain access to them are provided in special issue panel discussions by Wolken (NSSBF, SCF, STBL, CALL, CRA, others), Dunkelberg (NFIB), and Fenn and Liang (Venture Economics, VentureOne, others).

618

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Data on small ®rms and their suppliers of external ®nance have also been generated recently in other countries and have been used in recent research efforts. These include data from Eastern Europe (Karsai et al., 1997), Germany (Elsas and Krahnen, 1997; Harho€ and Korting, 1997), Italy (Angelini et al., 1998), Norway (Ongena and Smith, 1997), Russia (Cook, 1997), Trinidad/Tobago (Storey, 1997), and the UK (Cressy and Toivanen, 1997; Wright et al., 1997). The problems of small business ®nance likely apply with even greater force to small businesses in developing nations, but very little data are available from these nations (White, 1995). 2.2. US small business ®nance at a glance We next take a look at US data. Table 1 shows the distribution of ®nance for US small business ®nance across types of private equity and debt. The data in Table 1 are drawn primarily from the 1993 NSSBF and are book values weighted to represent all nonfarm, non®nancial, nonreal-estate US businesses as a whole, using the SBA classi®cation of ®rms with fewer than 500 full-time equivalent employees. We caution that these data are not completely accurate or consistent, and should be considered rough estimates intended only to give a general idea of where small businesses receive their funding. Table 1 shows that like large corporations, small businesses depend on both equity (49.63%) and debt (50.37%). We have broken down funding sources into four categories of equity and nine categories of debt. Panel A shows that the biggest equity category is funds provided by the ``principal owner'' at 31.33% of total equity plus debt or about two-thirds of total equity. The principal owner is typically the person who has the largest ownership share and has the primary authority to make ®nancial decisions. The next biggest equity category is ``other equity'' at 12.86%, which includes other members of the startup team, family, and friends. ``Angel ®nance'' accounts for an estimated 3.59%, but this is less precise than the other ®gures in our tables. 1 ``Angels'' are high
1 Angel ®nance estimates range from $15 billion to $120 billion. The lower bound is estimated based on NSSBF information on the number of small business corporations that raise equity from outside investors and from existing shareholders that are likely to be angel investors. Annual investments originated are estimated to average between $250,000 and $400,000 each for about 10,000 companies, or about $2.5 billion to $4.0 billion total invested. Assuming an average investment period of six years, these origination data suggest a steady state of between $15 billion and $24 billion outstanding. The upper bound is based on data from surveys of private investors and those with net worth of more than $1 million summarized in Freear et al. (1994). They suggest that angels provide between $10 billion and $20 billion of total new investments to about 30,000 companies each year. Based on an average investment period of six years, these data would imply between $60 billion and $120 billion in angel ®nance outstanding. We choose the lower bound of the information drawn from the survey data on investors because the NSSBF does not directly ask about angel ®nance, and emphasize the caveat that this is a very imprecise estimate.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

619

net worth individuals who provide direct funding to early-stage new businesses. Venture capital ± intermediated funds that are provided in a more formal market than angel ®nance ± provide 1.85% of small business ®nance. 2 About 80% of venture capital is provided by independent limited partnership venture capital funds, with much of the remainder provided by subsidiaries of ®nancial institutions, including bank holding companies. The nine categories of debt are divided into three categories of funding provided by ®nancial institutions (commercial banks providing 18.75% of total ®nance, ®nance companies 4.91%, and other ®nancial institutions 3.00%), three categories provided by non®nancial and government sources (trade credit 15.78%, other business 1.74%, and government 0.49%), and three categories provided by individuals (principal owner 4.10%, credit cards 0.14%, 3 and other individuals 1.47%). These statistics reveal that the largest sources of ®nance for small businesses are the principal owner (including owner's equity, loans, and credit card debt), commercial banks, and trade creditors, which together account for 70.10% of total funding. Panels B and C of Table 1 break out the data by size and age of the small business, respectively, and this same general result holds throughout ± these three sources are the largest three for every size and age group, and in all cases provide more than half of total funds. Nonetheless, there are some interesting di€erences. As might be expected, ``larger'' small businesses (more than 20 employees or more than $1 million in sales) have lower shares of funding provided by the principal owner through equity, principal owner loans, or credit cards; receive more funding from commercial banks and ®nance companies; and are more highly levered overall than ``smaller'' small businesses. Space constraints prevent extended discussion here, but we will discuss some surprising results by ®rm age in our discussion next about the ®nancial growth cycle of small business. 4

2 The use of the term ``venture capital'' is not uniform. Sometimes it refers to any external equity investment in a new or early stage venture, including angel ®nance. However, we wish to distinguish between the informal angel ®nance market and the formal intermediated venture capital market to which we refer here. 3 Credit card debt includes both the ®rm's credit card debt and the owner's credit card debt when used for ®rm purchases because these two are not separable in the data. We place the total under the principal owner here in order not to understate the owner's contribution to funding the ®rm, although the total is so small that it is unlikely to create much error either way. 4 One source of ®nance not shown in Table 1 ± which is neither conventional equity nor conventional debt ± is ®nance from certain types of strategic alliances. In some cases, a large ®rm provides funding for R&D or other activity to a small ®rm in exchange for future considerations, such as the right to market the small ®rmÕs product when it is ready for market. This occurs in many small biotechnology companies, which have high growth potential, but require large amounts of capital for R&D several years before their products are likely to come to market (Majewski, 1997).

620

Table 1 US small business ®nance at a glance: estimated distributions of equity and debt, percent of total equity plus debt (top numbers), and billions of dollars (bottom numbers) Sources of debt Financial institutions a Non®nancial business Individuals and government Total equity plus debt

Sources of equity

Principal owner

b

Angel Ven- Other Total ®ture equity equity nance capital

Com- FiOther mercial nance ®n. banks com- insts. panies 15.78% 1.74% 0.49% $264.1 $29.2 $8.1 11.81% 1.06% 0.37% $46.6 $4.2 $1.4 17.01% 1.95% 0.52% $217.5 $25.0 $6.7

Trade Other Govt. credit c business

Prin- Credit Other Total cipal card e indi- debt ownviduer d als

A: All nonfarm, non®nancial, nonreal-estate small businesses f 31.33% 3.59% 1.85% 12.86% 49.63% 18.75% 4.91% 3.00% $524.3 $60.0 $31.0 $215.2 $830.6 $313.8 $82.1 $50.1 n.a. n.a. 47.67% 19.94% 5.47% 2.83% $609.6 $255.0 $70.0 $36.2 56.00% 14.88% 3.08% 3.53% $220.9 $58.7 $12.1 $13.9

4.10% 0.14% 1.47% 50.37% 100.00% $68.5 $2.4 $24.5 $842.9 $1,673.4 5.59% 0.53% 3.16% 44.00% 100.00% $22.1 $2.1 $12.5 $173.6 $394.5 3.63% 0.02% 0.94% 52.33% 100.00% $46.5 $0.3 $12.0 $669.3 $1,278.9

n.a.

B: Breakout by size of small business ``Smaller'' (`20 44.53% n.a. $175.7 employees & `$1 mill.sales) ``Larger'' ( P 20 27.22% n.a. employees or P $1 $348.1 mill.sales) n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

n.a.

C: Breakout by age of small business ``Infant'' (0±2 years) 19.61% n.a. $8.6 ``Adolescent'' (3±4 17.37% n.a. years) $25.1 ``Middle-Aged'' (5±24 31.94% n.a. years) $324.9 35.42% n.a. ``Old'' (25 or more years) $165.8 47.90% $21.1 39.37% $56.8 48.00% $488.2 56.50% $264.5 15.66% $6.9 30.84% $44.5 17.86% $181.6 17.25% $80.8 8.33% $3.7 2.51% $3.6 5.85% $59.5 3.28% $15.3 3.84% $1.7 2.36% $3.4 2.87% $29.2 3.38% $15.8

n.a.

13.40% $5.9 13.42% $19.4 17.10% $174.0 13.86% $64.9

1.52% $0.7 1.06% $1.5 2.39% $24.3 0.56% $2.6

0.33% $0.1 0.72% $1.0 0.44% $4.4 0.54% $2.5

6.04% $2.7 6.19% $8.9 3.91% $39.7 3.68% $17.2

0.21% $0.1 0.20% $0.3 0.17% $1.7 0.06% $0.3

2.77% $1.2 3.32% $4.8 1.42% $14.4 0.88% $4.1

52.10% $23.0 60.63% $87.4 52.00% $528.9 43.50% $203.6

100.00% $44.1 100.00% $144.2 100.00% $1,017.1 100.00% $468.0

Financial Institutions include commercial banks, ®nance companies, thrift institutions, leasing companies, brokerage ®rms, mortgage companies, and insurance companies. b For proprietorships, principal owner's share of equity is by de®nition 100%. c Trade credit is de®ned as accounts payable for year-end 1992. d Only partnerships and corporations have principal owner loans. By de®nition, proprietorships do not have loans from owners. e Credit card debt is estimated using the typical monthly balances of business charges to both personal and business credit cards after monthly payments were made on these accounts. Personal and business totals could not be accurately separated using the NSSBF data. f Represents enterprises with fewer than 500 full-time equivalent employees, excluding real estate operators and lessors, real estate subdividers and developers, real estate investment trusts, agricultural enterprises, ®nancial institutions, not-for-pro®t institutions, government entities, and subsidiaries controlled by other corporations. Sources: All data except for angel ®nance and venture capital are from the 1993 National Survey of Small Business Finance (NSSBF). These data are weighted to replicate to nation's small business population as a whole, and were produced by Nicole Meleney. The NSSBF data are from year-end 1993, except that the principal owner's equity, total equity, and trade credit are from balance sheets at year-end 1992, and credit card debt is from typical monthly balances during 1993. The angel ®gure is based on survey data summarized in Freear et al. (1994) and should be considered to be just one point in a large range (see text). The venture ®gure is estimated from data in Venture Economics using methods employed in Fenn et al. (1997). The angel and venture estimates are not available (n.a.) by ®rm size or age. A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

a

621

622

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

2.3. The ®nancial growth cycle of small business Small business may be thought of as having a ®nancial growth cycle in which ®nancial needs and options change as the business grows, gains further experience, and becomes less informationally opaque. Fig. 1 shows this in a stylized fashion in which ®rms lie on a size/age/information continuum. Smaller/younger/more opaque ®rms lie near the left end of the continuum indicating that they must rely on initial insider ®nance, trade credit, and/or angel ®nance. 5 We de®ne initial insider ®nance as funds provided by the start-up team, family, and friends prior to and at the time of the ®rm's inception. As ®rms grow, they gain access to intermediated ®nance on the equity side (venture capital) and on the debt side (banks, ®nance companies, etc.). Eventually, if the ®rms remain in existence and continue to grow, they may gain access to public equity and debt markets. We emphasize that the growth cycle paradigm is not intended to ®t all small businesses, and that ®rm size, age, and information availability are far from perfectly correlated. We also emphasize that Fig. 1 is intended to give a general idea of which sources of ®nance become important at di€erent points in the ®nancial growth cycle, and the points in the cycle at which di€erent types of funding are shown to begin and end are not intended to be de®nitive. For example, even the very largest ®rms occasionally obtain funding through bank loans or private placements, but this is not shown in the ®gure. The notion that ®rms evolve through a ®nancial growth cycle is well established in the literature as a descriptive concept. 6 The perceived wisdom that start-up ®nancing is heavily dependent on initial insider ®nance, trade credit, and angel ®nance (Sahlman, 1990; Wetzel Jr., 1994) is appealing theoretically because start-up ®rms are arguably the most informationally opaque and, therefore, have much diculty in obtaining intermediated external ®nance. Initial insider ®nance is often required at the very earliest stage of a ®rm's development when the entrepreneur is still developing the product or business concept and when the ®rm's assets are mostly intangibles. Insider ®nance may be required again when the business begins small scale production with a limited marketing e€ort. 7 This ``start-up stage'' is often associated with the development of a formal business plan which is used as a sales document

Fig. 1 is adapted and updated from Carey et al. (1993, Fig. 10). For example, there are generally accepted de®nitions of the stages of ®nance for the kind of high-growth companies that are attractive to angels and venture capitalists (Pratt and Morris, 1987). 7 Insider ®nance depends obviously on the ®nancial resources of the entrepreneur. Thus, changes in demographics and wealth distribution may e€ect new ®rm formation (Rosen, 1998a). Rosen argued that the signi®cant transfer of wealth that will occur when the heirs of the baby boom generation inherit their wealth beginning 25 years from now may spark a signi®cant surge in new ®rm formation.
6

5

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

623

Fig. 1. Firm continuum and sources of ®nance.

to obtain angel ®nance. Venture capital would typically come later, after the product has been successfully test-marketed, to ®nance full-scale marketing and production. Sometimes, however, venture capital may be used to ®nance product development costs when those costs are substantial, such as ®nancing clinical trials in the biotechnology industry. Venture capitalists often invest in companies that have already received one or more rounds of angel ®nance. Conventional wisdom argues that bank or commercial ®nance company lending would typically not be available to small businesses until they achieve

624

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

a level of production where their balance sheets re¯ect substantial tangible business assets that might be pledged as collateral, such as accounts receivable, inventory, and equipment. 8 This sequencing of funding over the growth cycle of a ®rm can be viewed in the context of the modern information-based theory of security design and the notion of a ®nancial pecking order. Costly state veri®cation (Townsend, 1979; Diamond, 1984) and adverse selection (Myers, 1984; Myers and Majluf, 1984; Nachman and Noe, 1994) arguments suggest the optimality of debt contracts after insider ®nance has been exhausted. These debt contracts could include trade credit, commercial bank loans and ®nance company loans. However, moral hazard can make debt contracts quite problematic. Moral hazard problems are likely to occur when the amount of external ®nance needed is large relative to the amount of insider ®nance (inclusive of any personal wealth at risk via pledges of personal collateral or guarantees). This suggests that external equity ®nance, speci®cally angel and venture capital, may be particularly important when these conditions hold and the moral hazard problem is acute. The fact that high-growth, high-risk new ventures often obtain angel ®nance and/or venture capital before they obtain signi®cant amounts of external debt ®nance suggests that the moral hazard problem may be particularly acute for these ®rms. 9 Other arguments also a€ect the choice between external equity and external debt. As examples, entrepreneurs may choose external debt in order to keep ownership and control of their ®rms, or they may choose external equity to help share the risk with less risk-averse investors. Until recently, data constraints have made it dicult to examine this paradigm empirically. A recent empirical analysis of the ®nancial growth cycle (Fluck et al., 1997) found results somewhat at variance with the perceived wisdom. Using data on Wisconsin businesses, they estimated that external ®nance exceeds insider ®nance at start-up. They also found that external ®nance declines as a proportion of total ®nance over the ®rst 7±8 years of a business' life cycle, then increases thereafter. Because their data do not include trade credit, their results may understate the dependence on external ®nance throughout the life cycle. Their results suggest that perhaps informational opacity does not
8 See Brewer and Genay (1994) and Brewer et al. (1997) for empirical evidence that external private equity in the form of venture capital is more likely to be used to ®nance intangible assets and activities that generate little collateral while external private debt is more likely to be used to ®nance tangible assets. 9 Other arguments have also been suggested as driving the optimality of the type of equity contracts we observe in venture capital, as we will discuss at greater length in Section 3. Garmaise (1997) argued that the normal pecking order in which external debt precedes external equity can be reversed if it is assumed that venture capitalists have superior information to entrepreneurs. While it seems plausible to argue that entrepreneurs have a superior informational advantage over certain aspects of their project such as the feasibility of their projects' technology, it may be reasonable to assume that venture capitalists have superior information over a project's marketability and its operational implementation.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

625

make it quite so dicult for young ®rms to obtain external ®nance, particularly debt from ®nancial institutions, as is implied by the perceived wisdom about the ®nancial growth cycle. Panel C of Table 1 sheds further light on these and related issues about the evolution of small business ®nance over the growth cycle by showing the distribution of ®nance by ®rm age for our weighted national sample from the NSSBF. We categorize small businesses as ``infants'' (0±2 years), ``adolescents'' (3±4 years), ``middle-aged'' (5±24 years), or ``old'' (25 years or more), which may be viewed as a rough approximation of seed, start-up, and later stages of ®nance discussed earlier. One interesting phenomenon is that funds provided by the principal owner (equity plus debt) increase substantially as ®rms move into the middle age and old categories, from about 25% of funding to about 40%. One reason may be the accumulation of retained earnings over time by principal owners of small businesses that are successful enough to survive into middle age or that the ®rms that succeed tend to start out with greater principal owner stakes. The principal owner may also use some of the retained earnings to obtain a larger equity share by buying out some of the other insider owners and insider debt. As noted above, much of the seed money often comes in the form of equity and debt from family and friends, and some of this may be repurchased by the ®rm as it grows and becomes more self-sucient. As shown, the principal owner's equity increases over time by more than the total equity, consistent with the possibility that shares are being bought from other shareholders. In addition, debt held by the principal owner through loans and credit debt as well as debt held by other individuals (mostly family and friends) decline as the ®rm matures and retires these insider loans that were needed in the early stages. These data also speak to the issue of insider ®nance versus outsider ®nance and how they vary over the ®nancial growth cycle. Like the Wisconsin data, these weighted national data also appear to indicate that insider ®nance does not dominate external ®nance, even in the youngest ®rms. While data on angel and venture ®nance (as well as funding provided by other members of the startup team) are not broken out by age, we can calculate an upper bound to insider ®nance. For adolescents (Panel C) the principal owner provides 25.7%. The majority of the remaining equity (28.3%) is probably from other members of the start-up team. Likewise most of the debt from other individuals (2.8%) is likely from insiders. This translates into an upper bound to insider ®nance of 56.8%. Of this 56.8%, some of the equity comes from angels (possibly more than the 3.6% for the whole population in Panel A) and some (but probably not much) comes from nonangel outsiders. Venture capital is likely less important to adolescents than in the whole population (1.9% in Panel A) because venture capitalists tend to avoid pure start-ups. Taken together, these data suggest that insider ®nance is roughly equal in importance to external ®nance for adolescents.

626

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

It is perhaps surprising how much funding is provided to young ®rms by external debt from ®nancial institutions. This might be considered a violation of the conventional wisdom, which holds that external ®nance from these institutions may have to wait until the ®rm has shown some success and generated some business assets that could be pledged as collateral. However, this funding is not entirely external in an economic sense. As shown below, most small business loans provided by these institutions are personally guaranteed by the one or more of the inside owners, giving the ®nancial institution recourse against their personal wealth in the event the loan is not repaid. In many cases, the personal assets of the insiders are also explicitly pledged as collateral to back the loans. In addition, the owners of small businesses that are organized as proprietorships and partnerships generally are not protected by the limited liability laws that govern corporations (except for limited partners), and so may have their personal wealth at stake to repay loans from ®nancial institutions whether or not there is a formal guarantee or pledge of personal collateral. Thus, much of the ``external'' ®nance from ®nancial institutions is at least partially ``insider'' ®nance in the sense that the insiders are legally required to assume much of the losses if the loans are not repaid. This use of personal assets to help with external ®nance also highlights another important aspect of small business ®nance ± the ®nancial intertwining of owners and their businesses (Ang, 1992). Outside investors and intermediaries often put considerable weight on the ®nancial conditions and reputations of the inside owners, and their own relationships with the inside owners when making investment decisions. For relatively new small businesses, it may often be easier and more informative to evaluate the creditworthiness of the entrepreneur, who may have a longer credit history, more pledgeable assets, and personal data that are relatively easy to evaluate using modern credit scoring techniques. This intertwining of personal and business ®nances often makes research on small business ®nance dicult, as data on the owners' ®nances are often unavailable to researchers. We caution that the weighted averages in Table 1 mask considerable heterogeneity among types of ®rms and the funding they receive. We also caution that these data are from 1993 and therefore may not accurately re¯ect current conditions in small business ®nance. Firms with di€erent types of earnings pro®les are likely to be ®nanced with di€erent combinations of equity and debt. Small businesses in high-growth, high-risk sectors more often obtain external equity investments from angels and venture capitalists, whereas ®rms with steadier income ¯ows more often obtain external debt ®nance from banks and other ®nancial institutions. 10 Similarly, small businesses with more generic
Consistent with this, Fenn et al. (1997) found that venture capital-backed ®rms going public were much more likely to be in the computer-related and medical-related industries than other ®rms going public.
10

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

627

physical inputs like motor vehicles, buildings, and simple equipment may more often borrow from ®nancial institutions because they can use these inputs as collateral to back the loans. It has been estimated that about 23.7% of small businesses disappear within 2 years and 52.7% disappear within 4 years due to failure, bankruptcy, owner retirement, owner health, or the desire to enter a more pro®table endeavor (US Small Business Administration, 1995, Table A.14, p. 243). Thus, the ®rms that survive to be middle aged and old in Panel C are much better performers than the median small business, which likely is out of business before reaching these stages in the ®nancial growth cycle. Importantly, not all ®rms are structured ®nancially in anticipation of following a path from inception to IPO. Some small businesses are simply ``mom and pop'' type enterprises, and are not managed to pursue a high growth strategy. Some are ``life-style ventures'' in which other arguments are prominent in the entrepreneur's objective function, such as being one's own boss (Wetzel Jr., 1994). This does not preclude pro®tability, but it may preclude the type of high-growth prospects that are so attractive to venture capitalists. 2.4. The interconnectedness of small ®rm ®nance The ®nancial growth cycle paradigm is also useful for highlighting the interconnectedness of the sources of small business ®nance enumerated in Table 1 as ®rms grow from the start-up stage, to ``early stage'' ®nance, to ``later stage'' ®nance, and ultimately public ®nance. Di€erent sources of funding may be substitutes or complements. For example, the angel contract is often constructed in anticipation of possible future venture capital, indicating that angel ®nance and venture capital are often complementary sources. Likewise, the venture capital contract is written in anticipation of going public, suggesting that venture capital and public equity are also complements. Loans from commercial banks and other ®nancial institutions are often predicated on having sucient equity that was built up in the past through initial inside ®nance, angel ®nance, and venture capital (complementary). Other connections between types of ®nance are more subtle. A few examples found in the research that are discussed later in this article are illustrative: · Dependence on trade credit is negatively related to the strength of the ®rm's relationship with its bank (substitutes). · The announcement of a loan commitment may raise stock prices and reduce the cost of equity ®nance (complements). · Bank borrowers who do not pledge collateral may send a favorable signal about quality that lowers the cost of other types of ®nance (complements). Research on small business ®nance should take into account the connections among types of small business ®nance, including the expected e€ects of one type of ®nance on the future cost and availability of other types.

628

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

2.5. Di€erences between small business ®nance and large business ®nance Finally, there are some notable qualitative di€erences between the ®nancing of small businesses on the left side of the size/age/information continuum in Fig. 1 and the large businesses on the right side. The ®rst, which has already been noted and is a major theme of this article, is that small businesses generally only have access to private equity and debt markets, whereas large businesses have access to public markets. We argue that informational opacity is a major reason why small ®rms cannot issue publicly traded securities, but it is not the only reason. Public equity and debt underwriting is characterized by signi®cant costs associated with public market due diligence, distribution, and securities registration. Many of these costs are essentially ®xed and create economies of scale in issue size. Given that issue size and asset size of the ®rm are strongly positively related, these economies of scale in issue size may be dif®cult for small and mid-sized businesses to overcome. Thus, a combination of informational opacity and issue costs may determine the size of ®rm for which a public o€ering becomes economically attractive. On the equity side, the median ®rm asset size was $16.0 million for venture-backed IPOs, and $23.3 million for nonventure-backed IPOs over 1991±1993 (Fenn et al., 1997). A reasonable guess for the minimum asset size for entering this market would be about $10 million. For public debt side, a reasonable guess for the minimum ®rm asset size is about $150±$200 million. 11 While we characterize small ®rms as obtaining external ®nance almost exclusively through private equity and debt markets and not public markets, the converse does not generally hold for large ®rms. Even after ®rms are able to access public equity and debt markets, they often continue to use private markets, at least for certain types of transactions. Large ®rm LBOs typically involve raising substantial sums in the organized private equity markets (Fenn et al., 1997). Similarly, ®rms with access to public debt markets often continue to use private debt markets heavily, with bank loans, private placements, and other private debt arrangements accounting for half or more of large corporate debt. Arguably, even large ®rms may engage in informationally opaque activities that require the information production services of a ®nancial intermediary that can structure a tailored contract and monitor performance over the life of the contract (Carey et al., 1993; Houston and James, 1996; Hadlock and James, 1997). Another di€erence between small and large ®rms is that most small ®rms are owner-managed. In the 1993 NSSBF, 86.0% of the ®rms are managed by an

Carey et al. (1993) estimated that the issue size of public debt begins about $75±$100 million. Assuming that a ®rmÕs assets are at least twice as large as its public debt yields a minimum asset size for ®rms to issue in the public debt market of about $150±$200 million.

11

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

629

owner/partner, and only 14.0% by a hired employee/paid manager. As a result, agency problems in corporate governance and in choosing capital structure (e.g., free cash ¯ow problems) that are driven by the separation of ownership and control are often irrelevant for small ®rms. 12 The juxtaposition of ownership and management, however, may create its own set of problems. On the one hand, for example, an undiversi®ed owner may pursue nonvalue-maximization behavior to reduce risk. On the other hand, the agency cost of debt might be higher without an intervening layer of risk averse management that would otherwise reduce risk. 3. The role of private equity markets in small business ®nance As noted earlier, all of the funds provided by the ``principal owner'' and most of the ``other equity'' in Table 1 represent insider ®nance. These funds are critical at the ``seed ®nancing'' and ``start-up'' stages when information problems are most acute. Insider funding is also usually a necessary condition for any infusions of external ®nance to reduce adverse selection and moral hazard problems. At later stages of growth ± as represented by our ``middle-aged'' and ``old'' categories in Panel C of Table 1 ± retained earnings are often an important source of additional funding and serve as a source of strength to assure ¯ows of external ®nance. Angel ®nance and venture capital ± at 3.59% and 1.85% of total ®nance, respectively ± represent relatively small portions of small business ®nance. However, this considerably understates the role of the external private equity market that is made up of these two categories for certain types of ®rms. Angels and venture capitalists invest very selectively and target small companies with signi®cant upside potential. 13 Thus, most of the infants and adolescents would not be candidates for angel ®nance, and the overwhelming majority would not be candidates for venture capital. The importance of the external private equity can best be judged not by the quantity of this equity, but by the eventual success of the ®rms that receive it. In terms of the ®nancial growth cycle paradigm, the big winners are usually

12 An interesting exception occurs when a venture capitalist obtains a controlling interest in a ®rm still managed by the entrepreneur. 13 This type of ®nance is sometimes discussed in terms of a ``target rate of return'', or the rate that the angel or venture capitalist would realize in the most likely successful state. When they invest in early-stage ®rms, the target rate can be as high as 40±80% depending on the stage of ®nance with angels generally at the lower end and venture capitalists at the higher end. These target rates often require giving external equity investors a majority ownership. Later stage venture capital investing, however, may be associated with somewhat lower target rates (Fenn et al., 1997).

630

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

those that are taken public in an IPO. 14 During the 1980s, approximately 15% of all IPOs were backed by venture capital, well out of proportion to the fraction of all ®rms that received venture capital. Since 1990, this share has about doubled to 30% (Fenn et al., 1997). Moreover, discussions with industry participants suggest that most companies that receive venture capital had prior angel ®nance. We next turn to the structure of the angel and venture capital markets, respectively. 3.1. The angel ®nance market Angel ®nance di€ers markedly from most other categories of external ®nance in that the angel market is not intermediated. Instead, it is an informal market for direct ®nance where individuals invest directly in the small companies through an equity contract, typically common stock. The modern theory of ®nancial intermediation suggests that ®nancial intermediaries exist in part because of economies of scale in information production. That is, they eliminate redundancy in information production when numerous small investors pool their funds through an intermediary and eliminate the delegation costs associated with ®nancial intermediation. Because angels by de®nition and by SEC regulation are high net worth individuals, the increment of funds that an angel wishes to invest in a small ®rm is often consistent with the amount that the ®rm needs. Quite often one angel is sucient, so redundancy of information production is not a relevant issue. Angels typically provide ®nance in a range of about $50,000±$1,000,000, below that of a typical venture capital investment (Wetzel Jr., 1994). However, angels do not always act alone. Angels sometimes work as a small investment group where they coordinate their investment activity (Prowse, 1998). Sometimes this is done in conjunction with a ``gatekeeper'' such as a lawyer or accountant who brings deal ¯ow to the group and helps structure the contracts. The angel market tends to be local, where investor proximity may be important in addressing information problems. There is disagreement over the extent to which angels are active investors. Barry (1994) described angels as investors who do not ``(take) on the consulting role of venture capitalists''. In contrast, Wetzel Jr. (1994) reported that ``angel deals typically involve a close group of co-investors led by a successful entrepreneur who is familiar with the venture's technology, products, and markets''. Wetzel further noted that the advice and counsel that angels provide to entrepreneurs can be quite important. Some suggest that angels are willing to accept
14 Barry et al. (1990) reported that venture capitalists enjoyed positive returns in 96% of the cases in which one of their funded ®rms was taken public via an IPO. However, for the next most common (and next most attractive) exit, acquisition by another company, only 59% provided positive returns to venture capitalists.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

631

psychic return partially in lieu of monetary return and develop relationships with their entrepreneurs over time. Angels often invest in multiple rounds at di€erent stages as the companies they are investing in move through the early stages of ®nancial growth. Overall, the degree to which angels are active investors and the extent to which psychic return partially o€sets monetary return are substantially unresearched questions. It is safe to say, however, that angels demand less control and bring less ®nancial expertise to the table on average than venture capitalists. While the angel market can best be characterized as informal, there have been some attempts to formalize this market. These attempts may be motivated by the assumption that search and information costs have been signi®cant impediments to the eciency of the angel market. One thrust has been to create private angel networks in which entrepreneurs can solicit equity investments by angels who are members of the network. Typically the network is operated by a not-for-pro®t entity (such as a university), sometimes referred to as the ``switch''. The entrepreneurs solicit private equity by displaying summary information about their ®rm and their ®nancial needs in the form of term sheets on the network. Angels who have been ``quali®ed'' by the switch can then search across these term sheets and identify companies of interest. The angel is then put in touch with the entrepreneur to discuss the investment opportunity. Recently the SBA has linked a number of angel capital networks together to form a system called ACE-Net. This system now permits angels to search across term sheets from entrepreneurs across the US (Acs and Tarpley, 1998; Lerner, 1998a). The value of angel networks in general, and ACE-Net in particular, is a substantially unresolved issue. The networks are typically subsidized and are predicated on the assumption that there is some degree of market failure in the angel market. However, the existing informal nature of the angel market may be the optimal solution to the acute information problems associated with early stage new venture ®nancing. The role played by gatekeepers, for instance, may be quite important in reducing information-driven contracting costs. For example, an accountant may have both an entrepreneur and an angel as clients. In connecting the two, the accountant has reputational capital at stake and thus provides some of the services associated with classic intermediation. It is unclear whether a more formal market for angel ®nance can provide an economically signi®cant substitute or addition to the current informal angel market. 15

The other recent thrust in the angel market has been the standardization of documentation. In conjunction with the ACE-Net project, the SBA has adopted standardized legal forms for angel private equity contributions (available on its website), which may lower transactions costs.

15

632

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

3.2. The venture capital market Unlike the angel market, the venture capital market is intermediated. 16 Venture capitalists perform the quintessential functions of ®nancial intermediaries, taking funds from a group of investors and redeploying those funds by investing in informationally opaque issuers. In addition to screening, contracting, and monitoring, venture capitalists also determine the time and form of investment exit (Tyebjee and Bruno, 1984; Gorman and Sahlman, 1989). In performing these functions, the venture capitalist is the consummate active investor, often participating in strategic planning and even occasionally in operational decision making. Interest in the relationship between the venture capital fund and its portfolio investments is re¯ected in a growing body of research on this subject, spurred in part by the development of new databases (Fenn and Liang, 1998). This research includes investigations of origination and due diligence, the nature of the contract between the venture capital fund and the ®rms it invests in, and how institutional features of the market a€ect these investments. At origination, venture capitalists confront a signi®cant adverse selection problem associated with providing external ®nance to unusually opaque ®rms and therefore spend a considerable amount of time evaluating prospective issuers (Amit et al., 1990; Fried and Hisrich, 1994; Fenn et al., 1997). Syndication may also help solve the adverse selection problem (Lerner, 1994a). An agency problem arises in the relationship between the entrepreneur and the venture capitalist in which the entrepreneur may expend insucient e€ort, exhibit expense preference behavior, or lack sucient information or skill to make optimal production decisions. The problem may be compounded by the fact that information in general about the value of the project is imperfect and revealed over time (Cooper and Carleton, 1979; Bergemann and Hege, 1998). The menu of contract features that characterize venture capital investing may be explained as solutions to this agency problem. These include the staging of venture capital investments to assure optimal exercise of production options and ecient stopping (Sahlman, 1988, 1990; Chan et al., 1990; Admati and P¯eiderer, 1994; Gompers, 1995; Bergemann and Hege, 1998), 17 control and the choice of equity/debt instrument (Gompers, 1993; Marx, 1993; Cornelli and Yosha, 1997; Trester, 1998), entrepreneur compensation (Sahlman, 1990), restrictive covenants (Chan et al., 1990, Gompers and Lerner, 1996), board representation (Lerner, 1995), and the allocation of voting rights (Fenn et al., 1997). In addition, venture capitalists expend considerable resources
16 For more extensive reviews of the venture capital literature, see Barry (1994) and Fenn et al. (1997). 17 Staged ®nance may also create perverse incentives by encouraging the entrepreneur to focus on short-term goals instead of wealth maximization (Hellman, 1993).

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

633

monitoring their portfolio ®rms (Gorman and Sahlman, 1989), and they often tend to specialize in particular industries in which they develop expertise (Ruhnka and Young, 1991; Gupta and Sapienza, 1992; Norton and Tenenbaum, 1993). About 80% of all venture capital in the US ¯ows through independent limited partnerships, with most of the remaining 20% provided by subsidiaries of ®nancial institutions. In the partnerships, the general partners usually consist of senior managers of venture capital management ®rms and the limited partners are institutional investors. 18 The biggest categories of institutional investors are public pension funds (26%), corporate pension funds (22%), commercial banks and life insurance companies (18%), and endowments and foundations (12%) (Fenn et al., 1997). The limited partners typically put up 98% or more of the funds and receive 80% of the partnership's pro®ts. The general partners receive 20% of the partnership's pro®ts plus a fee for managing the fund. 19 The limited partnership is structured to address problems of asymmetric information and to align the incentives of the general partners and the limited partners. This is accomplished particularly through the ®nite-life nature of the partnership agreement, which requires general partners to regularly raise new funds in order to stay in business, and the linking of the general partners' compensation to the success of the partnership. Other features include covenants restricting the venture capitalist's management of the fund, mandatory distribution requirements, and other restrictions on activities that may be associated with self-dealing (Sahlman, 1990; Gompers and Lerner, 1996). The typical venture capital fund has a 10 year life span, usually with an option to extend for two years. Large, well-established venture capital management ®rms operate multiple funds simultaneously, each at di€erent stages in their life spans. During the early years of the fund, the senior managers search for and screen new deals, and structure the contracts with the selected companies. During the middle years, the venture capitalists manage the investments in their fund's portfolio. This is associated with active involvement in the management of each of the portfolio companies, including providing consulting services and sometimes becoming involved in solving major operational problems, serving on the board of directors, ®nding and hiring managers, occasionally replacing poorly performing managers, and assisting the ®rm in forming strategic alliances. Gorman and Sahlman (1989) found that these activities were associated with venture capitalists allocating more than 100 hours and visiting each of their portfolio ®rms on average 19 times per year.
18 This is an oversimpli®cation of the precise legal relationship among the senior managers, the management ®rm, and the venture capital fund. See Fenn et al. (1997) for more details. 19 See Gompers and Lerner (1994) and Fenn et al. (1997) for more detail on the speci®c structure of limited partnerships and associated compensation issues.

634

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

During the later years of a fund's life, much of the venture capitalist's time is focused on ``harvesting'' portfolio ®rms. The most attractive exit is typically through an IPO and subsequent public o€erings. The IPO market is characterized by the same type of informational asymmetries that characterize the private equity market, although ®rms going public are generally less opaque than when they received infusions of angel ®nance and venture capital. Mechanisms such as underpricing (Rock, 1986; Benveniste and Spindt, 1989) and price stabilization (Chowdhry and Nanda, 1996; Benveniste et al., 1996; Benveniste et al., 1998) are market features that address information problems. Venture capitalists may also play a role in reducing opacity. Megginson and Weiss (1991) found that venture capital-backed IPOs are less underpriced than nonventure-backed IPOs, Barry et al. (1990) found that the degree of underpricing is negatively related to the amount of venture capital ownership, and Brav and Gompers (1997) found that venture capital-backed IPOs outperform nonventure-backed IPOs in the long run. In addition, the venture capitalist may add value choosing optimal timing for an IPO (Lerner, 1994b). However, less reputable venture capitalists may have incentives to bring portfolio ®rms to market too early, possibly to help fund-raising e€orts associated with starting new funds (Gi€ord, 1994, Gompers, 1996). In general, only a minority of the ®rms in the fund's portfolio will be successful enough to take public. The second best exit is by sale to another company. Alternatively, if a portfolio ®rm does not do well, it may be put back to its original owners, or (in a worst-case scenario) liquidated. However, the payo€s from the few most successful ®rms generally provide the bulk of the fund's returns. 4. The role of private debt markets in small business ®nance We next turn to the private debt markets that ®nance small business. As discussed above, the capital structure decision between equity and debt is di€erent for small ®rms than for large ®rms in part because small businesses are usually more informationally opaque than large ®rms. In addition, since small businesses are usually owner-managed, the owner/managers often have strong incentives to issue external debt rather than external equity in order to keep ownership and control of their ®rms. Table 1 shows estimated percentage distributions of nine di€erent types of private debt for US small business, three each from the major categories of ®nancial institutions, non®nancial business and government, and individuals. Financial institutions account for 26.66% of the total funding of small businesses, or slightly more than half of the total debt funding of 50.37%, with commercial banks providing the lion's share at 18.75%. Non®nancial business/government debt provides 19.26% of small business funding (mostly trade

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

635

credit), and debt owed to individuals accounts for only 5.78% of small business funding. After brie¯y discussing the latter two categories, we will spend most of the section discussing research on ®nancial institution debt. 4.1. Non®nancial business and government debt A sizable 15.78% of total small business assets are funded by trade credit, as measured by accounts payable at the end of the prior year. Clearly, trade credit is extremely important to small business ®nance, but has received much less research interest than commercial bank lending, which provides only slightly more credit to small business. Although relatively expensive, a small amount of trade credit may be optimal from the viewpoint of transactions costs, liquidity, and cash management and may help give the borrowing ®rm and supplier information that helps predict cash ¯ows (Ferris, 1981). It is not necessarily clear, however, whether working capital ®nance is best provided by suppliers versus by a ®nancial institution through a line of credit. In some cases, suppliers have advantages over ®nancial institutions because they may have better private information about the small business' industry and production process, or may be able to use leverage in terms of withholding future supplies to solve incentive problems more e€ectively (Biais and Gollier, 1997). Suppliers may also be better positioned to repossess and resell the supplied goods (Mian and Smith, 1992). Trade credit may also provide a cushion during credit crunches, monetary policy contractions, or other shocks that leave ®nancial institutions less willing or less able to provide small business ®nance (Nilsen, 1994; Biais and Gollier, 1997). During these times, large businesses may temporarily raise funds in public markets, such as commercial paper, and lend these additional funds to small businesses through trade credit (Calomiris et al., 1995). Trade credit that extends beyond a few days of liquidity, however, is often quite expensive. A typical trade credit arrangement makes payment due in full in 30 days, but gives a 2% discount if payment is made within the ®rst 10 days (Smith, 1987). The implicit interest rate of 2% for 20 days (although it is not always strictly enforced) is much higher than rates on most loans from ®nancial institutions, and so would likely only be taken in cases in which credit limits at ®nancial institutions are exhausted. As we will see shortly, only about half of small businesses have loans from ®nancial institutions, so very expensive trade credit may often be the best or only available source of external funding for working capital. Prior empirical analysis found that both transactions and ®nancial variables a€ect the proportion of trade credit that is paid late by small businesses (e.g., Elliehausen and Wolken, 1993). It has also been found in the US that as a small business ages and its relationships with ®nancial institutions mature ± and it presumably becomes more informationally transparent ± it tends to pay o€ its accounts payable sooner and become less dependent on

636

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

trade credit (Petersen and Rajan, 1994, 1995). Recent evidence from Russia suggests that in developing economies, trade credit provides a signal that leads to more bank credit (Cook, 1997). This suggests that in economic environments with weak informational infrastructure and less developed banking systems, trade credit may play an even more important role because of its strength in addressing information problems. The data in Table 1 suggest that direct loans from non®nancial businesses and government are both small, just 1.74% and 0.49% of small business funding, respectively. However, the government does provide ®nancial support in other ways. For example, the SBA had guarantees outstanding on 135,859 small business loans totaling $21.2 billion as of 30 September, 1994 or about 1.27% of all US small business ®nance (although these data are from a slightly di€erent point in time from the data in Table 1) (US Small Business Administration, 1995, p. 281). 4.2. Small business debt held by individuals Turning to debt held by individuals, these loans account for just 5.71% of total small business ®nance. Most of this (4.10%) represents debt funding from the principal owner in addition to his/her equity interest in the ®rm. In some cases, these personal loans may be just a convenient way of providing shortterm ®nance to the ®rm, while in other cases, these loans may create tax bene®ts by substituting interest for dividends. The amount of funding raised through credit card ®nancing ± which has received much press attention as a potential alternative to conventional bank loans (e.g., Ho, 1997) ± appears to be quite small, just 0.14% of total small business ®nance. However, this ®gure may be understated because it includes only the amount of debt carried after the monthly payment is made, neglecting short-term ¯oat between the purchase date and the monthly payment. Finally, 1.47% of small business funding is provided by loans from other individuals, most of which is likely from family and friends or other insiders. 4.3. Financial institution debt For the remainder of this section, we will focus on banks, ®nance companies, and other ®nancial institutions that together provide most of the external debt ®nance to small businesses. As noted above, these ®nancial institutions specialize in screening, contracting, and monitoring methods to address information and incentive problems, and we will cover a few of the most important of these methods in the limited space here. Table 2 helps to illustrate some of the facts about these ®nancial institutions and their methods. Panel A shows that only a little over half of small businesses, 54.23%, have any loans or leases from ®nancial institutions. Of course,

Table 2 Estimated distribution of small business debt a from ®nancial institutions All ®nancial institutions 54.23% 19.30% 100.00% 5.33 years 7.21 years 52.13% 6.94% 14.81% 14.62% 6.83% 4.66% 100.00% 94.34% 51.08% 4.78 years 6.49 years 24.83% 18.92% 7.12% 5.16% 23.71% 20.25% 100.00% 87.72% 38.87% 40.57% 7.00% 86.95% 12.96% 2.40% 1.62% 15.30% 2.60% 11.43% Commercial banks Finance companies Other ®nancial institutions

b

A: Percent of small businesses with ®nancial institution debt (percent of ®rms) Percent of ®rms with debt from at least one institution of this type Percent of ®rms with debt from more than one institution of this type Percent of ®rms with this type as its ``primary'' ®nancial institution c

B: Average length of relationship between small business ®rms and each type of ®nancial institution Average length of relationships with ®nancial institutions of this type 6.64 years 7.77 years 9.01 years 9.37 years Average length of relationship with ``primary'' institution if it is this type c 56.35% 14.91% 10.21% 3.99% 2.45% 12.09% 100.00%

C: Percent of each type of ®nancial institution's small business debt by category of loan or lease Credit lines used 52.03% 13.89% Mortgage loans d Equipment loans 10.71% Motor vehicle loans 6.08% Capital leases 5.65% Other loans 11.64% Total 100.00%

D: Percent of each type of ®nancial institution's small business debt by collateral and guarantee status 91.94% 91.99% Percent of debt from this type of institution that is secured e 51.63% 53.82% Percent of debt from this type of institution that is guaranteed f

a

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

b

637

Debt of nonfarm, non®nancial, nonreal-estate small businesses as described in Table 1, note f. Financial institutions include commercial banks, ®nance companies, thrift institutions, leasing companies brokerage ®rms, mortgage companies, and insurance companies. c A ®rm's ``primary'' institution is the one designated by the ®rm as its primary provider of ®nancial services, including loan, deposit, and other services. It is not necessary to have a loan to have a ``primary'' institution ± almost all ®rms use ®nancial institutions for deposit services. A few ®rms that did not have any relations with ®nancial institutions were neglected for the calculations of ``primary'' institution. d Mortgages include both commercial and residential mortgages if the funds were used for business purposes. e Secured debt includes the credit lines used and other loans that are reported as secured, plus all equipment loans, all mortgage loans, all motor vehicle loans, and all capital leases. f Guaranteed debt includes the used credit lines, mortgage loans, motor vehicle loans, equipment loans, and other loans that are reported as guaranteed. Capital leases by de®nition are not guaranteed. Source: 1993 NSSBF, all data are from year-end 1993. See Table 1.

638

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

many small businesses without ®nancial institution debt would qualify for loans or leases, but choose not to borrow (Levinson and Willard, 1997). The data also suggest that small ®rms tend to specialize their borrowing at a single ®nancial institution ± only about one-third of the borrowing ®rms (19.30% / 54.23%) have loans from two or more institutions. In 86.95% of the cases, small businesses identify commercial banks as their ``primary'' ®nancial institution, since banks dominate other institutions in providing transactions/deposit services, and also provide most of the loans to the small businesses that receive ®nancial institution credit (40.57% / 54.23%). 20 The data in Panel B suggest that small businesses tend to stay with their ®nancial institutions. On average, small ®rms have been with their current ®nancial institutions for 6.64 years, and 9.01 years for their primary institution. The ®ndings in Panels A and B ± that small businesses tend to get their credit from a single institution and that they stay with their institutions for long periods of time ± suggest bene®ts to these relationships, which are discussed below. Panel C gives information on the type of loan or lease. About half of the funds, 52.03%, are drawn under lines of credit, a type of loan commitment. Such commitments are promises by the ®nancial institution to provide future credit, and may be used to reduce transactions costs, provide insurance against credit rationing, and other purposes described below. Mortgage loans, the next largest category at 13.89%, may be secured by either commercial property or personal property of the owner. For most equipment loans, motor vehicle loans, and capital leases, the proceeds of the loan or lease are used to purchase the assets pledged as collateral. Panel D shows that 91.94% of all small business debt to ®nancial institutions is secured. This very high percentage implies the vast majority of virtually all types of ®nancial institution loans and leases to small businesses ± including loans drawn under lines of credit ± are backed by collateral. In addition, 51.63% of ®nancial institution debt is guaranteed, usually by the owners of the ®rm. The data in Table 2 as a whole suggest that ®nancial institutions use a number of contracting methods like collateral and guarantees, lines of credit, and relationships extensively to deal with the information and incentive problems of small businesses, and we next investigate some of these methods in depth. 21

20 Banks and ®nance companies also tend to di€er in their lending policies possibly in part because of regulatory di€erences. Based on data for large borrowers, ®nance companies fund observably riskier, more highly levered borrowers on average than banks, but both cover the same risk spectrum (Carey et al., forthcoming). 21 The NSSBF also has information on the race and gender of the entrepreneur, which allows for analysis of possible race and gender discrimination. Research in this ®eld is just beginning, but there does appear to be some evidence of racial discrimination by lenders (Cole, 1997; Cavalluzzo and Cavalluzzo, forthcoming).

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

639

4.3.1. Collateral and guarantees Collateral and guarantees are powerful tools that allow ®nancial institutions to o€er credit on favorable terms to small businesses whose informational opacity might otherwise result in either credit rationing or the extension of credit only on relatively unfavorable terms. These contract features address adverse selection problems at loan origination and moral hazard problems that arise after credit has been granted. Collateral and guarantees may also reduce the cost of intermediation because a ®nancial institution may be able to assess the value of pledged or guaranteed assets at lower cost than it can assess the value of the business as an on-going concern. We distinguish between ``inside'' collateral and ``outside'' collateral. Inside collateral involves pledging assets owned by the ®rm. This reorders the claims of the ®rm's creditors by giving one of them priority via a security interest in speci®c assets. Outside collateral involves pledging assets owned outside the ®rm, typically assets belonging to the ®rm's owners. Outside collateral enhances the claim of a single creditor by conveying recourse against additional assets outside the ®rm without diminishing the claims of the other creditors in the event of bankruptcy. Guarantees give the lender general recourse against the assets of the principal owner or other party issuing the guarantee for de®ciencies by the ®rm in repaying the loan. A guarantee is similar to a pledge of outside personal collateral, but di€ers in two important ways. First, a guarantee is a broader claim than a pledge of collateral, since the liability of the guarantor is not limited to any speci®c assets. Second, a guarantee is a weaker claim than a pledge of collateral against any given set of assets, since a guarantee does not involve speci®c liens that prevent these assets from being sold or consumed. 22 Both guarantees and outside personal collateral may provide powerful incentives for the entrepreneur to behave in a way that bene®ts the bene®ciary creditor (often to the detriment of other creditors) when the business is in distress. This incentive depends more on the disutility to the entrepreneur of losing personal assets, rather than on the value of the attachable assets to the lender in the event of default. Thus, a guarantee or pledge of personal collateral from an entrepreneur with only a modest amount of personal wealth may still provide a strong incentive that bene®ts the lender, even if recourse against these personal assets represents only a small fraction of the value of the loan.

Personal outside collateral and guarantees, while commonly used by small businesses, are rare for large ®rms. Usually no owner of a large corporation has enough wealth to back the debt of the ®rm or owns enough of a share of the ®rm to want to back the debt personally.

22

640

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Most of the research on collateral has emphasized its use in mitigating information problems. Theory suggests that pledging outside collateral may help resolve adverse selection problems when the borrower has more information about the quality of the investment than the lender, and may help prevent credit rationing (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981, 1986; Bester, 1985; Chan and Kanatas, 1985; Besanko and Thakor, 1987a, b). Similarly, pledging outside collateral may attenuate moral hazard by reducing the incentives to switch into riskier projects or to reduce e€ort (Boot et al., 1991). Models of inside collateral similarly key on information problems and incentives. The pledging of some of the ®rm's assets to one debt holder may help mitigate the Myers (1977) underinvestment problem by allowing the ®rm to invest in relatively safe projects (Stulz and Johnson, 1985), may reduce asset-substitution problems (Smith and Warner, 1979), may help enforce optimal ®rm closure (Swary and Udell, 1988), may help in the enforcement of covenants and renegotiating the loan under ®nancial distress (Gorton and Kahn, 1997), or may help reduce the costs of dividing the remaining assets in bankruptcy (Welch, 1997), although it may exacerbate the agency costs of debt by discouraging maintenance of secured assets (John et al., 1997). Some models also take into account the e€ects of collateral on the costs of other types of funding. For example, a ®rm may choose to borrow on an unsecured basis from a ®nancial institution rather than pledging collateral because unsecured lending may require more monitoring by the institution, which as discussed above may reduce the costs of other equity and debt (Adler, 1993). The choice of unsecured debt might also be used as a signal of a favorable quality assessment by the lender, again reducing the costs of other equity and debt (Rajan and Winton, 1995). Much of the theoretical and empirical analysis in this literature concerns whether riskier versus safer borrowers tend to pledge collateral, and the extent to which pledging collateral reduces risk, which may be of policy concern for the prudential supervision of ®nancial institutions. Theoretical models of collateral usually start with the assumption of informational opaqueness and analyze whether riskier versus safer borrowers within an observationally equivalent risk pool will pledge collateral more often. There is disagreement in the results. Most of the models of outside collateral ®nd that safer borrowers within the pool will tend to pledge outside collateral (see Boot et al. (1991) for an exception) because the owner/managers of safer ®rms know they are less likely to lose their collateral (reducing adverse selection problems) or because pledging collateral induces them to plot a safer course of action (reducing moral hazard problems). The relatively few models of inside collateral are either ambiguous with respect to risk or predict that riskier ®rms are more likely to pledge collateral. The practitioner literature is typically focused on inside collateral and its association with observable risk (rather than di€erences in risk known only to the borrowers). This literature usually predicts that ®nancial

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

641

intermediaries will more often require riskier borrowers to secure their loans (Hempel et al., 1986; Morsman Jr., 1986). The empirical literature usually found secured lending associated with risky borrowers or with risky loans (which implies risky borrowers, since the collateral itself reduces the risk of the loan) (Orgler, 1970; Hester, 1979; Scott and Smith, 1986; Berger and Udell, 1990, 1992; Booth, 1992; Booth and Chua, 1996; Klapper, 1998). Most of the empirical literature was written without access to data on small business ®rms. A new set of studies on collateral and guarantees uses the data from the NSSBF, NFIB, and SCF to focus on the types of collateral and guarantees used by small businesses and the extent to which these tools are used to address informational opacity of these ®rms. Many small businesses pledge accounts receivable and/or inventory as inside collateral to secure lines of credit in which the amount of credit granted ¯uctuates with the value of qualifying receivables/inventory. 23 This may be particularly useful for an informationally opaque small ®rm because the lending institution's risk exposure is not as closely tied to the uncertain future cash ¯ows of the ®rm as in other types of lending. The monitoring of receivables/inventory may also produce valuable information about future ®rm performance as well as information about the value of the collateral, and therefore be used as part of an overall relationship that may lead to more favorable credit terms in the future. It has been found that accounts receivable and/or inventory was pledged twice as often as all other types of collateral combined on bank lines of credit to small business and that small ®rms that pledge accounts receivable and/or inventory were younger and had shorter relationships with their lenders, consistent with informational opacity (Berger and Udell, 1995). Outside personal collateral and guarantees may also be important to the ®nancing of small ®rms that are informationally opaque and have few pledgeable business assets. About 40% of small business loans and close to 60% of loan dollars are guaranteed and/or secured by personal assets (Ang et al., 1995; Avery et al., 1998). Combining the NSSBF data with the personal wealth data from the SCF, it was found that the use of personal collateral and guarantees occurred more often: (1) for ®rms that were younger, smaller, and had fewer tangible assets (and are arguably more informationally opaque); and (2) for owners that were wealthier, particularly with more liquid assets (Avery

Secured lending which is principally based on the value of the speci®c assets pledged as inside collateral (as opposed to the projected cash ¯ows of the ®rm) is often referred to as asset-based lending.

23

642

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

et al., 1998). This is also another example of how the personal ®nances and business ®nances of small business owners are often intertwined. 24 Other analyses of small business that could not distinguish between inside and outside collateral are also consistent with the notion that more informationally opaque or riskier small businesses more often pledge collateral. For example, an analysis using the NFIB data on all types of collateral (both personal and business) found that younger ®rms tended to pledge collateral more often (Leeth and Scott, 1989). It was also found that small businesses from the former East Germany tend to pledge collateral more often than ®rms from the former West Germany, presumably due at least in part to greater informational opacity or higher risk of the ®rms in the former East Germany (Harho€ and Korting, 1997). 4.3.2. Loan commitments/lines of credit Another set of contract features that may be employed to help o€set the information problems of small businesses is loan commitments or lines of credit from ®nancial institutions. A loan commitment is a forward contract issued by a ®nancial institution to provide debt under prespeci®ed terms over some future time interval unless the borrower's condition has su€ered ``material adverse change'', or if the borrower has violated a covenant in the contract. As shown in Table 2, about half of small business debt held by ®nancial institutions is under lines of credit, which is a form of loan commitment. Lines of credit are generally pure revolving credits that allow the ®rm to borrow as much of the line as needed at any given time over the time interval speci®ed. Lines of credit are thus very ¯exible and convenient for the borrower, and are usually used to provide working capital, rather than to fund speci®c large investments. Loan commitments provide protection for the borrower against credit rationing or credit crunches that are based on general market conditions, rather than speci®c, identi®able, legally defensible deteriorations in the individual borrower's condition (Melnik and Plaut, 1986; So®anos et al., 1990; Avery and Berger, 1991a; Berger and Udell, 1992; Morgan, 1994, 1998). This implies that borrowers are essentially immune ± at least until their current commitment
24 Personal guarantees and pledges of personal assets may be seen as substitutes for an injection of additional equity by the owners. Under most circumstances, ®nancial institutions would o€er better terms if the same amount of equity were added to the ®rm, which would save the costs of pursuing recourse against personal assets in the event of ®nancial losses. However, these extra costs may be o€set by some bene®ts for the owner of personal collateral and guarantees, such as better convenience, lower transactions costs, or better diversi®cation, rather than liquidating personal assets (e.g., private home) and investing the proceeds in the business. The data generally support the dominance of personal equity over personal collateral and guarantees ± equity makes up about 85% of small business ownersÕ investments in their businesses as opposed to only about 10% for personal collateral/guarantees, and about 5% for personal loans to the business (Avery et al., 1998).

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

643

contracts expire ± from having their credit withdrawn in general credit rationing or credit crunch episodes. Commitment contracts may either help resolve adverse selection/moral hazard problems or exacerbate these problems. By o€ering potential borrowers various sets of contract terms on commitments ± up-front fees, usage fees, interest rates, etc. ± ®nancial institutions may be able to induce informationally opaque borrowers to reveal their types, or to choose higher net present value projects (Boot et al., 1987; Kanatas, 1987; Thakor and Udell, 1987; Berkovitch and Greenbaum, 1991). However, commitments can also exacerbate information problems because commitment contracts are signed at an earlier time when less information is available than spot loan agreements. By agreeing to provide credit in advance, it is possible that the ®nancial institution would have gained enough information by the time the funds are drawn down to refuse to issue a spot loan on similar terms or that the borrower would be able to risk-shift to take advantage of the ®nancial institution (Avery and Berger, 1991a). Similar to the collateral research, most of the empirical commitment research focused on the risk associated with loans under commitment relative to the risk of other loans. No strong association between commitments and risk was found when commitments to all sizes of business borrowers were examined (Koppenhaver, 1989; Avery and Berger, 1991a, b; Berger and Udell, 1990, 1993) or when just commitments to small businesses were examined (Berger and Udell, 1996). Additional research results about lines of credit issued to small businesses are discussed below. 4.3.3. Debt covenants and maturity Another set of tools that ®nancial institutions use in debt contracts to solve the informational opacity problems of small businesses include restrictive covenants and choice of maturity. The debt contracts issued by commercial banks, ®nance companies, and other ®nancial institutions are often covenant-rich, requiring the borrower to return to the institution to renegotiate these covenants when strategic opportunities to enhance value arise or when the ®nancial condition of the ®rm changes (Berlin and Loeys, 1988; Carey et al., 1993). In part, these covenants and their renegotiation are intended to give the lending institution more control and prevent borrowers from engaging in risk-shifting behavior. By using speci®c ®nancial ratio and activity restrictions linked to periodic submission of ®nancial information, covenants limit the ®rm's ability to change its ®nancial condition or strategy. Thus, covenants can force a borrower to obtain permission from its lender before embarking on signi®cant strategic changes. One theoretical result is that the strictest covenants are expected to be placed on the ®rms with the most credit risk and greatest moral hazard incentives (Berlin and Mester, 1993). As discussed below, however, effective covenants generally cannot be imposed on the smallest ®rms which do

644

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

not have audited ®nancial statements, so short maturities must be used in place of formal covenants to control the behavior of these ®rms. A borrower can request a waiver when a covenant prevents the ®rm from engaging in a new activity. Renegotiation about the waiver allows the lender considerable control over whether the new activity will be undertaken and under what terms. This control can be ecient in allowing positive net present value activities to be undertaken and preventing those with negative values, but inecient outcomes can also be created by this control. For example, the control provided by covenants may allow the lender to ``hold-up'' the borrower for a higher rate or other concessions, even on a positive net present value project. Thus, covenants can create excessive market power and suboptimal outcomes in much the same way as can proprietary access to information acquired during relationships (discussed below). Of course, the market limits this control by the ®nancial institution. Most commercial bank loans can be prepaid without penalty, so borrowers have the option of obtaining more accommodating ®nance elsewhere (and incurring some associated transactions costs). A ®nancial institution also has an incentive and ability as a repeat player to acquire a reputation for fairness in renegotiation. Covenants are common in commercial bank loans and are generally stricter than those in private placements and much stricter than those in public bonds. In part, this re¯ects the comparative advantages of ®nancial institutions in renegotiating and selectively relaxing these covenants (Berlin and Mester, 1993). The covenants in bank loans and private placements are typically set suciently tightly that renegotiation is fairly likely. One study found that 47% of private placements required renegotiation one or more times over the maturity of the contract (Kwan and Carleton, 1993). We are not aware of any hard data on the frequency of covenant renegotiation for bank loans, but anecdotal evidence suggests that bank loans with covenants are renegotiated even more frequently than private placements (Carey et al., 1993). The use of covenants on small business loans is a very underresearched ®eld, but there is some empirical evidence on the use of covenants in bank lending to larger ®rms. An empirical analysis of mid-sized ®rms con®rms the positive role of covenants in bank loan agreements in making external funding available at reasonably low cost. It was found that the investment expenditures of ®rms with bank loan commitments carrying strong covenants were less sensitive to cash ¯ow than ®rms with loan commitments carrying weak covenants or those without commitments (Morgan, 1995). It was also found that the bank loans and commitments to mid-sized and large ®rms that were syndicated most broadly tend to carry the most covenants, suggesting that covenants play a positive role in assuring other syndicate members that sucient controls on ®rm behavior are in place or that members will be informed of changes in ®rm condition when covenants waivers are negotiated (Carey, 1996).

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

645

The choice of debt maturity is similarly used by ®nancial institutions as a contract feature to address control and information problems. The longer the agreement, the greater the opportunity for the borrower to alter its risk pro®le and/or su€er ®nancial distress. Maturity can be viewed as a particularly strong type of covenant. With a sequence of short-maturity credits, a lender can force renegotiation frequently. In contrast, with covenants renegotiation can only be triggered by those covenants enumerated in the loan agreement. One reason that smaller ®rms typically have less access to longer maturity debt is that they tend to be more both informationally opaque and more risky than large ®rms, which would create more severe problems of risk-shifting for small ®rms in long-term lending agreements. In addition, very small ®rms do not have audited ®nancial statements, making it extremely dicult to impose ratio-related ®nancial covenants that typically accompany intermediate and long-term bank debt. 25 4.3.4. Relationship lending Under relationship lending, information is gathered by a ®nancial institution through continuous contact with the ®rm and entrepreneur in the provision of ®nancial services. This information is then used to help make additional decisions over time about the evolution of contract terms and monitoring strategies. The information produced in conjunction with the relationship may be garnered over time in conjunction with the extension of credit (e.g., Petersen and Rajan, 1994; Berger and Udell, 1995), the provision of deposit services (e.g., Allen et al., 1991; Nakamura, 1993; Cole, 1998), or the delivery of other ®nancial services to the ®rm or to the entrepreneur. This information production can occur over a much longer period of time than any one debt contract or deposit account. As shown in Table 2 above, the existing relationships between small businesses and their primary ®nancial institutions have lasted for over 9 years on average. The vast majority of small businesses identify their commercial bank as their primary institution, presumably because banks provide the widest range of credit, deposit, and other related services. Relationship lending may have a number of bene®ts to small business, including lower cost or greater availability of credit due to ecient gathering of information, protection against credit crunches, or the provision of implicit interest rate or credit risk insurance. Information garnered over time in conjunction with a series of loans may be derived from the accumulation of a repayment history, periodic submissions of ®nancial statements, renegotiations, visits with management, and other data associated with on-going monitoring of the borrowing ®rm. Deposit accounts provide further information in the form of balance information, transactions
25

For a comprehensive survey on debt maturity, see Ravid (1996).

646

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

activity, payroll data, etc. that help give a more complete picture of the ®nancial health of the ®rm. Information about the quality of the entrepreneur may also be culled from the provision of personal loans, credit cards, deposit accounts, trust accounts, investment services, etc., and from other business dealings or personal contact outside the ®rm. Knowledge of the local community gained over time may also be valuable because it allows the bank to judge the market in which the business operates, to obtain references and feedback on borrower performance, and to evaluate the quality of the ®rm's receivables. Consolidating the purchase of ®nancial services within a single bank may substantially strengthen the relationship, as well as increasing the sources of revenue to the bank. Frequently, this is an explicit requirement imposed by banks on their small business customers. Under relationship lending, the bank arguably has some market power over the information gained during the relationship. This market power may come from exclusive access to the information if rival lenders cannot appropriate the information culled by the bank from the deposit and loan accounts of the ®rm and the entrepreneur. Alternatively, the market power may come from longterm contracting, such as long-term loans (which small businesses typically do not have). Market power may also derive from substantial switching costs that prevent the borrowing ®rm from leaving when faced with above-competitive prices, which is more likely to occur, the more tailored the services provided by the bank. Finally, market power may come from limits on competition in the lending and deposit markets, such as those that might characterize highly concentrated rural banking markets. Ironically, market power by the bank may play a positive role for the small business customer by allowing the bank to enforce long-term implicit contracts in which the borrower receives a subsidized interest rate in the short term, and then compensates the bank by paying a higher-than-competitive rate in a later period (Sharpe, 1990). As the market power of the bank increases, small businesses with progressively lower credit quality may be able to obtain funding (Petersen and Rajan, 1995). However, excessive exploitation of market power can also create other problems. These problems may include the establishment of multiple banking relationships by borrowers to avoid exploitation, which can create higher transactions costs, duplicated e€ort, free-rider problems, etc. Market power may also lead to increased agency costs (greater risk-taking, reduced managerial e€ort) because of high rates. In addition, some small businesses with positive net present value investment opportunities may simply choose not to borrow and invest in order to avoid future exploitation by the lender. These problems may be reduced by the use of loan commitments that limit the ability of a bank to exploit a borrower later in the relationship by prespecifying contract terms (Houston and Venkataram, 1994). The tradeo€ between the bene®cial e€ects of the ecient gathering of information though the relationship

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

647

versus the potential problems created by the exploitation of this market power is one of the central issues in relationship lending research. Some of the adverse incentive e€ects of market power over relationship information may be mitigated by the release of some of this information. Padilla and Pagano (1997) showed that banks may increase their pro®ts by sharing some of their private information about the condition of a small business (e.g., by giving this information to a credit bureau). Essentially, by giving away information and pro®ts in future periods, the bank may make higher current pro®ts by encouraging additional entrepreneurial e€ort. The logic of Padilla and Pagano's model may be extended to other problems created by market power. In many circumstances, it may be in the bank's interest to reveal information learned through relationship lending with a lag. The bank may be able to earn some rents o€ the information in the short term and demonstrate to the small business that it will not be fully exploited in the long run. The use of a single relationship bank by a small business may also create a problem in which having credit withdrawn by the bank may signal unfavorable information about the small business, even if there has been no deterioration in the condition of the small business. This may occur because the bank experiences its own liquidity problem, which cannot be distinguished from an individual borrower's credit problem. As a result, small businesses may maintain multiple banking relationships, creating higher transactions costs. Detragiache et al. (1997) showed that this problem may be particularly severe in economies in which bankruptcy costs are high (so greater costs are borne if the borrower is unfunded) and in which banks rarely have liquidity problems (so that a withdrawal of credit by one bank is more likely to be interpreted by others as a credit problem for the borrower). They suggested that these conditions hold more closely in Italy than in the US, which may help explain why Italian small businesses have a mode of seven banking relationships and US small businesses have a mode of one banking relationship (their Table 1). The bene®ts and costs of relationships have been shown to some degree in empirical research using data on large business. For example, the ``bank uniqueness'' literature suggests that banking relationships o€er important bene®ts even for ®rms that are suciently informationally transparent as to have publicly traded equity. Studies found that announcements of bank loan commitments and similar credit facilities yield abnormal positive stock returns on average for the borrowing ®rms (Mikkelson and Partch, 1986; James, 1987; Lummer and McConnell, 1989; Billett et al., 1995). 26 These results
The size of the e€ect found depended upon the type of institution issuing the contract (bank, ®nance company, insurance company issuing a private placement, etc.), whether the contract was a new commitment or a renewal, the credit rating of the issuing institution (commitments from higher-rated institutions yielding greater excess returns), and whether the line was secured (higher return for secured lines).
26

648

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

suggest that the relationships embodied by these commitments add value, and that the creation of this value is signaled to market participants. By extension, if relationships are valuable for large, relatively transparent ®rms, they are likely even more valuable for small, relatively opaque ®rms. Other research on large ®rms suggests that the ``hold-up'' problem discussed above ± in which the bank may exploit market power over the borrower subsequent to information production ± may also apply to ®rms with access to public debt markets. Some research suggests that these ®rms may try to reduce the control of their banks by issuing public debt, even though public debt may entail higher costs (Diamond, 1991, 1993; Rajan, 1992; Houston and James, 1996). These large ®rms may also engage in multiple banking relationships in order to obtain additional needed funding that might otherwise be withheld by a single bank with monopoly access over relationship information (Houston and James, 1996). 27 Presumably, if market power by a single relationship bank is a signi®cant problem for large, informationally transparent ®rms that can issue public debt, it may be even more of a problem for small, informationally opaque ®rms that do not have access to public debt markets. The relationship lending literature often focuses on whether the terms of bank lending ease or tighten over the course of the relationship as the relationship strengthens and the bank gains access to more information. The extant theory o€ers con¯icting predictions. In Petersen and Rajan (1995), initial asymmetric information creates adverse selection and moral hazard problems in which banks charge high rates initially and reduce rates in later periods after borrower types have been revealed. Similarly, Boot and Thakor (1994) predict that borrowers pay high rates and pledge collateral early in the relationship, and then pay lower rates and do not pledge collateral later in the relationship after they have demonstrated some project success. In contrast, Greenbaum et al. (1989), Sharpe (1990), and Wilson (1993) all demonstrated conditions under which lenders subsidize borrowers in early periods and are reimbursed for this subsidy with high rates in later periods, so terms of lending for small businesses may worsen over the course of the relationship. The empirical results on this issue are mixed. Using the 1987 NSSBF data on US small businesses, it was found that interest rates and collateral requirements on lines of credit tend to decline with the length of the bank±borrower

One solution intermediate between single- and multiple-relationship banking is to have a special relationship with one bank while borrowing from multiple banks. An example is the ``housebank'' system for mid-sized borrowers in Germany (Elsas and Krahnen, 1997).

27

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

649

relationship for some small businesses (Berger and Udell, 1995), although rates on loans generally did not decline with the length of the relationship when loans not issued under lines of credit were included (Petersen and Rajan, 1994). One potential explanation for this di€erence is that the value of a relationship may depend on the type of credit. Lines of credit may more often be relationship-driven, whereas mortgages, equipment loans, motor vehicle loans, and other loans may more often be transactions-driven. 28 It was also found that dependence on trade credit decreased with the length of the banking relationship, supporting the value of relationship lending (Petersen and Rajan, 1994, 1995). Using the 1993 NSSBF, it was found that the existence of a relationship between the small business and the bank raised the probability that credit would be extended (Cole, 1998). Cole also found that the breadth of the relationship was quite important ± credit was particularly likely to be extended if the ®rm also obtained savings account and ®nancial management services from the same bank. Another analysis using data on two US bank holding companies found no clear e€ect of the duration of the relationship on the rates charged to small businesses (Blackwell and Winters, 1997). A study of Italian cooperative banks (which specialize in small business lending to their own members) and conventional commercial banks yielded some interesting di€erences depending on the type of relationship (Angelini et al., 1998). For small businesses that are members of cooperatives, rates decline and credit availability increases with the length of their relationship with the cooperative bank. In contrast, rates increase with the duration of the relationship for nonmember borrowers from cooperatives and for borrowers from commercial banks. A study of publicly traded Norwegian ®rms of varying sizes found that the probability of ending a banking relationship was higher when relationships were mature, suggesting that more information is generated early in relationships (Ongena and Smith, 1997). They also found that the probability of ending the relationship was higher if the ®rm was young, small, and growing, presumably when relationships could do the most to overcome informational opacity problems. This may suggest either that the banks tried to exploit market power over information and drove some of these borrowers away or that the information the banks learned was often unfavorable, and banks purposely set contract terms to drive away the borrowers with unfavorable information. A study of mid-sized German ®rms found no association

28 Supporting this notion, it was found that 88.8% of small business borrowers with lines of credit had these lines at only a single bank, where borrowers with two or more of other types of bank loans (mortgages, equipment loans, motor vehicle loans, other loans) had these loans consolidated at a single bank only about 50% of the time or less (Berger and Udell, 1995).

650

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

between relationship duration and loan pricing, but did ®nd some evidence of better credit availability through stronger bank±borrower relationships (Elsas and Krahnen, 1997). Speci®cally, Elsas and Krahnen found that the ®rm's ``housebank'' ± the bank with which the ®rm has its closest or strongest relationship ± was willing to provide liquidity during periods of ®rm distress, whereas other banks were not. A study using survey data on smaller German ®rms found that longer relationships were associated with lower collateral requirements, but no di€erence in interest rates (Harho€ and Korting, 1997). However, ®rms that described their banking relationship as one of mutual trust in response to a survey question had both lower loan rates and lower collateral requirements. The results in this literature suggest three tentative conclusions. First, the strength of the relationship as measured by its duration or other factors is usually, but not always, associated with easier credit terms for the small business in terms of lower rates, fewer collateral requirements, less dependence on trade credit, or more availability of funds. This lends support to the notion that relationship lending appears to be an ecient information collection mechanism and at least indirectly suggests that problems with the exploitation of market power are not so severe as to o€set the bene®ts of pursuing a relationship in most cases. However, there are important exceptions. For example, most small businesses in Italy borrow from multiple banks and face higher rates as their relationships mature. Second, there is considerable uncertainty about the exact mechanism through which banks obtain and use relationship information and how best to measure the strength of the relationship (i.e., how to proxy for the value of information obtained through the relationship). Most of the studies speci®ed the duration of the relationship as the measure of its strength. The results of some of the studies also suggested that in addition to duration, the strength of the relationship may also depend upon: (1) whether the loan is drawn under a line of credit, (2) the breadth of the relationship (whether it extends to deposits and other services), (3) the size of the borrowing ®rm and its outside ®nancing options, (4) the structure of the banking industry, and (5) the trust that is built up between the bank and the small business. Further research is needed to determine how banks obtain and use the information acquired through relationships. Third, the e€ects of relationships di€er across nations, presumably due to di€erences in their macroeconomic environments in terms of information infrastructure, business conditions, and regulatory regime. The single banking relationships of small businesses in the US and most other nations versus the multiple banking relationships of small businesses in Italy may be at least partially explainable by di€erences in the concentration of the banking industry,

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

651

the fragility of the ®nancial systems, bankruptcy rules, and other factors that a€ect the collection and use of information by banks. 29 5. The vulnerability of small business ®nance to the macroeconomic environment The ¯ow of funds to small business in private equity and debt markets is likely to depend in an important way upon ¯uctuations in the macroeconomic environment, such as shocks to the real or ®nancial sectors or changes in government policy. Because of its informational opacity, small business arguably is likely to bear a disproportionate share of the loss of funding that occurs when there is a market failure. In this section, we consider a number of areas of research related to this vulnerability, including the e€ects of public equity market disruptions and public policy changes on the ¯ow of funds into angel ®nance and venture capital markets, and the e€ects of monetary policy shocks, credit crunches, and the consolidation of the banking industry on the ¯ow of funds to small business in banking markets. 5.1. The ¯ow of funds into angel ®nance and venture capital markets Business conditions in general can a€ect the ¯ow of funds in the private equity and debt markets. The ¯ow and pricing of private equity depend crucially on the public equity markets. The pricing of angel ®nance and venture capital at the origination stage are based in great part on forecasts of valuation at the time of exit. One of the principal valuation techniques involves taking current public market price/earnings multiples and applying them to forecasted earnings at exit. The ex post behavior of the stock market will then determine the timing of exit through the IPO and subsequent o€erings, and the valuations associated with those o€erings. Thus, when stock market values fall, this can create a chain reaction in which the highly volatile IPO market shuts down, which then may reduce the ¯ow of funds in private angel ®nance and venture capital equity markets.
29 A related issue is the extent to which the public reputation of the ®rm a€ects the terms of credit faced by the small business versus the private information held by the primary bank gained through relationship lending (i.e., reputation versus monitoring as in Diamond, 1991). Many of the studies just reviewed also found that the age of the ®rm was also quite important to obtaining bank credit on easier terms. Assuming that age proxies well for public reputation, this suggests that public reputation may be of a similar order of importance as the establishment of a strong banking relationship to obtaining favorable credit terms. An additional study also found that the e€ect of the longest banking relationship dominated the e€ect of the length of the relationship of the bank with credit currently outstanding (Covitz, 1997). This suggests that some of the information obtained through relationships may be appropriable by other lenders, or that the bank does not have full market power over the use of this information.

652

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

It has been found that high realized returns in the venture capital industry driven by current stock prices tend to lead to increased capital commitments to venture capital funds (Gompers and Lerner, 1997; Gompers, 1998). Gompers (1998) argued that recently high stock market valuations may have led to an ``overheating'' of the primary venture capital market. He also found that this increase in the supply of funds ¯owing into venture capital appears to be associated with a number of di€erent changes in venture capital contracts including: an increase in the share of pro®ts retained by fund general partners; less restrictions in partnership agreements; a shift into later-stage investments; and an increased appetite for international investments. The ebb and ¯ow of funds into venture capital raises the question of why the primary market for venture capital appears to be myopic and vulnerable to waves of pessimism and optimism. We do not have the answer, except to observe that anecdotal evidence suggests that the same myopia seems to exist in primary stock markets, real estate markets, and credit markets. For example, waves of optimism and pessimism may also characterize the pricing of commercial bank loans as credit standards ¯uctuate over the business cycle. The venture capital industry is relatively new, but as an intermediated industry, it may be subject to the same types of shocks as those that a€ect the commercial banking industry. For instance, some institutional investors might severely contract their new investments in venture capital when they su€er losses in other parts of their portfolios. As indicated earlier, corporate and public pension funds plus endowments together provide more than half of the funding for venture capital limited partnerships. This type of contraction might be similar to the contraction in bank lending that occurred during the credit crunch of the early 1990s (discussed below) that appears to have been caused in part by losses in the banking industry's commercial real estate portfolio. These issues of ¯uctuations in venture capital funding are extremely interesting and pose dicult challenges for future research. The overwhelming importance of institutional investors in the US venture capital market is also of interest in and of itself. Prior to the 1980s, US pension funds were e€ectively barred from any economically signi®cant investment in venture capital because of prudent man rules. However, in 1979 the Department of Labor reinterpreted the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) to permit pension fund investment in venture capital provided that it did not endanger the entire portfolio. These and other regulatory changes led to a large increase in the ¯ow of funds into venture capital. As patient investors, pension funds and endowments along with life insurance companies may be ideally suited for investing in venture capital. Today, vibrant formal venture capital industries are for the most part limited to the US and UK. The US experience suggests that other countries may wish to consider public policy initiatives that encourage the development

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

653

of pension funds and their regulatory ¯exibility to invest in venture capital. 30 However, the absence of well-developed public equity markets in continental Europe and elsewhere has arguably been a signi®cant impediment to the development of venture capital industries. A distinguishing feature of the US ®nancial landscape that makes venture capital investing so attractive is the existence of well-developed public equity markets, particularly markets for small cap stocks such as NASDAQ, which provide the up-side exit for venture capitalists. 5.2. The e€ects of shocks to the banking industry on small business ®nance In recent years, there have been banking crises involving failures, capital shortfalls, regulatory changes, or other diculties in a number of countries ± including Japan, Korea, the Scandinavian countries, the US, and others ± followed by periods of recessions or reduced economic growth. The transmission mechanism from distress in the banking industry to a decline in macroeconomic performance is not fully known, but arguably it may work in part through a reduction in bank credit to small businesses. Financial distress in the banking industry can have a short-term e€ect on lending as banks shrink and reduce their credit risk exposure and try to rebuild equity capital ratios. In addition, bank failures can impose a long-run cost because of the loss of bank±borrower relationships and the information built up through contact over time, making it dicult for some borrowers to continue funding investments that have positive net present values (Slovin et al., 1993). This would most likely a€ect informationally opaque small businesses that depend on their banks and would have diculty ®nding external ®nance elsewhere. In turn, this reduction in investment may exacerbate regional or macroeconomic diculties (Bernanke, 1983). The regulation and supervision of banks to keep them safe and sound is often justi®ed at least in part on the basis of avoiding systemic crises that might substantially reduce the supply of credit to bank-dependent small businesses. 5.2.1. Monetary policy shocks The ``credit channels'' of monetary policy transmission are two distinct hypothesized mechanisms through which monetary policy shocks may have disproportionately large e€ects on small business funding. These mechanisms ± which are based on imperfections in private debt markets ± operate alongside the traditional ``money view'' channel in which monetary policy operates through changing interest rates, which a€ect the real spending preferences of economic agents.

30 Many countries, such as Germany, have pay-as-you-go pension systems, and therefore do not have large pension fund industries.

654

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

According to the ``bank lending view'', the reduction in bank reserves that accompanies a monetary policy tightening results in some banks reducing their supply of loans. This reduction in loan supply forces some borrowers to reduce real spending and slow the macroeconomy because alternative means of funding are unavailable or una€ordable, at least in the short term (Bernanke and Blinder, 1988). To the extent that the bank lending view holds, it suggests that monetary policy shocks may have disproportionately large e€ects on bank-dependent relationship borrowers with few alternative sources of funds. This may often apply to small businesses ± at least the half that borrow from banks. The empirical research generally con®rms the two main empirical implications of the bank lending view ± that tight monetary policy reduces the supply of bank loans, and that reduced bank lending slows the macroeconomy (see Kashyap and Stein, 1997 for a survey). In addition to the aggregate evidence, the data also con®rm that much of the aggregate slowing may be due to adjustments by small businesses. One such ®nding is that monetary policy appears to have a more potent impact on small banks than large banks (Kashyap and Stein, 1995). This is likely to work disproportionately through small ®rms, since small banks tend to specialize in small business lending. Another ®nding is that monetary policy shocks appear to a€ect the growth and investment of small manufacturing ®rms more than large manufacturers (Gertler and Gilchrist, 1994; Bernanke et al., 1996). According to the second credit channel mechanism, the ``balance sheet channel'' or ``®nancial accelerator'', the tightening of monetary policy works in part because the associated higher interest rates impair collateral values or otherwise reduce the net worth of certain borrowers, making them less creditworthy and diminishing their ability to obtain funds. Of course, this mechanism can ``accelerate'' the e€ects on the macroeconomy of any shock that reduces collateral values or net worth (e.g., oil price increase, real estate market crash), magnifying the e€ect on the macroeconomy by exacerbating existing information-driven contracting problems between borrowers and lenders. The balance sheet channel is likely to have a disproportionate e€ect on the small businesses that have loans from ®nancial institutions, which were found in Table 2 above to pledge collateral on more than 90% of these loans. This balance sheet channel di€ers from the bank lending channel in that it implies a reduction in the demand for credit by creditworthy borrowers from all lenders, rather than a reduction in the supply of credit by banks in response to monetary policy tightening. A variety of empirical evidence provides support for this balance sheet channel and its disproportionately large e€ect on small businesses, including ®ndings linking monetary policy with changes in balance sheet strength, and ®ndings linking balance sheet positions with real spending decisions (see Bernanke and Gertler, 1995; Bernanke et al., 1996 for summaries).

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

655

5.2.2. The credit crunch The early 1990s in the US has been labeled a credit crunch mostly because of the decline in business lending by US banks. From the end of 1989 to the end of 1992, real domestic commercial and industrial (C&I) loans held by US banks fell 23.2%, a decline in 1994 dollars from $596.7 billion to $458.2 billion. Rough estimates based on extrapolation from the STBL suggested that the proportional decline in small business lending (loans to borrowers with bank credit less than $1 million) was considerably greater ± an estimated fall of 38.5% from $143.7 billion to $88.4 billion in 1994 dollars (Berger et al., 1995). Analysis of other data sources, including the NFIB (Dunkelberg and Dennis, 1992) and NSSBF (Avery et al., 1998) also suggested that bank credit was more dicult to obtain for small businesses in the early 1990s than in the late 1980s. A number of hypotheses of the decline in credit have been tested, including the e€ects of implementation of the Basle-Accord risk-based capital standards, which generally raised capital requirements against business loans (Haubrich and Wachtel, 1993; Berger and Udell, 1994; Hancock and Wilcox, 1994a; Wagster, 1997), regulatory capital actions based on leverage ratios (Berger and Udell, 1994; Peek and Rosengren, 1994, 1995a; Hancock and Wilcox, 1994a; Hancock et al., 1995), depletion of bank capital from loan loss experiences of the late 1980s (Peek and Rosengren 1994, 1995a; Hancock and Wilcox, 1994a, 1997), greater regulatory scrutiny, including tightened examination criteria, loan loss reserve policies, and formal actions (Bizer, 1993; Peek and Rosengren, 1995b; Wagster, 1997), choices of lower risk pro®les by bank managers (Hancock and Wilcox, 1993, 1994b), reduced loan demand because of macroeconomic or regional recessions (Bernanke and Lown, 1991; Hancock and Wilcox, 1993, 1997), or a secular decline in the demand for bank loans because of the growth of alternative sources of credit (Berger and Udell, 1994). Although this literature falls short of consensus, the empirical ®ndings generally do not support risk-based capital as a major contributor to the lending slowdown, but do provide some support for most of the other hypotheses. One study was able to examine the e€ects of changes in bank capital, loan delinquency rates, and other factors not only on bank lending, but also on the health of small businesses in the same state during the credit crunch (Hancock and Wilcox, 1998). Hancock and Wilcox found that a $1 capital decline at a small bank reduced C&I lending more than a $1 capital decline at a large bank. More important, they found that reductions in capital at small banks during the credit crunch led to statistically and economically signi®cant reductions in the employment, payroll, and number of small businesses in the state. These results highlight the importance of bank lending to small business, and suggest a signi®cant role for capital problems at small banks in the regional and national slowdowns in the early 1990s.

656

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

5.3. Credit rationing of small business over the interest rate and credit risk cycles Theories of credit rationing (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981 and others) suggest that adverse selection and moral hazard problems associated with informationally opaque borrowers may be exacerbated when open-market interest rates rise. Lenders may not be able to raise the interest rate to such borrowers in lock-step with rates on government securities for fear of attracting lower quality borrowers or inducing risk-shifting behavior. A result is ``sticky'' loan interest rates and equilibrium credit rationing. It seems likely that if a signi®cant amount of such rationing by banks occurs, it would disproportionately a€ect the availability of credit to small businesses. A number of empirical studies found evidence that bank loan rates to business are sticky, providing some support for equilibrium rationing (Slovin and Sushka, 1983; King, 1986; So®anos et al., 1990). However, one study used individual loan data from the STBL and found evidence suggesting that this stickiness did not re¯ect substantial credit rationing. The stickiness was approximately equal for new loans under commitment, which are protected from rationing, and new loans not under commitment. Moreover, the ratio of commitment loans to noncommitment loans did not rise substantially when open-market rates were high, as would be the case if noncommitment borrowers were being rationed (Berger and Udell, 1992). Nonetheless, another study using a di€erent data set on the stock of bank loans found that the commitment/noncommitment loan ratio did rise substantially when monetary policy tightened (Morgan, 1998). One explanation for loan rate stickiness other than credit rationing is that banks might provide implicit interest insurance to some of their relationship borrowers. Banks can smooth loan interest rates by providing loans at below-market interest rates for risk-averse relationship borrowers when market rates are high and make up for this with above-market rates to the same borrowers when market rates are low or with higher prices on other ®nancial products (Fried and Howitt, 1980). This may be facilitated by the presence of core deposits with similarly sticky interest rates (Berlin and Mester, 1997). As was the case for other bene®ts from relationship lending described above, the provision of interest rate insurance may be facilitated by the bank having market power over the information acquired through the relationship. The expected future rents to be earned on exclusive access to this information may provide the incentive for the bank to lend at a loss in the short term. Some empirical evidence supports the notion of interest rate insurance. Some loan interest rates reported on the STBL were below the US Treasury rate of comparable repayment duration when Treasury rates were very high (Berger and Udell, 1992). Such loans have negative expected economic returns, and cannot easily be justi®ed without reference to expected pro®ts from elsewhere within the length or breadth of a relationship. Other evidence of loan interest rate stickiness or smoothing on STBL small business loans has also

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

657

been found, and this stickiness was associated with higher pro®tability, consistent with the presence of interest rate insurance that represents ecient contracting (Berlin and Mester, 1998). It is similarly possible that banks provide implicit credit risk insurance to some of their relationship borrowers. Banks may continue to provide credit at an expected loss to relationship borrowers that are in temporary distress in the expectation that the short-run loss may be made up in the long run by the value of continuing the relationship. Similar to implicit interest rate insurance, implicit credit risk insurance may be facilitated by the bank having market power over information generated through contact over time in the relationship. Some evidence discussed above ± German ``housebanks'' lending during periods of distress ± is consistent with the presence of credit risk insurance. Similarly, Japanese businesses with longstanding relationships with a main bank have been found to have lower costs of overcoming periods of ®nancial distress (Hoshi et al., 1990). Smoothing of rates in response to credit risk shocks was also found in US data, but such smoothing was not clearly associated with higher or lower bank pro®ts, and so may or may not represent an ecient contracting mechanism (Berlin and Mester, 1998). 5.4. Consolidation of ®nancial institutions and the supply of small business credit Mergers and acquisitions (M&As) of banks and other ®nancial institutions raise a policy concern that the larger organizations created by these M&As may reduce the availability of credit to small businesses, given the empirical regularity that large banking institutions devote lesser proportions of their assets to small business loans than small institutions (Berger et al., 1995; Keeton, 1995; Levonian and Soller, 1995; Berger and Udell, 1996; Peek and Rosengren, 1996; Strahan and Weston, 1996). As of the June 1997 CALL, banks with less than $100 million in assets had about 9% of their portfolios invested in small business loans (measured as loans to business borrowers with bank credit less than $1 million), whereas banks with over $10 billion in assets devoted only about 2% of their assets to these loans. This empirical regularity may occur in part because small institutions generally cannot make large business loans due to legal lending limits and problems of diversi®cation. In addition, large institutions may be disinclined to extend relationship-driven small business loans because of Williamson (1967, 1988) type organizational diseconomies associated with producing such loans alongside their core business of producing transactions-driven loans and other services for large business customers. That is, it may be too costly to provide relationship-based services ± which often demand intimate knowledge gained over time through contact with the small business, its owner, and its local market ± together with the capital market ®nancial services in which large banks tend to specialize.

658

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

The lending quantity data alone do not indicate whether it is relationship loans versus transaction loans that are being issued in lesser proportions by large banking organizations. Nonetheless, some evidence on this point is provided by pricing data. Large banks have been found not only to have much smaller proportions of loans to small borrowers, but they also tend to charge substantially lower average prices to the small borrowers who receive credit from them. Large banks are estimated to charge about 100 basis points less on small businesses loans and require collateral about 25% less of the time than small banks, other things equal (Berger and Udell, 1996). These data are consistent with the view that large banks tend to issue small business loans to higher-quality transactions-driven credits that can be evaluated based on the same type of analysis of ®nancial ratios as large borrowers, rather than relationshipdriven loans to informationally opaque small businesses that tend to have higher interest rates and collateral requirements. Similar arguments may be made about the e€ects of greater organizational complexity that may be associated with the banking institutions formed by M&As. For example, a multibank holding company with multiple layers of management that acquires an independent bank in another region of the nation may ®nd it costly to process relationship-based information acquired through contact over time by a local loan ocer in a distant local market. However, the data are not as clear regarding complexity as they were regarding size. One study using the STBL found no clear e€ect of complexity on small business lending (Berger and Udell, 1996), whereas studies using CALL data have split on the measured e€ect of out-of-state ownership of banks (Keeton, 1995; Whalen, 1995). A counterargument is that multibank holding companies may be ecient small-business lenders because they can act as internal capital markets that distribute funds to banks with superior local lending opportunities. Supporting this view, it was found that loan growth was less constrained by the bank's ®nancial condition if the bank was part of a multibank holding company than if it was unaliated. Instead, what was most important for lending by aliated banks was the ®nancial condition of their holding company (Houston et al., 1997; Houston and James, 1998). The actual e€ects of M&As on the supply of small business credit by the consolidating institutions depend not only on the increases in size and organizational complexity of the consolidating institutions, but also on other dynamic changes in their behavior, including possible changes in organizational focus by these institutions. Some studies have analyzed the dynamics of M&As by comparing small business lending by the consolidating institutions before and after M&As (Keeton, 1996, 1997; Peek and Rosengren, 1996, 1998; Strahan and Weston, 1996, 1998; Craig and Santos, 1997; Kolari and Zardkoohi, 1997a, b; Zardkoohi and Kolari, 1997; Walraven, 1997; Berger et al., 1998). The results often di€er by type of merger or acquisition, sizes of organizations,

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

659

econometric technique employed, and number of years after M&A the lending data were examined. The most common ®ndings are that consolidations of large banking organizations (which involve most of the assets involved in M&As) tend to reduce small business lending, whereas consolidations involving small organizations tend to increase small business lending, but there are exceptions to these ®ndings. The total change in the supply of small business credit from M&As also depends on the reactions of other lenders. For example, if a bank reduces its supply of relationship-driven credit because of diseconomies associated with supplying transactions-driven services, other lenders that are not burdened by these diseconomies may react by picking up some or all of these credits. These could occur by other local institutions stepping in or by de novo institutions started by loan ocers who have left the consolidating institutions taking some of their relationship-based loan portfolios with them. One study measured the e€ects of M&As on the lending of other banks in the same local markets and found evidence suggesting that changes in the supplies of small business credit by these other banks tended to o€set much, if not all of the negative e€ects on small business lending of M&As (Berger et al., 1998). Two other studies found that de novo banks tend to lend more to small businesses as a percentage of assets than other small banks of comparable size, also consistent with the possibility of a positive small business lending reaction to M&As (Goldberg and White, 1998; DeYoung, 1998). Thus, the evidence to date gives some general tendencies of the e€ects of M&As on the lending of the banks involved, but the information to date on the reactions of other lenders and the extent to which these reactions run through existing versus de novo banks is quite thin. Moreover, these studies concentrate primarily on the quantities of credit issued, and not the rates charged or other contract terms. The evidence on relationship lending cited above suggests that some borrowers that are dropped by consolidating banks and picked up by other lenders may not only have temporary disruptions of credit, but may also have to pay higher loan rates, pledge more collateral, or be more dependent on trade credit in the short term until their new banking relationships mature. 6. Conclusions Public focus on small business ®nance derives both from the spectacular success of some recent entrepreneurial ®rms and from concern that many small businesses with positive net present value projects may not be able to obtain sucient external ®nance. Causes for concern include, among others, the recent credit crunches in Asia and the US, the lack of well-developed venture capital markets in continental Europe and elsewhere, and the potential impact

660

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

of ®nancial institution consolidation on the availability of credit to small business everywhere. This paper explores a number of facets of small ®rm ®nance, the investors and intermediaries that provide it, and the private equity and debt markets in which they function. We see much of small business ®nance through a growth cycle paradigm, in which di€erent capital structures are optimal at di€erent points in the cycle, although we emphasize that this paradigm does not ®t all small businesses. The issues surrounding capital structure for small businesses are generally di€erent from those that are most important for large corporations, and often involve the intertwining of the personal ®nances of the entrepreneur and other insiders with the ®nances of the ®rm. Unlike large ®rms, small ®rms typically have a substantial amount of their funding provided by insiders ± the entrepreneur, other members of the start-up team, family, and friends. In addition, small businesses generally receive their external funding in private equity and debt markets, rather than public markets. Part of the capital structure decision for small ®rms is whether and when to enter public capital markets via an IPO, although the vast majority of ®rms never reach this point in the ®nancial growth cycle. Even the distinction between insider ®nance and external ®nance in small business is not always completely clear, since insiders often give personal guarantees or pledge personal collateral against external debt provided by ®nancial institutions. The intermediaries in private markets also evaluate the personal ®nances of the inside owners ± including assets that are not invested in the ®rm ± so these personal assets also have a bearing on the capital structure of the ®rm. Finally, the vast majority of small businesses are ownermanaged, which alleviates agency con¯icts between owners and managers that a€ect capital structure choices in large corporations. However, owner management may introduce other factors into capital structure decisions of small ®rms, such as the owner/manager's level of risk aversion, or his/her incentive to issue external debt rather than external equity in order to keep ownership and control of the ®rm. We argue that the degree of informational opacity is a key feature that drives the ®nancial growth cycle and that distinguishes small business ®nance from large business ®nance. Deviations from the Modigliani and Miller (1958) assumption that agents can write contracts based on full information have been used to explain capital structure in corporate ®nance for the last 40 years, and these informational imperfections are arguably much more applicable to small business ®nance. Early in the growth cycle, small businesses typically do not have audited ®nancial statements, do not have many business assets that can be easily evaluated or pledged as collateral, and have little repayment history or record of pro®tability upon which external suppliers of funds can rely. For such ®rms, outsiders often put considerable weight on the creditworthiness and reputation of the entrepreneur, who may have a longer credit history, more pledgeable assets, and personal data that are easier to

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

661

evaluate than the records of the ®rm. Even after some experience, small businesses may remain opaque relative to large ®rms because their activities are not publicly visible, and because they do not issue traded securities which are continuously priced in public equity and debt markets. Theory o€ers some suggestions on the e€ects of informational opacity on capital structure. The pecking order suggests that informational opacity will favor ®rst using insider funds generated within the ®rm or from the entrepreneur and other insiders that have superior information about the ®rm. The modern information-based theory of security design predicts that the mix among external equity and debt sources will be a€ected by three dimensions of informational opacity ± costly state veri®cation, adverse selection, and moral hazard. Costly state veri®cation and adverse selection problems tend to favor external debt contracts, whereas moral hazard problems tend to favor external equity contracts. Di€erences in the relative severity of these information problems may help explain why certain types of small businesses obtain external equity from angels and venture capitalists, whereas other types tend to rely more on external debt from banks, ®nance companies, and trade creditors. Of course informational opacity also may keep ®rms from obtaining signi®cant amounts of external funding at all. Only about half of small businesses have loans outstanding from ®nancial institutions and even fewer tap external equity markets, although to some extent the lack of external ®nance may re¯ect the choice of the entrepreneur. The relative shares among private equity and debt suppliers also depend on their abilities to resolve information problems. Intermediaries engage in screening, contracting, and monitoring activities to address information problems. They o€er highly structured, complex contracts to small businesses, in contrast to the contracts employed in public markets which are more often generic in nature. Nonetheless, there are important di€erences among the intermediaries in the way they address the information problems of small businesses. For example, venture capitalists may participate in strategic planning and operational decision making, whereas banks use collateral, commitments, restrictive covenants, and short maturities to sort ®rm types and restrain ®rms from engaging in risk-shifting behavior. Banks also often form long-term relationships through continuous contact with the ®rm and entrepreneur in the provision of multiple ®nancial services. Banks then use the information gathered over the course of relationships to help make additional contracting and monitoring decisions, although the exercise of market power over this information can cause other problems. Trade creditors ± who provide almost as much credit to small business as banks ± may have superior information about the ®rm, may be able to solve incentive problems by threatening to withhold future supplies, may have advantages in repossessing and selling the supplied goods, and may be able to provide extra funds during crisis periods in the banking industry. The choice among these and other sources of funds depends in part on

662

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

which types of information problems the ®rm has, and which sources are best suited to resolve these problems. We identify the extent to which US small business is ®nanced by four di€erent sources of equity and nine di€erent sources of debt, and show how the capital structure changes with the size and age of the ®rm. This analysis con®rms some of the conventional wisdom and also o€ers some surprises. The three largest sources of funding are the principal owner, commercial banks, and trade creditors, which together account for over 70% of total small business ®nance, consistent with conventional wisdom. However, credit card debt appears to be surprisingly unimportant, providing less than 1% of small business ®nance. In addition, ®nancial institution debt appears to be an important source of funding to very young ®rms, contrary to the conventional wisdom that such funding would typically not be available to small businesses until they had acquired substantial tangible business assets that might be pledged as collateral. The data also provide a solution to this puzzle. The evidence suggests that ®nancial institution debt is often based on recourse against the personal wealth of the entrepreneur through guarantees or pledges of personal collateral. We use this taxonomy of sources of ®nance as a backdrop against which we analyze the extant research on a wide variety of sources of funding to small business, including insider seed ®nance, angel ®nance, venture capital, commercial bank and ®nance company loans, trade credit, government sponsored ®nance, and others. We also examine the nature of speci®c screening, contracting, and monitoring features associated with the provision of external equity and debt including among others, collateral, guarantees, commitments, covenants, maturity, relationship lending, interest rates, and venture capital pricing and control. In addition, the nature and importance of the ®nancial intermediaries and markets that provide external equity and debt to small business are analyzed. We emphasize that the modern theory of ®nancial intermediation is based largely on resolving information problems, which are most acute in small business ®nance. We also emphasize many ways in which the di€erent sources of small business ®nance are interconnected through reference to the growth cycle paradigm. The extant research is quite fragmented into separate literatures on such issues as ®nancial contracting, venture capital, relationship lending, the impact of credit crunches, the impact of banking industry consolidation, the IPO market, etc. Part of our objective is to bring these literatures together in one place. We try to make connections among these literatures in order to demonstrate how these various types of small ®rm ®nance and markets are related in ways that help explain ®nancial security design and capital market structure as it applies to small business. As well, we analyze the vulnerability of small ®rm ®nance to the macroeconomic environment. This involves a variety of issues including: the fragility of

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

663

private equity markets and their strong reactions to current events in public equity markets; the e€ects of monetary policy shifts; bank credit crunches caused by regulatory changes, macroeconomic conditions, or capital problems in the banking industry; credit rationing over the interest rate and credit risk cycles; and the continuing e€ects of the consolidation of ®nancial institutions. In great part, the vulnerability of small businesses to these changes stems from the informational opacity of small ®rms and imperfections in the screening, contracting, and monitoring procedures of intermediaries in addressing information problems. The legal and informational infrastructures also play key roles. Well-de®ned bankruptcy laws that clearly establish priority, clarify the process of bankruptcy, and reduce the uncertainty of outcome are critical. Information-rich environments characterized by well-de®ned accounting standards, sophisticated accounting expertise, and well-developed mechanisms for information sharing are also critical. Current research on contracting across countries suggests that these di€erences in environment can have signi®cant effects on contract structure, contracting costs, and the availability of external ®nance to small business. While much research has begun on the topic of small business ®nance, even more remains to be done. Our analysis of the ®nancial growth cycle and the interconnectedness of small ®rm ®nance suggests that some of the most exciting areas for future research may involve investigating how sources of small ®rm ®nance may change over the business cycle, in reaction to changes in government policy, during times of distress in private or public markets, and as information processing technology continues to improve. Moreover, it is important to determine the e€ects of the availability and cost of small business ®nance on the formation of new ®rms, their ability to engage in risky or opaque activities, and their e€ects on employment, real output, and economic growth. The availability of new data resources described and employed in research throughout this special issue should prove very useful in pursuing these and other research agendas on small business ®nance.

Acknowledgements The authors thank the Berkley Center for Entrepreneurial Studies and the New York University Solomon Center for sponsoring the conference on which this special issue is based, which was held at the New York University, May 2223, 1997. This paper was written while Udell was at New York University. We also thank Zoltan Acs, Mitch Berlin, Emilia Bonaccorsi, Seth Bonime, Mark Carey, Dan Covitz, Hesna Genay, Gibi George, Mark Gertler, Jere Glover, Diana Hancock, Anil Kashyap, Nellie Liang, Zachary Magaw, Nicole Meleney, Loretta Mester, Don Morgan, Patricia Miller-Edwards, Charles Ou,

664

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Loretta Poole, Phil Strahan, Larry White, and John Wolken for help with the article, the special issue, and the conference.

References
Acs, Z., Tarpley, F.A., Jr., 1998. The angel capital electronic network (ACE-Net). Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 793±798, this issue. Adler, B.E., 1993. An equity agency solution to the bankruptcy priority puzzle. Journal of Legal Studies 22, 73±98. Admati, A.R., P¯eiderer, P., 1994. Robust ®nancial contracting and the role of venture capitalists. Journal of Finance 49, 371±402. Allen, L., Saunders, A., Udell, G.F., 1991. The pricing of retail deposits: Concentration and information. Journal of Financial Intermediation 1, 335±361. Amit, R., Glosten, L., Muller, E., 1990. Entrepreneurial ability, venture investments, and risk sharing. Management Science 36, 1232±1245. Ang, J.S., 1992. On the theory of ®nance for privately held ®rms. Journal of Small Business Finance 1, 185±203. Ang, J.S., Lin, J.W., Tyler, F., 1995. Evidence on the lack of separation between business and personal risks among small businesses. Journal of Small Business Finance 4, 197±210. Angelini, P., Di Salvo, R., Ferri, G., 1998. Availability and cost for small businesses: Customer relationships and credit cooperatives. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 925±954, this issue. Avery, R.B., Berger, A.N., 1991a. Loan commitments and bank risk exposure. Journal of Banking and Finance 15, 173±192. Avery, R.B., Berger, A.N., 1991b. Risk-based capital and deposit insurance reform. Journal of Banking and Finance 15, 847±874. Avery, R., Bostic, R.W., Samolyk, K.A., 1998. The evolution of small business ®nance: The role of personal wealth. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1019±1061, this issue. Barry, C.B., 1994. New directions in research on venture capital ®nance. Financial Management 23, 3±15. Barry, C.B., Muscarella, C.J., Peavy III, J.W., Vetsuypens, M.R., 1990. The role of venture capital in the creation of public companies: Evidence from the going public process. Journal of Financial Economics 27, 447±471. Benveniste, L.M., Busaba, W.Y., Wilhelm, W.J., 1996. Price stabilization as a bonding mechanism on new equity issues. Journal of Financial Economics 42, 223±255. Benveniste, L.M., Erdal, S.E., Wilhelm, W.J., Jr., 1998. Who bene®ts from secondary market price stabilization of IPOs? Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 741±767, this issue. Benveniste, L.M., Spindt, P.A., 1989. How investment bankers determine the o€er price and allocation of new issues. Journal of Financial Economics 24, 343±362. Bergemann, D., Hege, U., 1998. Dynamic venture capital ®nancing and learning. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 703±735, this issue. Berger, A.N., Kashyap, A.K., Scalise, J.M., 1995. The transformation of the US banking industry: What a long, strange trip its been. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 55±218. Berger, A.N., Saunders, A., Scalise, J.M., Udell, G.F., 1998. The e€ects of bank mergers and acquisitions on small business lending. Journal of Financial Economics 50. Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1990. Collateral, loan quality, and bank risk. Journal of Monetary Economics 25, 21±42. Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1992. Some evidence on the empirical signi®cance of credit rationing. Journal of Political Economy 100, 1047±1077.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

665

Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1993. Securitization, risk, and the liquidity problem in banking. In: Klausner, M., White, L.J. (Eds.), Structural Change in Banking. Irwin (Richard D.), Homewood, IL, pp. 227±291. Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1994. Did risk-based capital allocate bank credit and cause a `credit crunch' in the US? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 26, 585±628. Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1995. Relationship lending and lines of credit in small ®rm ®nance. Journal of Business 68, 351±382. Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1996. Universal banking and the future of small business lending. In: Saunders, A., Walter, I. (Eds.), Financial System Design: The case for universal banking. Irwin (Richard D.), Burr Ridge, IL, pp. 559±627. Berkovitch, E., Greenbaum, S.I., 1991. The loan commitment as an optimal ®nancing contract. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 26, 83±95. Berlin, M., Loeys, J., 1988. Bond covenants and delegated monitoring. Journal of Finance 43, 397± 412. Berlin, M., Mester, L.J., 1993. Debt covenants and renegotiation. Journal of Financial Intermediation 2, 95±133. Berlin, M., Mester, L.J., 1997. Why is the banking sector shrinking? Core deposits and relationship lending. Working paper #96-18R. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Berlin, M., Mester, L.J., 1998. On the pro®tability and cost of relationship lending. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 873±897, this issue. Bernanke, B., 1983. Non-monetary e€ects of the ®nancial crisis in the propagation of the great depression. American Economic Review 73, 257±276. Bernanke, B.S., Blinder, A., 1988. Credit, money, and aggregate demand. American Economic Review 78, 435±439. Bernanke, B.S., Gertler, M., 1995. Inside the black box: the credit channel of monetary policy transmission. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 27±48. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1996. The ®nancial accelerator, and the ¯ight to quality. Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 1±15. Bernanke, B.S., Lown, C.S., 1991. The credit crunch. Brookings Papers on Economics Activity 2, 205±248. Besanko, D., Thakor, A.V., 1987a. Collateral and rationing: Sorting equilibria in monopolistic and competitive markets. International Economic Review 28, 671±689. Besanko, D., Thakor, A.V., 1987b. Competitive equilibrium in the credit market under asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Theory 42, 167±182. Bester, H., 1985. Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review 75, 850±855. Biais, B., Gollier, C., 1997. Trade credit and credit rationing. Review of Financial Studies 10, 903±937. Billett, M.T., Flannery, M.J., Gar®nkel, J.A., 1995. The e€ect of lender identity on a borrowing ®rm's equity return. Journal of Finance 50, 699±718. Bizer, D.S., 1993. ``Regulatory discretion and the credit crunch''. Working Paper, US Securities and Exchange Commission, Washington, DC (April). Blackwell, D., Winters, D.B., 1997. Banking relationships and the e€ect of monitoring on loan pricing. Journal of Financial Research 20, 275±289. Boot, A.W.A., Thakor, A.V., 1994. Moral hazard and secured lending in an in®nitely repeated credit market game. International Economic Review 35, 899±920. Boot, A.W.A., Thakor, A.V., Udell, G., 1987. Competition, risk neutrality and loan commitments. Journal of Banking and Finance 11, 449±471. Boot, A.W.A., Thakor, A.V., Udell, G.F., 1991. Secured lending and default risk: Equilibrium analysis and policy implications and empirical results. The Economic Journal 101, 458±472. Booth, J.R., 1992. Contract costs, bank loans, and the cross-monitoring hypothesis. Journal of Financial Economics 31, 2±41.

666

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Booth, J.R., Chua, L., 1996. Loan collateral decisions and corporate borrowing costs. Working paper. Arizona State University, Tempe, AZ. Boyd, J., Prescott, E.C., 1986. Financial intermediary-coalitions. Journal of Economic Theory 38, 211±232. Bostic, R.W., Canner, G.B., 1998. New information on small business and small farm lending. Federal Reserve Bulletin 84. Brady, T.F., English, W.B., Nelson, W.R., 1998. Recent changes to the Federal ReservesÕs Survey of Terms of Business Lending. Federal Reserve Bulletin 84. Brav, A., Gompers, P.A., 1997. Myth or reality?: Long-run underperformance of initial public o€erings; Evidence from venture capital and nonventure-capital backed IPOs. Journal of Finance 52, 1791±1821. Brewer, E., Genay, H., 1994. Funding small businesses through the SBIC program. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives 18, 22±34. Brewer, E., Genay, H., Jackson, W.E., Worthington, P.R., 1997. The security issue decision: Evidence from small business investment companies. Working paper. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Calomiris, C., Himmelberg, C., Wachtel, P., 1995. Commercial paper, corporate ®nance and the business cycle: A microeconomic perspective. Carnegie±Rochester Series on Public Policy 42, 203±250. Carey, M., 1996. Financial covenants, private debt, and ®nancial intermediation. Working paper. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Washington, DC. Carey, M., Post, M., Sharpe, S.A., forthcoming. Does corporate lending by banks and ®nance companies di€er? Evidence on specialization in private debt contracting. Journal of Finance. Carey, M., Prowse, S., Rea, J., Udell, G.F., 1993. The economics of private placements: A new look, Financial Markets. Institutions and Instruments 2. Cavalluzzo, K., Cavalluzzo, L., forthcoming. Market structure and discrimination: The case of small business. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. Chan, Y.-S., Kanatas, G., 1985. Asymmetric valuation and the role of collateral in loan agreements. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 17, 85±95. Chan, Y.-S., Siegal, D., Thakor, A.V., 1990. Learning, corporate control and performance requirements in venture capital contracts. International Economic Review 31, 365±381. Cole, R.A., 1997. Availability of credit to small and minority-owned businesses: Evidence from the 1993 National Survey of Small Business Finances. Working paper. Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC. Cole, R.A., 1998. The importance of relationships to the availability of credit. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 959±977, this issue. Cook, L., 1997. Trade ®nance, bank ®nance, and capital market imperfections. Working paper. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. Cooper, I., Carleton, W., 1979. Dynamics of borrower-lender interaction: partitioning the ®nal payo€ in venture capital ®nance. Journal of Finance 34, 517±529. Chowdhry, B., Nanda, V., 1996. Stabilization, syndication and pricing of IPOs. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 25±42. Cornelli, F., Yosha, O., 1997. Stage ®nancing and the role of convertible debt. Institute of Financing and Accounting WP 253±1997. London Business School. Covitz, D.M., 1997. The role of public reputation in small ®rm ®nance. Working paper. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC. Craig, B.R., Santos, J.C.D., 1997. Banking consolidation, Impact on small business lending. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Cressy, R., Toivanen, O., 1997. Is there adverse selection in the credit market? Working paper. University of Warwick.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

667

Detragiache, E., Garella, P.G., Guiso, L., 1997. Multiple versus single banking relationships. Working paper. Banca DÕItalia, Rome. DeYoung, R., 1998. Comment on Goldberg and White. Journal of Banking and Finance 22. Diamond, D.W., 1984. Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 51, 393±414. Diamond, D.W., 1991. Monitoring and reputation: The choice between bank loans and directly placed debt. Journal of Political Economy 99, 688±721. Diamond, D.W., 1993. Seniority and the maturity of debt contracts. Journal of Financial Economics 33, 341±368. Duca, J.V., 1998. Comment on Cole. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 978±981, this issue. Dunkelberg, W., 1998. Credit, banks and small business in America. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1085±1088, this issue. Dunkelberg, W.C., Dennis, W.J., Jr., 1992. The small business ``credit crunch'', The NFIB Foundation, Washington, DC. Eisenbeis, R.A., 1998. Comment on Hancock and Wilcox. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1015±1017, this issue. Elliehausen, G.E., Wolken, J.D., 1993. The demand for trade credit: An investigation of motives for trade credit by small businesses. Sta€ study 165. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC. Elsas, R., Krahnen, J.P., 1997. Is relationship lending special? Evidence from credit-®le data in Germany. Working paper. Johann Wolfgang Goethe-University, Frankfurt. Fenn, G.W., Liang, N., 1998. New resources and new ideas: Private equity for small business. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1077±1084, this issue. Fenn, G.W., Liang, N., Prowse, S., 1997. The private equity market: An overview. Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments 6, 1±106. Ferris, J.S., 1981. A transactions theory of trade credit use. Quarterly Journal of Economics 96, 243±270. Flannery, M.J., 1998. Comment on Benveniste, Erdal, and Wilhelm Jr. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 768±772, this issue. Fluck, Z., Holtz-Eakin, D., Rosen, H.S., 1997. Where does the money come from? The Financing of Small Entrepreneurial Enterprises. Working paper. New York University. Freear, J., Sohl, J.E., Wetzel, W.E., Jr., 1994. The private investor market for venture capital. The Financier 1, 7±19. Fried, V.H., Hisrich, R.D., 1994. Towards a model of venture investment decision making. Financial Management 23, 28±37. Fried, J., Howitt, P., 1980. Credit rationing and implicit contract theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 12, 471±486. Garmaise, M., 1997. Informed investors and the ®nancing of entrepreneurial projects. Working paper. Stanford University. Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1994. Monetary policy, business cycles, and the behavior of small manufacturing ®rms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 309±340. Gi€ord, S., 1994. On the relationship between venture capital the entrepreneur. Unpublished manuscript. Boston University. Goldberg, L.G., White, L.J., 1998. De novo banks and lending to small businesses. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 851±867, this issue. Gompers, P.A., 1993. Incentives, screening and venture capital: A role for convertible debt. Unpublished manuscript. University of Chicago. Gompers, P.A., 1995. Optimal investment, monitoring, and the staging of venture capital. Journal of Finance 50, 1461±1489. Gompers, P.A., 1996. Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial Economics 42, 133±156.

668

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Gompers, P.A., 1998. Venture capital growing pains: should the market diet? Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1089±1104, this issue. Gompers, P.A., Lerner, J., 1994. An analysis of compensation in the US venture capital partnership. Working paper. University of Chicago and Harvard University. Gompers, P.A., Lerner, J., 1996. The use of covenants: an empirical analysis of venture partnership agreements. Journal of Law and Economics 39, 463±498. Gompers, P.A., Lerner, J., 1997. Money chasing deals? The impact of fund in¯ows on private equity valuations. Working paper. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. Gorman, M., Sahlman, W.A., 1989. What do venture capitalists do? Journal of Business Venturing 4, 213±248. Gorton, G., Kahn, J., 1997. The design of bank loan contracts, collateral, and renegotiation. Working paper. University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA. Greenbaum, S.I., Kanatas, G., Venezia, I., 1989. Equilibrium loan pricing under the bank±client relationship. Journal of Banking and Finance 13, 221±235. Gupta, A.K., Sapienza, J.J., 1992. Determinants of capital ®rms' preferences regarding the industry diversity and geographic scope of their investments. Journal of Business Venturing 7, 347±362. Hadlock, C., James, C.M., 1997. Bank lending and the menu of ®nancing options. Working paper. Univerisity of Florida Gainesville, FL. Hancock, D., Laing, A., Wilcox, J.A., 1995. Bank balance sheet shocks and aggregate shocks: Their dynamic e€ects on bank capital and lending. Journal of Banking and Finance 19, 661±677. Hancock, D., Wilcox, J.A., 1993. Has there been a `capital crunch' in banking? The e€ects on bank lending of real estate market conditions and bank capital shortfalls. Journal of Housing Economics 3, 31±50. Hancock, D., Wilcox, J.A., 1994a. Bank capital and the credit crunch: The roles of risk-weighted and unweighted capital regulations. AREUEA 22, 59±94. Hancock, D., Wilcox, J.A., 1994b. Bank capital, loan delinquencies, and real estate lending. Journal of Housing Economics 4, 121±146. Hancock, D., Wilcox, J.A., 1997. Bank capital, nonbank ®nance, and real estate activity. Journal of Housing Research 8, 75±105. Hancock, D., Wilcox, J.A., 1998. The `Credit crunch' and the availability of credit to small business. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 983±1014, this issue. Harho€, D., Korting, T., 1997. Lending relationships in Germany: Empirical results from survey data. Working paper. Haubrich, J., Wachtel, P., 1993. Capital requirements and shifts in commercial bank portfolios. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 29 (Quarter 3), 2±15. Hellman, T., 1993. Financial structure and control in venture capital. Working paper. Stanford University. Hempel, G., Coleman, A., Simonson, D., 1986. Bank Management, Wiley, New York. Hester, D., 1979. Customer relationships and terms of loans: Evidence from a pilot survey. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 11, 349±357. Ho, R., 1997. Credit-card use to ®nance small business is soaring, says survey of small ®rms. Wall Street Journal B2, Sept. 25. Hoshi, T., Kashyap, A.K., Sharfstein, D., 1990. The role of banks in reducing the costs of ®nancial distress in Japan. Journal of Financial Economics 27, 67±88. Houston, J.F., James, C.M., 1996. Bank information monopolies and the mix of private and public debt choices. Journal of Finance 51, 1863±1889. Houston, J.F., James, C.M., 1998. Do bank internal capital markets promote lending? Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 899±918, this issue. Houston, J.F., James, C.M., Marcus, D., 1997. Capital market frictions and the role of internal capital markets in banking. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

669

Houston, J.F., Venkataram, S., 1994. Information revelation, lock-in, and bank loan commitments. Journal of Financial Intermediation 3, 355±378. James, C., 1987. Some evidence on the uniqueness of bank loans. Journal of Financial Economics 19, 217±235. John, K., Lynch, A.W., Puri, M., 1997. Collateral and perquisite consumption: Theory and evidence. Working paper. New York University. Kashyap, A.K., 1998. Comment on Angelini, Di Salvo and Ferri. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 955±957, this issue. Kashyap, A.K., Stein, J.C., 1995. Monetary policy and bank lending. Carnegie±Rochester Series on Public Policy 42, 151±195. Kashyap, A.K, Stein, J.C., 1997. The role of banks in monetary policy: A survey with implications for the European Monetary Union. Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Sept./Oct., 3±18. Kanatas, G., 1987. Commercial paper, bank reserve requirements, and the informational role of loan commitments. Journal of Banking and Finance 11, 425±448. Karsai, J., Wright, M., Dudzinski, Z., Morovic, J., 1997. Emerging venture capital markets: Evidence from Hungary, Poland and Slovakia. Working paper. University of Nottingham. Keeton, W.R., 1995. Multi-oce bank lending to small businesses: some new evidence. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review 80 (2), 45±57. Keeton, W.R., 1996. Do bank mergers reduce lending to businesses and farmers? New evidence from tenth district states. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review 81 (3), 63±75. Keeton, W.R., 1997. The e€ects of mergers on farm and business lending at small banks: New evidence from tenth district states. Working paper. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. King, S.R., 1986. Monetary transmission: through bank loans or bank liabilities? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 8, 290±303. Klapper, L., 1998. Short-term collateralization: Theory and evidence. Working paper. New York University. Kolari, J., Zardkoohi, A., 1997a. The impact of structural change in the banking industry on small business lending. Report to the Small Business Administration. Kolari, J., Zardkoohi, A., 1997b. Bank acquisitions and small business lending. Working paper. Texas A&M University, College Station, TX. Koppenhaver, G.D., 1989. The e€ects of regulation on bank participation in the guarantee market. In: Kaufman, G. (Ed.), Research in Financial Services: Private and Public Policy. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, pp. 165±180. Kwan, S.H., Carleton, W.T., 1993. The structure and pricing of private placement corporate loans. Working paper. University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ. Leeth, J.D., Scott, J.A., 1989. The incidence of secured debt: Evidence from the small business community. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 24, 379±394. Lerner, J., 1994a. The syndication of venture capital investments. Financial Management 16±27. Lerner, J., 1994b. Venture capitalists and the decision to go public. Journal of Financial Economics 293±316. Lerner, J., 1995. Venture capitalists and the oversight of private ®rms. Journal of Finance 50, 301± 318. Lerner, J., 1998a. ``Angel'' ®nancing and public policy: An overview. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 773±783, this issue. Lerner, J., 1988b. Comment on Bergemann and Hege. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 736± 740, this issue. Levinson, A.R., Willard, K.L., 1997. Do ®rms get the ®nancing they want? Measuring credit constraints among small businesses in the US. Working paper, Milken Institute. Levonian, M., Soller, J., 1995. Small banks, small loans, small business. Working paper. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

670

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Lummer, S.L., McConnell, J.J., 1989. Further evidence on the bank lending process and the capital market response to bank loan agreements. Journal of Financial Economics 25, 99±122. Majewski, S.E., 1997. Using strategic alliance formation as a ®nancing mechanism in the biotechnology industry. Working paper. University of California, Berkeley, CA. Mann, R.J., 1998. Comment on Avery, Bostic and Samolyk. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1062±1066, this issue. Marx, L.M., 1993. Negotiation and renegotiation of venture capital contracts. Working paper. Northwestern University, Evanston, IL. Megginson, W.L., Weiss, K.A., 1991. Venture capitalist certi®cation in initial public o€erings. Journal of Finance 46, 903±979. Melnik, A., Plaut, S.E., 1986. Loan commitment contracts, terms of lending, and credit allocation. Journal of Finance 41, 425±435. Meyer, L.H., 1998. The present and future role of banks in small business ®nance. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1109±1116, this issue. Mian, S., Smith, C., 1992. Accounts receivable management policy: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance 47, 169±200. Mikkelson, W., Partch, M., 1986. Valuation e€ects of securities o€erings and the issuance process. Journal of Financial Economics 15, 31±60. Modigliani, F., Miller, M., 1958. The cost of capital, corporation ®nance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review 48, 261±297. Morgan, D.P., 1994. Bank credit commitments, credit rationing, and monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 26, 87±101. Morgan, D.P., 1995. Bank monitoring mitigates agency problems: New evidence using ®nancial commitments in bank loan commitments. Paine Webber working paper PW-95-12, Columbia University, New York. Morgan, D.P., 1998. The credit e€ects of monetary policy: Evidence using loan commitments. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30, 102±118. Morsman Jr., E., 1986. Commercial loan structuring. Journal of Commercial Bank Lending 68, 2± 20. Myers, S., 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 147±175. Myers, S., 1984. Presidential address: The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance 39, 575± 592. Myers, S.C., Majluf, N.C., 1984. Corporate ®nancing and investment decisions when ®rms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187±221. Nachman, D.C., Noe, T.H., 1994. Optimal design of securities under asymmetric information. Review of Financial Studies 7, 1±44. Nakamura, L.I., 1993. Commercial bank information: Implications for the structure of banking. In: Klausner M., White, L.J. (Eds.), Structural Change in Banking. Irwin (Richard D.), Homewood, IL pp. 131±160. Ongena, S., Smith, D., 1997. Empirical evidence on the duration of banking relationships. Working paper, Norwegian School of Management, Bekkestua. Orgler, Y., 1970. A credit scoring model for commercial loans. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 2, 435±445. Nilsen, J.H., 1994. Trade credit and the bank lending channel of monetary policy. Working paper, Princeton University. Norton, E., Tenenbaum, B.H., 1993. Specialization versus diversi®cation as a venture capital investment strategy. Journal of Business Venturing 8, 431±442. Padilla, A.J., Pagano, M., 1997. Endogenous communication among lenders and entreprenuerial incentives. Review of Financial Studies 10, 205±236.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

671

Pagano, M., 1998. Comment on Berlin and Mester and Houston and James. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 919±923, this issue. Peek, J., Rosengren, E.S., 1994. Bank real estate lending and the New England capital crunch. AREUEA 22, 33±58. Peek, J., Rosengren, E.S., 1995a. The capital crunch: Neither a borrower nor a lender be. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27, 625±638. Peek, J., Rosengren, E.S., 1995b. Bank regulation and the credit crunch. Journal of Banking and Finance 19, 679±692. Peek, J., Rosengren, E.S., 1996. Small business credit availability: How important is size of lender? In: Saunders, A., Walter, I. (Eds.), Financial System Design: The Case for Universal Banking. Irwin (Richard D.), Burr Ridge, IL, pp. 628±655. Peek, J., Rosengren, E.S., 1998. Bank consolidation and small business lending: It's not just bank size that matters. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 799±819, this issue. Petersen, M.A., Rajan, R.G., 1994. The bene®ts of ®rm-creditor relationships: Evidence from small business data. Journal of Finance 49, 3±37. Petersen, M.A., Rajan, R.G., 1995. The e€ect of credit market competition on lending relationships. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 407±443. Pratt, E.S., Morris, J.K., 1987. PrattÕs guide to ventrue capital sources. (Venture Economics, Inc., Wellesley). Prowse, S., 1998. Angel investors and the market for angel investments. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 785±792, this issue. Rajan, R.G., 1992. Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and armÕs-length debt. Journal of Finance 47, 1367±1399. Rajan, R.G., Winton, A., 1995. Covenants and collateral as incentives to monitor. Journal of Finance 50, 1113±1146. Ramakrishnan, S., Thakor, A.V., 1984. Information reliability and a theory of ®nancial intermediation. Review of Economic Studies 51, 415±432. Ravid, S.A., 1996. Debt maturity ± A survey. Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments 5 (3), 1±68. Rock, K., 1986. Why new issues are underpriced. Journal of Financial Economics 15, 187± 212. Rosen, H.S., 1998. The future of entrepreneurial ®nance. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1105±1107, this issue. Rosen, R.J., 1998. Comment on Peek and Rosengren and Strahan and Weston. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 846±849, this issue. Ruhnka, J.C., Young, J.E., 1991. Some hypotheses about risk in venture capital investing. Journal of Business Venturing 6, 115±133. Sahlman, W.A., 1988. Aspects of ®nancial contracting in venture capital investment. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 1, 23±36. Sahlman, W.A., 1990. The structure and governance of venture-capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics 473±521. Scott, J.A., Smith, T.C., 1986. The e€ect of the bankruptcy reform act of 1978 on small business loan pricing. Journal of Financial Economics 16, 119±140. Sharpe, S.A., 1990. Asymmetric information, bank lending, and implicit contracts: a stylized model of customer relationships. Journal of Finance 45, 1069±1087. Slovin, M.B., Sushka, M.E., 1983. A model of the commercial loan rate. Journal of Finance 38, 1583±1596. Slovin, M.B., Sushka, M.E., Polonochek, J.A., 1993. The value of bank durability: Borrowers as bank stakeholders. Journal of Finance 48, 247±266.

672

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

Smith, C., Warner, J., 1979. Bankruptcy, secured debt, and optimal capital structure: Comment. Journal of Finance 34, 247±251. Smith, J.K., 1987. Trade credit and information asymmetries. Journal of Finance 42, 863±872. So®anos, G., Wachtel, P., Melnik, A., 1990. Loan commitments and monetary policy. Journal of Banking and Finance 14, 677±689. Stiglitz, J., Weiss, A., 1981. Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review 71, 93±410. Stiglitz, J., Weiss, A., 1986. Credit rationing and collateral In: Edwards, J., Franks, J., Mayer, C., Schaefer, S., (Eds.), Recent Developments in Corporate Finance, Cambridge University Press, New York, pp. 101±135. Storey, D.J., 1997. Discouraged Borrowers: A Study of Micro and Small Businesses in Trinidad and Tobago. Working paper. University of Warwick. Strahan, P.E., Weston, J., 1996. Small business lending and bank consolidation: Is there cause for concern? Current issues in Economics and Finance 2, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1±6. Strahan, P.E., Weston, J., 1998. Small business lending and the changing structure of the banking industry. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 821±845, this issue. Stulz, R., Johnson, H., 1985. An analysis of secured debt. Journal of Financial Economics 14, 501± 522. Swary, I., Udell, G.F., 1988. Information production and the secured line of credit. Working paper. New York University. Thakor, A.V., 1998. Comment on Trester. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 700±701, this issue. Thakor, A.V., Udell, G.F., 1987. An economic rationale for the pricing structure of bank loan commitments. Journal of Banking and Finance 11, 271±289. Townsend, R., 1979. Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state veri®cation. Journal of Economic Theory 21, 265±293. Trester, J.J., 1998. Venture capital contracting under asymmetric information. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 675±699, this issue. Tyebjee, T.T., Bruno, A.V., 1984. A model of venture capitalist investment activity. Management Science 30, 1051±1066. US Small Business Administration, 1995. The annual report on small business and competition. Wagster, J., 1997. The Basle Accord of 1988 and the international credit crunch of 1989±1992. Working paper. Wayne State University, Detroit, MI. Walraven, N., 1997. Small business lending by banks involved in mergers. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 97±25, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Washington, DC. Welch, I., 1997. Why is bank debt senior? A theory of asymmetry and claim priority based on in¯uence costs. Review of Financial Studies 10, 1203±1236. Wetzel Jr. W.E., 1994. Venture capital. In: Bygrave, W.D. (Ed.), Portable MBA in Entrepreneurship. Wiley, New York, pp. 172±194. Whalen, G., 1995. Out-of-state holding company aliation and small business lending. Economic and Policy Analysis working paper 95±4. Oce of the Comptroller of the Currency, . White, L.J., 1995. An analytical framework. In: Zahid, S.N. (Ed.), Financial Sector Development in Asia. Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 3±35. Wilson, P.F., 1993. The pricing of loans in a bank±borrower relationship. Working paper. Indiana University, Bloomington, IN. Williamson, O., 1967. The economics of defense contracting: incentives and performance. In: McKean, R. (Ed.), Issues in Defense Economics. Columbia University Press, New York. Williamson, O., 1988. Corporate ®nance and corporate governance. Journal of Finance 43, 567± 591.

A. N. Berger, G. F. Udell / Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673

673

Wolken, J.D., 1998. ``New'' data sources for research on small business ®nance. Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1067±1076, this issue. Wright, M., Robbie, K., Ennew, C., 1997. Serial entrepreneurs. British Journal of Management 8, 251±268. Zardkoohi, A., Kolari, J., 1997. The e€ect of structural changes in the US banking industry on small business lending. Working paper. Texas A&M University, College Station, TX.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Forget What You Know About Good Study Habits by Benedict Carey

...Forget What You Know About Good Study Habits By BENEDICT CAREYSEPT. 6, 2010 retrived from :http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/07/health/views/07mind.html?scp=1&sq=Study%20Skills&st=cse Every September, millions of parents try a kind of psychological witchcraft, to transform their summer-glazed campers into fall students, their video-bugs into bookworms. Advice is cheap and all too familiar: Clear a quiet work space. Stick to a homework schedule. Set goals. Set boundaries. Do not bribe (except in emergencies). And check out the classroom. Does Junior’s learning style match the new teacher’s approach? Or the school’s philosophy? Maybe the child isn’t “a good fit” for the school. Such theories have developed in part because of sketchy education research that doesn’t offer clear guidance. Student traits and teaching styles surely interact; so do personalities and at-home rules. The trouble is, no one can predict how. Yet there are effective approaches to learning, at least for those who are motivated. In recent years, cognitive scientists have shown that a few simple techniques can reliably improve what matters most: how much a student learns from studying. The findings can help anyone, from a fourth grader doing long division to a retiree taking on a new language. But they directly contradict much of the common wisdom about good study habits, and they have not caught on. For instance, instead of sticking to one study location, simply alternating the room where a person...

Words: 1915 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Survey Form

...EducationSatisfaction Please rate your satisfaction with the quality of education at $!our educational facility!$. () Excellent () Good () Fair () Poor () Very poor () Don’t know Q. ValueSatisfaction Please rate your satisfaction with the value of education at $!our educational facility!$. () Excellent () Good () Fair () Poor () Very poor () Don’t know Q. PreparationSatisfaction Please rate your education at $!our educational facility!$ on preparing you for the workforce. () Excellent () Good () Fair () Poor () Very poor () Don’t know Q. QualityComparedToOthers Overall, how does quality of education at $!our educational facility!$ compare to that of similar facilities? Is our quality... () Much better () Somewhat better () About the same () Somewhat worse () Much worse () Don’t know Q. ValueComparedToOthers Overall, how does value of education at $!our educational facility!$ compare to that of similar facilities? Is our educational value... () Much better () Somewhat better () About the same () Somewhat worse () Much worse () Don’t know Q. LibraryFacilities Please rate the library facilities at $!our educational facility!$. () Excellent () Good () Fair () Poor () Very poor () Don’t know Q. ClassroomFacilities Please rate the classroom facilities at $!our educational facility!$. () Excellent () Good () Fair () Poor () Very poor () Don’t...

Words: 799 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

I Want a Husband

...educated. A few things all women can agree upon is we all want a man who is gives attention, committed, a good provider, great listener, educated, and handy around the house. That is just to name a few things us women want in a man. When I think of what the world says a good man is to me it is like they are looking for the perfect man. To me the perfect man cannot be found every man has there flaws. You just have to find the man with the flaws that you can deal with. Every good man is not college educated; but they know how to get up and go to work to make an honest living. To find a man that is educated is a good thing that means that they are on your level and can keep up with you. Education is important to every woman when it comes to finding a husband, because you know that their values are in the right place if going to school is important to them. What woman you know wants a man that is not committed to them. If a man cannot be committed you might as well say there is not a relationship. Woman want to know that they are the only one in a man's life. Women like to know the man is not out and about doing things that he should not do. When a man is turns into a husband commitment is important. No woman wants to find out that her man was not committed totally to her cause it hurts. A husband should not be out all times of the night doing God knows what when he knows he got a wife at home. I always say “the measure of your love is only the measure of your loyalty”. Being...

Words: 1037 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Definition Essay On What Makes A Good Woman

...What is a Good Man/Good Woman? Many define a good man as being someone who is honest, loyal and can take care of his woman. While all that is true, a good man is defined in deeper terms to me. A good man is loyal because without loyalty there is no trust and trust is the foundation for relationships/friendship. He has a good heart, has a great sense of humor and knows a good woman when he is In the presence of one. He is physically, spiritually, mentally, and financially stable and capable of taking care of his self. A good man is also God-Fearing and knows that he isn’t perfect, but working to always better his-self. A good man will pray with you and for you. He appreciates and respects women and don’t take advantage her kindness, he would build a woman up and not tear her down. He loves and respects family. A good man is someone who is willing to encourage his woman or the next person that is down, even while he might be going through something on his own. He also has a heart and when...

Words: 610 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Yfhfth

...Early in the book, Jim Barton gets a valuable piece of advice: "You've got to know what you don't know." Why is it so important for CIOs to recognize their own shortcomings? Nolan: Good general managers know what they don't know. They build skills to create an environment around them--including people they trust, outside sources, self-education--to ensure they don't make huge mistakes by not appreciating aspects of other functional areas. This is truly a unique management capability. Just as a CEO can come from a number of functional backgrounds, in IT, the general management skills are critically important, but so is the ability to understand what's unique to IT. Whoever is in that position needs to do [his or her] homework, and Jim Barton is exemplary in accomplishing that requirement. Austin: At one point in the book, Barton's predecessor, Bill Davies, lectures him on knowing everything before he goes to see the CEO. Davies has a different set of inclinations. He's not particularly interested in having a conversation with the CEO. There's that notion out there about what it takes to be a manager--that you're somebody who brings solutions, not questions. That's outmoded. It's part of knowing what you don't know. If you're a leader and you don't want others to know what you don't know, you're going to dig yourself a hole. Nolan: When I was running a consulting firm [Nolan Norton & Co.], we would provide the IT background and training for really smart MBAs and others...

Words: 1197 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Exam

...covered in great detail here. So please study accordingly. You might even have to look these up. • Know what opportunity costs are:Opportunity cost is the benefit that you might have gained from choosing the next-best alternative . • Know the definition of economics (Micro and Macro):Microeconomics is the study of individual choice, and how that choice is influenced by economic forces. Macroeconomics is the study of the economy as a whole. It considers the problems of inflation, unemployment, business cycles, and growth. • Know what the invisible hand is:The invisible hand is the price mechanism, the rise and fall of prices that guides our actions in a market . • Know about mergers:a statutory combination of two or more corporations by the transfer of the properties to one surviving; corporation any combination of two or more business enterprises into a single enterprise; an act or instance of merging. • Know about patents :A patent is legal protection of a technical innovation that gives the person holding it sole right to use that innovation —in other words, it gives the holder a monopoly to produce a good. • Know excise taxes and tariffs:An excise tax is a tax that is levied on a specific good . The luxury tax on expensive cars that the United States imposed in 1991 is an example. A tariff is an excise tax on an imported good . • Know what sunk costs are:A marginal cost is the additional cost to you over and above the cost s you have...

Words: 3092 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

25 Qualities and Characteristics of a Good

...25 Qualities and Characteristics of a Good Manager Posted on October 19, 2011 by admin Do you work well with others? Are you a leader? If you have these qualities, you might make a good manager. However, you need just more than these two qualities to be a good manager. There are a number of factors that play into whether or not you would make a good manager. The good news is that you don’t have to rely solely on natural, inborn traits. It is possible to develop the qualities good managers possess. You can complete a management program to learn some of the necessary characteristics, and you can also develop many desirable qualities on your own. As you prepare for a job in management, keep in mind these 25 qualities and characteristics of a good manager: Personal Characteristics There are items that can help you improve yourself, and enhance your interactions with others. Desirable personal characteristics make a manager someone that others can look up to, and feel comfortable following: Self-Motivation: An effective manager can’t motivate others if he or she can’t self-motivate. Self-motivation, the ability to get yourself going, and take charge of what’s next for you, is a vital personal characteristic for a manager. You have to keep yourself going — and motivate those who work with you. Integrity: People trust a good manager because they know he or she has personal integrity. Workers need to know that you will fight for them, do what you say, and follow the rules...

Words: 1187 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Humanities

...practice for his thesis proposal. this isn't a, um, a straight group meeting either this is uh, uh to be a practice event for uh, for Rob's defense. but what we're_ the protocol of course is that we interrupt Rob on any point on either, content or, uh, presentation-style suggestions, or anything because, um, this this committee definitely will interrupt him, those of you who have been through this know. S2: who's on his committee? S3: um, oh it isn't up there. um, so Matt of course and Jim Dimmitt, um Steve Baker and Dave Sutep, who's a professor in physics. S1: so S4: so you have two outside professors? S3: mhm S1: right. uh although calling Steve, an outsider is [S3: yeah that's true ] so so he's, so it's it's good to know your committee just strategically, for your, defense, um, and, uh, Steve, is gonna be already very familiar with this material and is gonna be pretty familiar with it [S3: mhm ] and uh, uh Dave Sutep is gonna be, uh, completely, comfortable here. S3: so for those of you who don't know Dave is the director of the program in complex systems, so, that that's how you know it makes sense to have a physics professor, on this,...

Words: 17550 - Pages: 71

Premium Essay

Philosophy Platos Cave

...people, in a sense, would be the chained people in the cave. This shows us that people in this cave are in a world of misunderstanding. There are people that live their lives in the dark, which means, they live in just that cave and not know that there is something beyond the cave. They lack the truth because they live in such comfortable lives and that the shadows is all they are known to see. The artifacts that they see that casts these shadows are out of their sight and do not see that these are the real 'truths.' They think that its everything in their lives and try to make sense of these shadows in the best form they can. Then, all of the people play the game of knowing what they know about these shadows. The ones that guess them right and know these shadows very well are the ones that know everything there is to know about these shadows they know about. It is an illusion of what they think is real. They even start to respect the one that knows the most about these shadows that are the 'truths' to them. These artifacts represent the form of Good that they are able to see, and think the shadows are that sort of the form of Good that they see and believe in. Then, Plato supposes that these shadows are not supposed to be named. The form of Good can be perhaps something that only your mind can grasp. This is the belief that these prisoners have and can be interpreted as that we are born with these beliefs and that it is implanted and we do not trust anything else beyond that...

Words: 919 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Spiritual Shepherdology

...2002, p.113). According to MacArthur (2002), “2 Timothy 2, for example, Paul uses seven different metaphors to describe the rigors of leadership. He pictures the minister as a teacher (v. 2), a soldier (v. 3), an athlete (v. 5), a farmer (v. 6), a workman (v. 15), a vessel (vv. 20-21), and a slave (v. 24). All those images evoke ideas of sacrifice, labor, service, and hardship. They speak eloquently of the complex and varied responsibilities of spiritual leadership. Not one of them makes leadership out to be glamorous” (“Wanted: a Few Good Shepherds (Must Know How to Wash Feet)”, para 1). Thus, for those contending with an internal struggle that questions: why me? And, how do I become? One might also ask, “How do I develop a deeper relationship with Christ to learn how to be led in order to lead? Or, where is the course in “shepherdology” (MacArthur, 2007)? If we take a look at the Book of John, Christ declares, “I am the good shepherd. The good shepherd lays down his life for the sheep” (John 10:11). According to the article “What is Christian leadership?” (2011), “when Jesus referred to us as ‘sheep’, He was not speaking in affectionate terms. In truth, sheep rank among the dumbest animals in creation”. Further elucidation informs that “a stray sheep, still within earshot of the herd, becomes disoriented, confused, frightened, and incapable of finding its way back to the flock. Unable to ward off hungry predators, the stray is perhaps the most helpless of all...

Words: 1190 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Plato V Aristotle

...and Aristotle have similar views on the achievement of the good life but also many important differences. While both Plato and Aristotle believe that the good life is one that attains happiness and that only a philosophical life will bring ultimate happiness which will therefore lead to the good life, the main difference between the two is the status or nature of the good and thus happiness. In this essay I shall explain both Plato’s and Aristotle’s views on the good life and how it should be attained. Plato’s good life is an idealist view, as he came up with the theory of ideas (ideas come first, then the world) The ‘good’ to Plato is somehow different to the actual object we see, as the good is outside the world (in the world of ideas) To ‘see’ the good of ideas we must use our rationality. He believed that the entities are corruptible as they change (they possess becoming) To live a good life one must know what the good life is as an idea. The ‘good’ ‘moral’ and ‘truth’ are all ideas and the ‘Good’ is the idea of ideas. The good is an absolute term; being self-evident, transcendental and consistent. Plato believed that the Good life equals truth which equals knowledge which equals morality. According to Plato, to lead a good life one must have internal self-control – one must know one’s self. Plato also believed that you must have a self-disciplined mind to have a good mind. One way Plato explained his idea of the good life was by using the ‘Leaky jar analogy’ He believed in...

Words: 1616 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

You Are What You Think

...You are what you think The truth about life is the truth about ourselves. If you know the enemy and know yourself, you need not fear the results of a hundred battles. In life, we go through many battles, not necessarily the real ones, but the battles with our own problems and others around us. Here we will see a little how to have strength, know ourselves better and then apply the knowledge to life. It is really important to know ourselves, to know how we will react to the challenges we face, and to have a good image of ourselves, since we are what we think. First, it is important that we have a good example to look up to and learn with. We will talk about heroes as they are a good example. A hero is a person who does something special, or out of the ordinary in order to help others. It could also be someone who is admired for a characteristic about them, be it physical or mental. They are individuals that normal everyday people can look up to. This being the case, a superhero is nothing more than someone who helps many people. We have always looked up to our heroes. Some of us become heroes and that is thanks to the strength we take from them. They are great examples for kids and grownups. The humanity should keep taking the good things heroes have to share with us, and apply them in our lives. Second, “Having control of yourself”, is very important. Then we know how to control ourselves, our fears, and our excitement. We shouldn’t be blocked from doing something...

Words: 850 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Christ: Model of Today's Youth

...Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION Background of the Study As we all know Christ Himself is the creator who made everything in heaven and earth. Jesus might have selected anyone in the world to follow Him. Yet again, He called common men: fishermen, businessmen, plain folks but the very first we notice about Jesus in that He was “one of us”. He loved children and they returned His affections. When some of Jesus’ followers tried to restrain the youngsters from clustering around Him, our Lord said “Let the little children come to me and do not hinder them, for the Kingdom of heaven belongs to such as these” (Matthew 19:14 NIV) Every one of us knows Jesus Christ but did you know that Christ is the model of Today’s Youth? Without any doubt He is the unique personality of all time a man who changed the course of history so dramatically that almost nothing is untouched by his influence. In almost every country in this world, the front page of every single newspaper acknowledges Him. That’s because every date is marked from His birth more than two thousand years ago. The life Jesus led, the miracles He performed the words He spoke, His death on the cross, His resurrection, His ascent into heaven these all point to the fact that He was not merely a man but more that a man. Yet the very power of His name was destined to overthrow the most widespread. So we know that Christ’s sacrifice all the things to save our life. That’s great had done God to all of us that serve as model in each of us...

Words: 2560 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Aquina and Augustine

...Aquinas and Augustine Essay Individuals have their personal view of human nature and the ability to know “the good” and do “the good.” Augustine and Aquinas have their philosophy on human nature and the ability to know “the good” and do “the good.” Human nature is how we perceive the life of a human being and the characteristics that” make up” an individual. The ability to do well and know good depends on the individual and the goodness of God. Thomas Aquinas was one of the most important world Christian theologians that lived in the middle ages. He created his philosophy of human nature. Within his perception of human nature, he considered the true perception of human nature. In Aquinas’s Summa Theologian, he expresses what it’s like to be human or the essential features. Based on his views he used characters of human being to define humans. Character exist in all human beings. According to Aquinas, to be a human being has physical and mental unit factors. This means that to be human there must be a body and soul. A human is not made up of more of each factor, it is equally united to form a human being based on Aquinas perception. Soul is considered to be the principle of life in a human being. All humans have a soul and a body but none are alike. Although some of them are similar. Before Aquinas made his perception of human nature, he took in consideration Aristotelian conception of souls. This means that Aquinas considers a soul to be “the first principle of life in...

Words: 858 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Hahah Lol

...to be able to instruct others on what to do; they need to be able to talk to each other throughout the job, the Army communicate through various ways such as hand signals, radio etc... If the Army did not communicate within the job they would not perform the job well; no one would know exactly what they were doing therefore the job would more than likely become very confusing. For example, if there was a conflict that begun and not one of the work colleagues communicated no one would know what job/position they are meant to be taking, therefore the job would become a shamble and would not be completed correctly, this is why communication is very important in the Army. In the Police communication is also vital as they need to know what is expected from them, if Police did not communicate then crimes that were committed would not be solved, therefore it would make the Police force looked very unsuccessful. For example, if Police received a phone call from a distressed person because their house had been burgled and police officers did not radio through, then the crime would not be solved, this is why communication is very important in the Police force. Communication has good and bad points, some good points are: Being able to communicate over a large distance, this is vital in the Army and Police as both forces work in a very large distance of one another. Body language, if there was an argument taking place and the police turned up all aggressive towards the people involved...

Words: 1562 - Pages: 7