Free Essay

Hotel Marketing Strategy

In:

Submitted By mummyp
Words 7677
Pages 31
Shadow vs. Market Prices in Explaining Land Allocation: Subsistence Maize Cultivation in Rural Mexico
Aslıhan Arslan
No. 1469 | December 2008

Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Düsternbrooker Weg 120, 24105 Kiel, Germany

Kiel Working Paper No. 1469 | December 2008

Title*
Author Aslihan Arslan

Abstract: Economic models of land allocation may lead to expectations for farmer response that “surprisingly" do not materialize, if market prices fail to reflect the value of farmers' product. “Shadow prices" rather than market prices explain resource allocation better for farmers who attach significant non-market values to their own crops. I extend the theoretical model in Arslan and Taylor (2008) to explain why the land allocation of such farmers may not respond to market signals even if transaction costs are not binding. I estimate the proportion of land subsistence maize farmers allocate to traditional versus modern maize varieties using nationally representative rural household data from Mexico – the center of diversity of maize. I conclude that shadow prices explain land allocation better than market prices and discuss the importance of non-market values in understanding both farmers' supply response and on-farm conservation of traditional crops with non-market values. Keywords: Land allocation, shadow prices, non-market values, traditional crops, on-farm conservation, Mexico JEL classification: O12, O13, Q12, Q39

Aslıhan Arslan
Kiel Institute for the World Economy 24100 Kiel, Germany Telephone: (431) 881 4499 E-mail: aslihan.arslan@ifw-kiel.de

* I thank to the Center on Rural Economies of the Americas and Pacific Rim (REAP) and Program for the Study of Economic Change and Sustainability in Rural Mexico (PRECESAM) for letting me use this unique data set. I also thank to J. Edward Taylor, Steve Boucher and Lovell S. Jarvis at the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California - Davis, and Jann Lay at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy for valuable comments. All mistakes are mine.
____________________________________ The responsibility for the contents of the working papers rests with the author, not the Institute. Since working papers are of a preliminary nature, it may be useful to contact the author of a particular working paper about results or caveats before referring to, or quoting, a paper. Any comments on working papers should be sent directly to the author. Coverphoto: uni_com on photocase.com

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN EXPLAINING LAND ALLOCATION: SUBSISTENCE MAIZE CULTIVATION IN RURAL MEXICO
ASLIHAN ARSLAN† Abstract. Economic models of land allocation may lead to expectations for farmer response that “surprisingly” do not materialize, if market prices fail to reflect the value of farmers’ product. “Shadow prices” rather than market prices explain resource allocation better for farmers who attach significant non-market values to their own crops. I extend the theoretical model in Arslan and Taylor (2008) to explain why the land allocation of such farmers may not respond to market signals even if transaction costs are not binding. I estimate the proportion of land subsistence maize farmers allocate to traditional versus modern maize varieties using nationally representative rural household data from Mexico – the center of diversity of maize. I conclude that shadow prices explain land allocation better than market prices and discuss the importance of non-market values in understanding both farmers’ supply response and on-farm conservation of traditional crops with non-market values.

“The central place that maize occupies in the culture of Mexico makes it less likely that traditional production methods will be drastically altered by new market forces.” — CEC (1999) The question of how farmers respond to price signals is central for understanding the effects of changing economic conditions on food supply and farmer welfare. The answer to this question becomes more important if farmers’ land allocation decisions have implications for the on-farm conservation of crop genetic resources. Most research in economic literature on farmers’ land
Key words and phrases. Land allocation, shadow prices, non-market values, traditional crops, on-farm conservation, Mexico. JEL codes: O12, O13, Q12, Q39. Updated Draft: December 2, 2008. † Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Germany. I thank to the Center on Rural Economies of the Americas and Pacific Rim (REAP) and Program for the Study of Economic Change and Sustainability in Rural Mexico (PRECESAM) for letting me use this unique data set. I also thank to J. Edward Taylor, Steve Boucher and Lovell S. Jarvis at the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California - Davis, and Jann Lay at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy for valuable comments. All mistakes are mine.
1

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

2

allocation decisions focuses on determinants such as portfolio selection, safety-first behaviour or learning and uses market prices to value production (Feder, 1980; Just and Zilberman, 1983; Bellon and Taylor, 1993; Brush et al., 1992; Smale et al., 1994). If, however, market prices fail to reflect the value of farmers’ product, economic models may lead to wrong expectations and “surprising” farmer response to price signals. The inelastic supply response of maize farmers in rural Mexico in spite of decreasing maize prices after NAFTA is an example (Nadal, 2000). “Shadow prices” rather than market prices explain farmers’ resource allocation better if farmers attach significant non-market values to their own crops (Smale et al., 2001; Dyer Leal and Yunez Naude, 2003). This was suggested (though not explicitly accounted for) by many researchers as one of the underlying reasons for the inelastic supply response of subsistence farmers in Mexico (de Janvry et al., 1995; Dyer Leal and Yunez Naude, 2003; Berthaud and Gepts, 2004). Mexico is the center of maize domestication and diversity with 59 different races (Dowswell et al., 1996; Turrent and Serratos-Hernandez, 2004). These races represent the largest genetic diversity of maize in the world and are valuable inputs to crop breeding research for maize – the worlds’ most widely used food grain (Yunez Naude and Taylor, 2006; Berthaud and Gepts, 2004). Therefore, understanding maize farmers’ supply response has implications for the on-farm conservation of this diversity. I explain why some farmers’ land allocation decisions may not respond to market signals even if transaction costs (TCs) are not binding by extending the theoretical agricultural household model in Arslan and Taylor (2008). I estimate land allocation decisions between different maize types (traditional and modern) and compare the performance of market prices and shadow prices in explaining this decision using nationally representative household data from rural Mexico. I conclude that shadow prices explain the land allocation decisions of subsistence maize farmers better and discuss the importance of non-market values in understanding both supply response and on-farm conservation. The methods and the policy implications of this paper are applicable to other settings where farmers attach significant non-market values to their crops.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

3

I provide some background on the non-market values modeled in Arslan and Taylor (2008) in the next section. I extend their theoretical model to emphasize the tradeoff between allocating land to the subsistence or the cash crop in section 2. In section 3, I estimate the proportion of maize area allocated to traditional maize varieties using different prices (shadow vs. market) and compare their performance in explaining this allocation. I conclude in section 4 and provide policy implications. 1. Non-market values and land allocation Farmers’ land allocation decisions have long been a subject of economics. Especially those related to high yielding crop varieties have been studied in detail by the technology adoption literature following the Green Revolution (Feder, 1980; Just and Zilberman, 1983; Bellon and Taylor, 1993; Brush et al., 1992; Smale et al., 1994). These studies use market prices to value farmers’ output as a determinant of land allocation decision, along with socio-economic and agroecological variables. Smale et al. (1994) show that farmers’ land allocation to high yielding and traditional crop varieties have multiple explanations such as input fixity, safety first behaviour, learning and portfolio selection. They also value farmers’ maize output at market prices in their empirical analysis of maize cultivation in Malawi. While using market prices may not be problematic for some cases, more attention should be paid to shadow prices where farmers attach non-market values to their crops. If some farmers make land allocation decisions based on shadow prices that are different from market prices, we may underestimate (overestimate) the land such farmers will allocate to the crop with high shadow prices (modern crops). While most research in the agricultural household literature uses market prices to value agricultural output, both de Janvry et al. (1991) and Taylor and Adelman (2003) analyze farmer decisions under missing product markets and represent the value of the “constrained” food crop with a shadow price. The constraint in their context is a transaction cost (TC) band that prevents farmers from participating in markets both as a buyer and a seller. One shortcoming of TC based

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

4

household models is that they cannot account for non-market benefits farmers may derive from producing their own crops, because they assume that market crops are perfect substitutes for the domestic crop in consumption.1 If the market crop and the domestic crop are perfect substitutes, farmers would not produce a crop at a higher opportunity cost than the market price (controlling for risk and transaction costs). However, if the domestic crop has non-market values that make the “same” crop purchased in the market an imperfect substitute, then some farmers will produce it at high cost even if there is a local market with small or no TCs.2 The non-market values of producing and consuming one’s own crop may be significant if the crop has cultural or religious connotations (Altieri, 2004). Traditional crops in their centers of domestication (such as maize in Mexico, potatoes in Peruvian highlands, rice in Philippines or wheat in Turkey) have long histories of evolution that are intertwined with the culture of the peoples who grow them.3 In some cases these crops are used in weddings, funerals and rituals in which purchased crop simply will not do, and are important in determining the farmer’s place in the community as a good farmer (Fussell, 1992). Akerlof and Kranton (2000) model “identity” (or the sense of self) as a way to incorporate non-pecuniary motivations into economic behaviour. If a farmer’s “identity” depends on the cultivation of such a crop, the market purchased crop cannot provide the same utility as the domestic crop. In this case, the market crop lacks the non-market values and is a poor substitute for the domestic crop in consumption. Consequently, market prices may not reflect the full value of these crops for the farmer. Although I do not model “identity” explicitly as do Akerlof and Kranton (2000), their study provides an intuitive way of thinking about

1 2

Throughout this paper I use “domestic crop” to refer to the crop produced by the household. Besides the prevalence of subsistence farming in spite of lively local markets in developing countries, the imperfect substitutability in consumption can also explain the rationale behind backyard gardening in developed countries. If the non-market value of growing and consuming one’s own crop was not important, we would not expect a rational person to grow tomatoes in her backyard for multiple times the cost of buying them in the market. 3 The term “traditional crop” refers to a landrace, which is a crop cultivar that evolved with and has been genetically improved by traditional agriculturalists, but not by modern breeding practices. All components of landraces are adopted to local climate conditions, cultural practices, diseases and pests (Hoisington et al., 1999; Jarvis et al., 2000).

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

5

why some subsistence farmers may produce crops at cash losses when they can buy them in the market. It is not rare to find that small-scale maize farmers in Mexico incur cash losses when their maize production is valued at the price of maize commercially available in local markets (and not necessarily the same variety) (Smale et al., 2001; Dyer Leal and Yunez Naude, 2003; Brush and Chauvet, 2004). This finding does not reflect the “irrationality” of farmers. On the contrary, it likely reflects the existence of non-market benefits that farmers get from cultivating and consuming their own maize (Dyer Leal et al., 2002). When one takes these non-market values into account, the cash losses may lose significance. It has been argued in the literature that farming in general is a way of life with non-pecuniary benefits (Vincent, 1976; Botterill, 2001). Even in developed countries farmers do not just switch in and out of farming based on monetary incentives because of the “psychic income” they get from farming. Moreover, when the cultural values mentioned above are attached to farming, we can expect that monetary incentives will not be enough to fully explain farmer behaviour. Dyer Leal (2006) emphasizes the importance of “shadow values” (rather than market prices) in understanding the responses of subsistence maize producers to economic changes in Mexico. Arslan and Taylor (2008) are the first ones to explicitly model and estimate shadow prices by conceptualizing the non-market values with an asymmetric market constraint for the subsistence crop. This constraint is such that the farmer can sell this crop but cannot buy an identical crop in the market. The resulting market is similar in spirit to the “partly absent market” in Strauss (1986), where the separability of the agricultural household model breaks down due commodity heterogeneity. Arslan and Taylor (2008) theoretically analyze how non-market values may lead to shadow prices that are higher than market prices and empirically show that estimated shadow prices of traditional maize are significantly higher than market prices for subsistence farmers. Their empirical analysis also shows that the same is not true for modern maize and the sellers of traditional

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

6

maize, supporting the non-market values as an underlying determinant of subsistence farmers’ decisions. The theoretical model in Arslan and Taylor (2008) models farmer’s resource allocation to the subsistence crop holding the land area constant. I extend their model in the next section by including the decision to allocate the land between a subsistence and a cash crop to discuss the effects of shadow prices on this decision.

2. Theoretical Model Suppose that a farmer produces a cash crop in addition to a subsistence crop using labor and a fixed amount of land (A). The markets for the cash crop and labor are perfect, hence the farmer can buy and sell these at market prices. The farmer divides his land between the subsistence crop and the cash crop. He also decides how to allocate labor across different crops and activities to maximize his utility. Let Qi denote the quantity produced of crop i, where i = s, c identifying the subsistence and the cash crop, respectively. Xm and Xl are, respectively, the amount of market goods and leisure h consumed. He also consumes part or all of his subsistence crop denoted by Xs , where the superscript

h indicates that the only source of consumption of Xs is home production. Under the assumption of a perfect labor market, the farmer can hire out his own labor and hire in as much labor as he likes at the market wage, w. Output is certain and the farmer’s decisions are: what proportion of land to cultivate with the subsistence crop (θ); how much labor to allocate to the production of s each crop and to off-farm work; how much of his subsistence crop to sell (Xs ); and how much to

consume of all goods. The farmer’s problem is given by:

h max U (Xs , Xm , Xl ; Z)

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

7

subject to full income, production, and nonnegativity constraints;

s pm Xm + wXl ≤ ps Xs + pc Qc − w(Ls + Lc ) + W

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Qs = g(Ls , Aθ) Qc = h(Lc , A(1 − θ)) h s Xs + Xs ≤ Qs s h Xs , Xs , Xm , Ls , Lc ≥ 0.

Where θ satisfies 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1; pj denotes the market prices of consumption goods and the cash crop identified with subscripts j = s, m, c; Li denotes the amount of labor used to produce the crop i, and W denotes exogenous transfers. U(.) is a continuously differentiable and strictly quasiconcave utility function and g(.) and h(.) are, respectively, quasi-convex production functions for the subsistence and cash crops. The Lagrangean of this problem is:

h s Xl ,Xm ,Xs ,Xs ,θ,Li ,λ,µn

max

h L = U (Xs , Xm , Xl ; Z)

s ¯ +λ[ps Xs + pc h(Lc , A(1 − θ)) + W + w(T − Ls − Lc − Xl ) − pm Xm ] s h s h +µ1 [g(Ls , Aθ) − Xs − Xs ] + µ2 Xs + µ3 Xs + µ4 Xm + µ5 θ + µ6 (1 − θ) + µ7 Ls + µ8 Lc

i = s, c n = 1, ..., 8 As shown in Arslan and Taylor (2008), the shadow price of the subsistence crop can be expressed as: ρ≡ µ1 w = , λ M P Ls (6)

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

8

and estimated using the marginal product of labor in subsistence crop production. The shadow price is higher than the market price for farmers constrained by the asymmetric market constraint (i.e., do not sell any subsistence crop) (Arslan and Taylor, 2008). The optimality condition for land allocation is different from the standard optimality conditions for these farmers. The first order condition for θ is: µ1 M P As , when θ > 0. λ

pc M P Ac =

(7)

The farmer sets the value of marginal product of land (VMPA) cultivated with the cash crop equal to the “shadow value of marginal product” of land cultivated with the subsistence crop. Figure 1 shows the land allocation conditions between the cash crop and the subsistence crop.4 Under perfect markets – in which the market prices reflect the true value of crops to farmers – the farmer sets the value of marginal product of land equal to each other for all crops, which corresponds to the point θ∗ in Figure 1. However, if the farmer’s decision price, i.e. shadow price (ρ), is different from the market price, the observed land allocation will be different from what would be observed under the perfect markets scenario. He will allocate more land to the subsistence crop (point θ0 in Figure 1), which satisfies the equation 7. These farmers will not respond to changes in the market price of subsistence crop as expected, unless the price change is big enough to offset the difference between the two value measures. Farmers who are trapped in a TC band as defined in de Janvry et al. (1991) will exhibit a similar sluggish response to price signals. However, in their model, farmers would be indifferent between producing the cash crop and the subsistence crop as long as the TC are not binding. The current model and the empirical application in the next section provide an explanation for why land allocation may not respond to price signals even in the absence of TCs by accounting for non-market values. In the next section, I econometrically analyze subsistence maize farmers’
4Total land cultivated is set to unity for simplification.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

9

VMPA s VMPA s = *MPA s

VMPA c

VMPA s = p s *MPA s

0

*

Figure 1. Optimal land allocation using market prices vs. shadow prices. θ∗ is the proportion of land that would be allocated to the subsistence crop using the market prices (ps and pc ) and θ0 is the proportion of land that is allocated to the subsistence crop using the shadow price (ρ) of the subsistence crop. The distance between the value of marginal product line and the shadow value of marginal product line is decreasing with θ to reflect the decreasing marginal utility from the consumption of subsistence crop valued at ρ.

land allocation decisions using both market and shadow prices to test the empirical validity of the hypothesis that shadow prices explain these decisions better than market prices.

3. Do shadow prices explain land allocation better? I use agricultural household data from the Mexican National Rural Household Survey (ENHRUM) that was collected in January-February 2003. The sample covers 1782 households in 16 villages of each of the 5 geographic regions in Mexico and was designed by the National Institute of Statistics, Geography and Informatics (INEGI) to be nationally representative of rural Mexico. The survey data include household demographics; plot level information on inputs and output of all crops; marketing and consumption of agricultural and livestock products; and maize seed varieties and their origins. They also include information about migration and work histories, off-farm income sources, credit market participation and household assets.5
See http://precesam.colmex.mx for detailed information about the ENHRUM data, and Arslan (2007) for more descriptive statistics.
5

¡

¡

VMPA c = p c *MPA c

0

A=1

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

10

Arslan and Taylor (2008) show that the shadow prices of traditional maize varieties (TVs) are significantly higher than market prices for subsistence maize farmers in the ENHRUM data. The same is not true for modern maize varieties (MV) and the sellers of traditional maize, therefore market prices can be used to reflect the value of maize for these farmers. Understanding the land allocation decisions of subsistence farmers of TVs, however, calls for an understanding of farmers’ shadow prices as well as other variables that affect land allocation. Based on these results the TVs and MVs correspond, respectively, to the subsistence and the cash crop modeled in the theoretical model above. The classification of maize into different groups is based on farmers’ response to the question of whether the seed they used was “criollo” (TV) or “h´ ıbrido” (MV) as in Arslan and Taylor (2008). Given their conclusion that shadow prices are significantly different from market prices only for subsistence farmers of TVs, I use the subsample of ENHRUM data that only includes these farmers. Out of 280 farmers in this subsample around 75% are in the South-Southeast and Central Regions. Table 1 shows the proportion of land allocated to TVs, the shadow prices estimated by Arslan and Taylor (2008) and market prices. The proportion of land farmers allocate to TVs is largest in the South-Southeast and the Central regions. These two regions and the Western Central Region are also the ones where the estimated shadow prices are the highest. Given these shadow prices, market prices can not explain subsistence farmers’ land allocation to TVs, because they underestimate the subjective value of TVs for these farmers. I test this hypothesis by econometrically estimating the proportion of land subsistence farmers allocate to TVs using both market prices and shadow prices.6 Two econometric issues arise when doing this analysis: First, shadow prices are not observed, but estimated with error. This introduces an additional source of variance to the standard errors of the area share regressions, which will bias the results if not taken into account (Dumont et al.,
6

The analysis of area share is done at the household level. Given the plot-level data, I use the area weighted averages for shadow prices, soil quality and slope variables for this analysis.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

11

Table 1. Regional averages for area share of TVs, shadow prices and market prices Regions South-Southeast Central Western Cent. Northwest Northeast TVshare Shadow p. Market p. 0.70 87.75 2.34 0.76 31.60 1.72 0.61 57.35 1.51 0.29 0.18 2.28 0.73 24.69 1.30

2005). I use bootstrapping to address this issue following Cameron and Trivedi (2005). Second, the dependent variable is bounded from below and above (i.e., between 0-100%), which makes it likely that an OLS specification will result in predicted values that lie outside of this interval. I use tobit and fractional logit specifications to address the problems caused by the bounded(fractional) nature of the dependent variable in the area share regressions (Tobin, 1958; Papke and Wooldridge, 1996). The theoretical model discussed here does not include risk. Technology adoption literature shows that risk is an important determinant of farmers’ crop choices (Feder, 1980; Feder et al., 1985; Just and Zilberman, 1983). The ENHRUM data do not include a variable that represents the production or price risks farmers may face, however, they include detailed migration histories for all household members for each year since 1980. Munshi (2003) uses rainfall as an instrument for the size of the migrant networks in the destination cities. He shows that there is a strong correlation between the past rainfall in the community and migration. The intuition is that communities where most farmers rely on rain-fed agriculture will have more migrants as the variation in rainfall increases. Big variations in rainfall translate into variations in income, and migrant remittances can provide a steady source of income and hedge against risk. I use the standard error of the migration prevalence in each community over the period of 1980-2002 as a proxy for risk reversing the argument in Munshi (2003).7 As in Munshi’s sample, rain-fed agriculture is dominant in the ENHRUM sample to support the use of the variation in historical migration prevalence as a proxy
7When analyzed at the community level, this variable (along with the availability of irrigation) is significantly

correlated with the percentage of plots cultivated with TVs.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

12

for risk.8 To control for risk attitudes, I use a wealth index that captures risk attitudes to the extent that farmers’ risk aversion decreases with wealth.9 Farmers’ yield expectations also play a role in land allocation (Smale et al., 1994). The ENHRUM questionnaire asked farmers the average yield they would expect to get from maize production on each plot in a normal year. I use the ratio of the village level average expected yield for TVs and MVs to control for the effect of yield expectations on land allocation. In addition to these variables, I use the following explanatory variables in the econometric analysis: the market price of maize in the village, household size to account for consumption requirements, total number of adults (ages 15-60) in the household representing household labor availability, age, education, a dummy variable indicating farmers that use saved seed, area weighted soil quality and slope, a dummy variable indicating farmers with access to irrigation, proportion of farmers that have off-farm income and credit in the same village (both excluding the farmer himself), total area owned by the farmer, and regional dummy variables.10 Table 2 demonstrates the sample means and standard deviations of these variables. Subsistence farmers, on average, allocate 71% of their maize area to TVs and belong to households with 5.11 members with 2.6 working age adults. Forty-six percent of subsistence farmers use their own seed saved from previous harvests and only 13% have access to irrigation. The average expected yield of TVs is 84% of that of MVs, and farmers own 7 hectares of land on average. The average farmer lives in a community where around 40% of households have off-farm income and some kind of credit. I use three different specifications to estimate the area share of TVs using tobit and fractional logit models (Table 3). The first specification (Columns 1 and 4) uses only market prices to test
8Rain-fed plots account for around 85% of the plots both in the whole sample and the subsample used here. 9The wealth index is created using Principal Components Analysis based on the characteristics of households’ primary

residence, access to utilities, and ownership of a television and refrigerator. 10I do not include indigenous identity as an explanatory variable. The effect of this variable is captured by the shadow prices given that indigenous identity is one of the most important determinants of shadow prices (Arslan and Taylor, 2008). Inclusion of this variable does not change the results presented here.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

13

Table 2. Summary of variables used in econometric analysis Variable TVshare mktprice rho hhsize adults age educ oldseedD wtsoilq Definition Mean Std. Dev. Proportion of land in TVs 0.71 0.37 Market price of maize 1.90 0.75 Shadow price of TVs 46.94 43.07 Household size 5.11 2.47 Number of adults (ages 15-60) 2.64 1.55 Farmer’s age 50.26 14.65 Farmer’s education (yrs.) 3.69 3.12 Dummy variable (=1 if farmer uses own seed) 0.46 0.50 Weighted soil quality (1: Bad, 2: Regular, 3: 2.29 0.58 Good) wtslope Weighted slope (1: Plain, 2: Sloped, 3: Very 1.59 0.60 steep) irrigD Irrigation dummy 0.13 0.33 Standard deviation of community migration 3.82 2.58 sdmig prevalence between 1980-2002 expyield Ratio of expected yields (TV/MV) 0.84 1.14 totown Total area owned (ha.) 7.04 30.75 wealth Wealth index 1.62 0.65 othersoffD Proportion of farmers with off-farm income in 0.45 0.23 the village otherscredit Proportion of farmers with credit in the vil- 0.39 0.31 lage N Number of observations 280

how well we can explain land allocation for subsistence farmers if we ignore shadow prices. The second specification (Columns 2 and 5) uses only shadow prices, and the third (Columns 3 and 6) uses both. The regression standard errors are clustered at the Rural Development District (DDR) level to correct for potential error correlation due to unobserved agro-ecological conditions that are common to all households within a DDR.11 The Akaike and Bayesian Information Criteria (AIC and BIC) are also reported to compare the fit of different specifications.All regressions with shadow prices as an explanatory variable are bootstrapped to account for the fact that this variable is estimated with error. A Box-Cox regression shows that a logarithmic transformation for the shadow prices improves the fit of the model. Market prices, on the other hand, provide better fit without any transformation.
11Rural Development Districts are districts defined by SAGARPA (Secretary of Agriculture, Ranching, Rural Devel-

opment, Fisheries, and Food Supply) as having similar agro-ecological conditions and production potential.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

14

Table 3. Tobit and GLM (Fractional Logit) models for area share of TVs for subsistence farmers (marginal effects reported)
Tobit mkt.pr. ln(rho) TVshare (1) (2) sellprice 0.16 ln(rho) 0.24∗∗∗ ∗ hhsize -0.04 -0.03 adults 0.00 -0.01 age -0.01∗ -0.01∗∗ ∗∗ educ -0.04 -0.03∗ ∗ oldseedD 0.13 0.15 wtsoilq 0.02 0.00 wtslope -0.13 -0.17∗∗ irrigD 0.11 0.31 sdmig -0.02 -0.01 expyield -0.06 -0.02 totown -0.00 -0.00 wealth -0.30∗∗∗ -0.23∗∗ othersoffD 0.27 0.42∗ otherscredit -0.42 -0.21 R1 -0.35 -0.60∗∗ R2 -0.07 -0.29 R3 -0.12 -0.51∗∗ R4 -0.76∗∗∗ -0.63 Intercept 2.57∗∗∗ 1.96∗∗∗ AIC 533.59 497.99 BIC 609.92 574.32
Significance levels : ∗ : 10%

both (3) 0.17∗ 0.25∗∗∗ -0.04 -0.00 -0.01∗∗∗ -0.04∗∗ 0.13 0.02 -0.20∗∗ 0.36 -0.00 -0.03 -0.00 -0.20∗ 0.35 -0.27 -0.73∗∗∗ -0.33 -0.53∗∗ -0.78 1.81∗∗∗ 495.56 575.52

GLM (Frac. Logit) mkt.pr. ln(rho) both (4) (5) (6) 0.06 0.08 0.11∗∗∗ 0.11∗∗∗ ∗ -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 -0.00 -0.01 -0.00 -0.00 -0.00∗ -0.00∗ -0.01∗∗ -0.01 -0.01∗∗ ∗∗ ∗∗ 0.07 0.08 0.07∗ -0.00 -0.02 -0.01 -0.05 -0.07∗ -0.09 0.05 0.12 0.14 -0.01 -0.00 -0.00 -0.03 -0.01 -0.01 -0.00 -0.00 -0.00 -0.13∗∗ -0.10∗ -0.09∗ 0.12 0.20 0.15 -0.16 -0.08 -0.11 -0.14 -0.27∗ -0.34∗∗ -0.03 -0.12 -0.15 -0.06 -0.28 -0.30∗∗ -0.39∗∗ -0.34 -0.48 3.80∗∗∗ 3.05∗∗∗ 2.78∗∗ 320.61 298.91 298.24 393.30 371.61 374.57

∗∗ : 5%

∗ ∗ ∗ : 1%

Therefore, I use the log of the shadow prices and non-transformed market prices in the regressions reported in Table 3. The coefficients reported in Table 3 are marginal effects for all models. Columns 1-3 in Table 3 show the results of area share regressions using a tobit model, and columns 4-6 show the results using the fractional logit model. When used alone, market prices are not significant in explaining the area share of TVs (columns 1 and 4). Shadow prices are highly significant in predicting the land area allocated to TVs (columns 2 and 5), even after controlling for market prices (columns 3 and 6). The specifications only with shadow prices provide the best fit according to the Information Criteria. The area allocated to TVs is found to be positively correlated with the availability of family labor and negatively correlated with family consumption requirements in other settings (Bellon and Taylor, 1993; Smale et al., 1994). I find that both the household size and the number of

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

15

adults have negative coefficients, though these are not significant. Older farmers allocate smaller proportions of their maize land to TVs contradicting the finding in Bellon and Taylor (1993), however this coefficient is very small. Farmers with more education allocate smaller shares of land to TVs as found by Bellon and Taylor (1993). Farmers who save their own seed are more likely to allocate larger shares of their maize area to TVs, reflecting the fact that they carefully manage their seed stocks to ensure the availability of preferred traits embedded in TVs. Farmers in rural Mexico are found to cultivate TVs on poorer soils and shift to MVs as soil quality improves (Bellon and Taylor, 1993). Controlling for other variables, I do not find a significant effect of soil quality in the ENHRUM sample. Surprisingly, slope has a significant and negative coefficient. The steeper the slope of farmers’ plots, the smaller the area share of the TVs. Larger-scale farmers tend to allocate bigger shares of their land to cash crops in general (Fafchamps, 1992). Controlling for farmers’ wealth, total area owned by the farmer does not have a significant effect in this sample. I find that more wealthy farmers cultivate a larger share of their maize land with TVs, confirming previous findings (Bellon and Taylor, 1993; Bellon et al., 2006). Variables that control for farmers’ yield expectations and risk exposure are not significantly correlated with land allocation. This is surprising because risk usually affects land allocation in the absence of perfect credit and insurance markets (Fafchamps, 1992; Smale et al., 1994). Traditional crop varieties are perceived to be less vulnerable to risk in many different settings (Smale et al., 2001; Edmeades et al., 2006; Bellon et al., 2006). To the extent that shadow prices reflect the value of the risk reducing characteristics of TVs, my findings may capture the effect of risk on land allocation indirectly through shadow prices. Two variables represent market access: the percentage of other farmers in the village that have off-farm income and the percentage of other farmers in the village that have some kind of credit. Neither of these variables is significantly correlated with area share of TVs. This is similar to the

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

16

result in Bellon and Taylor (1993) and indicates that there is not necessarily a tradeoff between market access and cultivation of TVs. If the TVs have significant non-market values, farmers allocate higher proportions of their land to these varieties regardless of the off-farm income and credit market activities in their villages. Perales et al. (2003) has a similar conclusion after observing that farmers in villages that are closer to Mexico city and have better market access did not produce less TVs. On the contrary, TV cultivation was higher in these villages, leading to the conclusion that farmers’ variety selection depends on multiple criteria and minor varieties are cultivated for traits other than expected income or yield. This finding is also confirmed by Bellon et al. (2006) in Southeastern Mexico. The traits that affect the cultivation of TVs – mainly non-market values – are captured by shadow prices in the current analysis and help explain resource allocation decisions of subsistence farmers in the national sample. 4. Conclusions This paper shows that by using shadow prices rather than market prices, we can better understand land allocation decisions of subsistence farmers. In the case of maize in Mexico, shadow prices capture various non-market values subsistence farmers attach to traditional maize varieties, hence farmers’ real incentives to cultivate them (Arslan and Taylor, 2008). Accounting for these incentives takes part of the “surprise” out of farmers’ non-response to decreasing market prices following NAFTA. The non-market values of maize are one of the oft-mentioned underlying reasons for why farmers did not respond to price signals as expected (de Janvry et al., 1995; Dyer Leal and Yunez Naude, 2003; Berthaud and Gepts, 2004). This paper tests the role of non-market values in explaining land allocation by explicitly using shadow prices and comparing their performance to market prices. Research results suggest that market prices fail to explain land allocation decisions for farmers who attach significant non-market values to their crops. In addition to providing an insight into sluggish supply response of subsistence farmers, these results also have implications for the on-farm conservation of traditional crops. Shadow prices of

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

17

traditional crops give farmers de facto incentives for conservation. Although preferences may change over time, shadow prices create a buffer for sudden losses of genetic diversity on farmers’ fields. The regions where subsistence farmers exhibit sluggish supply response can contribute to on-farm conservation of TVs and should be prioritized in targeting of such programs. These results can be applied to other regions and crops where non-market benefits of subsistence crops are significant. An interesting extension to this paper would be to analyze the effects of the current food price crisis on resource allocation and poverty in rural Mexico. The international prices of basic food commodities have increased significantly in the last couple of years. Dyer Leal (2006) finds that land allocation decisions of maize farmers in rural Mexico are more responsive to price increases than price decreases. Whether the current price increases will be high enough to offset the difference between shadow and market prices and how this will translate into supply response with implications for on-farm conservation is a question left for future research. References Akerlof, G. A. and Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and Identity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3):715–753. Altieri, Miguel, A. (2004). Socio-Cultural Aspects of Native Maize Diversity. In Maize and Biodiversity: The Effects of Transgenic Maize in Mexico. Secretariat of the Commission for Environmental Cooperation of North America. Arslan, A. (2007). Farmers’ Subjective Valuation of Subsistence Crops: The Case of Traditional Maize in Mexico. PhD thesis, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Davis. Available at http://ssrn.com/author=354360. Arslan, A. and Taylor, J. E. (2008). Farmer’s Subjective Valuation of Subsistence Crops: The Case of Traditional Maize in Mexico. Kiel Working Papers 1457, Kiel Institute for the World Economy. Bellon, M. R., Adato, M., Becerril, J., and Mindek, D. (2006). Poor farmers’ perceived benefits from different types of maize germplasm: The case of creolization in lowland tropical Mexico. World Development, 34(1):113–129. Bellon, M. R. and Taylor, J. E. (1993). Folk Soil Taxonomy and the Partial Adoption of New Seed Varieties. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 41(4):763–786.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

18

Berthaud, J. and Gepts, P. (2004). Assessment of Effects on Genetic Diversity. In Maize and Biodiversity: The Effects of Transgenic Maize in Mexico. Secretariat of the Commission for Environmental Cooperation of North America. Botterill, L. C. (2001). Rural Policy Assumptions and Policy Failure: The Case of the Re-

establishment Grant. Australian Journal of Public Administration, 60(4):9–16. Brush, Stephen, B. and Chauvet, M. (2004). Assessment of Social and Cultural Effects Associated with Transgenic Maize Poduction. In Maize and Biodiversity: The Effects of Transgenic Maize in Mexico. Secretariat of the Commission for Environmental Cooperation of North America. Brush, Stephen, B., Taylor, J. E., and Bellon, Mauricio, R. (1992). Technology Adoption and Biological Diversity in Andean Potato Agriculture. Journal of Development Economics, 39:365– 387. Cameron, A., C. and Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics: Methods and Applications, pages 357–382. Cambridge University Press, New York. CEC (1999). Assessing environmental effects of the north american free trade agreement (nafta): An analytic framework (phase ii). Technical report, Commission for Environmental Cooperation, Montreal: Communications Commission for Economic Cooperation Secretariat. de Janvry, A., Fafchamps, M., and Sadoulet, E. (1991). Peasant Household Behaviour with Missing Markets: Some Paradoxes Explained. The Economic Journal, 101:1400–1417. de Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E., and Gordillo de Anda, G. (1995). NAFTA and Mexico’s Maize Producers. World Development, 23:1349–1362. Dowswell, Christopher, R., Paliwall, R., L., and Cantrell, Ronald, P. (1996). Maize in the Third World. Westview Press. Dumont, M., Rayp, G., Thass, O., and Willeme, P. (2005). Correcting Standard Errors in Twostage Estimation Procedures with Generated Regressands. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67(3):421–433. Dyer Leal, G. (2006). Crop Valuation and Farmer Response to Change: Implications for In-situ Conservation of Maize in Mexico. In Smale, M., editor, Valuing Crop Biodiversity: On-Farm Genetic Resources and Economic Change, pages 17–32. CABI Publishing, Cambridge, MA. Dyer Leal, G., Taylor, J. E., and Boucher, S. (2002). Rethinking the Supply Response to Market Reforms in Agriculture: Household Heterogeneity in Village General Equilibrium Analysis from Mexico. UCD ARE Working Paper. Dyer Leal, G. and Yunez Naude, A. (2003). NAFTA and Conservation of Maize Diversity in Mexico. Paper for the Program for Commission for Environmental Cooperation.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

19

Edmeades, S., Smale, M., and Karamura, D. (2006). Demand for Cultivar Attributes and the Biodiversity of Bananas on Farms in Uganda. In Smale, M., editor, Valuing Crop Biodiversity: On-Farm Genetic Resources and Economic Change, pages 1–16. CABI Publishing, Cambridge, MA. Fafchamps, M. (1992). Cash Crop Production, Food Price Volatility, and Rural Market Integration in the Third World. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 74(1):90–99. Feder, G. (1980). Farm Size, Risk Aversion and the Adoption of New Technology Under Uncertainty. Oxford Economic Papers, 32(2):263–283. Feder, G., Just, R., and Zilberman, D. (1985). Adoption of Agricultural Innovations in Developing Countries: A Survey. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 33(2):255–298. Fussell, B. (1992). The language of ceremony. In The Story of Corn, pages 281–300. Alfred A. Knopf, Inc. Hoisington, D., Khairallah, M., Reeves, T., Ribaut, J., Skovmand, B., Taba, S., and Warburton, M. (1999). Plant Genetic Resources: What can they contribute toward increased crop productivity? Proceedings of National Academy of Science, 96:5937–5943. U.S.A., Colloquium Paper. Jarvis, D., Meyer, L., Klemick, H., Guarino, L., Smale, M., Brown, A., Sadiki, M., B., S., and Hodgkin, T. (2000). A Training Guide for In Situ Conservation On-farm. IPGRI, Rome, Italy. Just, R. and Zilberman, D. (1983). Stochastic Structure, Farm Size and Technology Adoption in Developing Agriculture. Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 35(2):307–328. Munshi, K. (2003). Labor Market. Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants in the U.S. available at

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(2):549–599.

http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/v118y2003i2p549-599.html. Nadal, A. (2000). The Environmental and Social Impacts of Economic Liberalization on Corn Production in Mexico. Report to Oxfam and World Wildlife Fund International. Papke, L. E. and Wooldridge, J. M. (1996). Econometric methods for fractional response variables with an application to 401(k) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(6):619 – 632. Perales, Hugo, R., Brush, S. B., and Qualset, C. (2003). Landraces of Maize in Central Mexico: An Altitudinal Transect. Economic Botany, 51(1):7–20. Smale, M., Bellon, M. R., and Aguirre Gomez, J. A. (2001). Maize Diversity, Variety Attributes, and Farmers’ Choices in Southeastern Guanajuato, Mexico. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 50:201–225.

SHADOW VS. MARKET PRICES IN LAND ALLOCATION

20

Smale, M., Just, R., and Leathers, H. (1994). Land Allocation in HYV Adoption Models: An Investigation of Alternative Explanations. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 76:535– 546. Strauss, J. (1986). The Theory and Comparative Statics of Agricultural Household Models: A General Approach (Appendix to Part 1). In Singh, I. J., Squire, L., and Strauss, J., editors, Agricultural Household Models: Extensions, Applications, and Policy, pages 71–91. The Johns Hopkins University Press, World Bank Research Publication, Baltimore. Taylor, J. E. and Adelman, I. (2003). Agricultural Household Models: Genesis, Evolution and Extensions. Review of Economics of the Household, 1(1):33–58. Tobin, J. (1958). Estimation of relationships for limited dependent variables. Econometrica, 26(1):24–36. Turrent, A. I. and Serratos-Hernandez, J. A. (2004). Context and Background on Wild and Cultivated Maize in Mexico. In Maize and Biodiversity: The Effects of Transgenic Maize in Mexico. Secretariat of the Commission for Environmental Cooperation of North America. Vincent, D. (1976). Economic Aspects of Farm Poverty. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 20:103–118. Yunez Naude, A. and Taylor, Edward, J. (2006). La biodiversidad genetica del maiz en Mexico. Programa de Estudios del Cambio Economico y la Sustentabilidad del Agro Mexicano, Folletin Informativo No. 3.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Startup Hotel Marketing Strategy

...Marketing strategy PPPP 1) Bit of space explaining scenario, trends, etc 2) Target Market 3) Small paragraph about mainstream vs niche 4) Hotel Marketing mix 5) Recommendations 6) Contingency plan Put X instead of info you don’t have, make situation clear for Rach to edit. Target atleast 3 pages and max 5, although getting info in crucial (excl. references) Page1: Scenario, Trends, customer profile, mainstream vs niche Page 2+3: Marketing Mix Page 4: Estimated Budgetary recommendations and Contingency Plan Marketing Plan Introduction For a startup company, an effective marketing plan is essential in order to ensure that it stands out from other, larger and more established brands. Established brands not only have tremendous brand recognition and a developed customer base but also the financial wherewithal to influence or manipulate the market conditions to make them more favorable to them. Nowhere is this more evident than in the hotel industy where large family firms have dominated the industry for decades. in addition the large initial investments, large overheads and fierce competiton often deter new entrants. However, the advent of the internet and consequently E-busness and IT business solutions has significantly leveled said playing field. With tourism increasing rapidly, especially from inxcreasingly affluent middle classes from the Newly Industrialized Economies (NICs), the hotel industry faces new challenges and opportunities, somthing...

Words: 840 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

W Hotel Marketing Strategy

...------------------------------------------------- 中国大陆首家W酒店入驻广州 W 酒店是喜达屋酒店与度假村国际集团旗下的全球现代奢华时尚生活品牌,它有着独立酒店的个性化时尚风格,也具备了主流商务酒店值得信赖、始终如一的卓越品质和体贴周到的服务。W酒店的官方定位是“Lifestyle”品牌,业内普遍将其归类为大型的Boutique hotel路线。激发灵感、创造潮流、大胆创新的W酒店在业界影响深远,为宾客重新诠释了以当代设计为主导,打造奢华现代生活方式的住宿体验。 喜达屋集团是世界酒店与休闲服务业中的领袖企业之一,在全球100个国家和地区拥有1,134家酒店,其自有与管理的酒店雇佣员工超过171,000名。作为世界知名的品牌,喜达屋是一个集酒店业主、经营与销售等功能于一身的综合集团,旗下拥有瑞吉、豪华精选、W酒店、威斯汀、艾美、喜来登、福朋酒店以及近期登场的雅乐轩,还有源宿。喜达屋拥有一项行业领先且备受赞誉的忠诚计划——SPG俱乐部,会员可获得积分并将其兑换成客房住宿、客房升级和航班,且无日期限制。喜达屋还拥有喜达屋度假住房所有权股份有限公司,旗下的别墅式度假酒店和喜达屋旗下品牌的贵宾特权缔造出世界级的度假体验。 ------------------------------------------------- 广州旅游业与接待服务业 广州地处广东中南部,是国家的经济、金融、贸易、航运和会展中心。自1975年以来,每年春秋两季都会在广州举办中国进出口商品交易会,即广交会,迄今已有五十余年历史,是中国目前历史最长、层次最高、规模最大、商品种类最全、到会客商最多、成交效果最好的综合性国际贸易盛会。日益成熟和发展的广交会给广州酒店业带来了无限商机,酒店在每年两届广交会期间的收入就占到了全年总营业额的近30%,例如花园酒店在广交会期间的营业额约占全年1/3,而海珠区一家四星级酒店约占1/4。除了广交会外,大大小小的各种展览多达800多个。游客抽样调查显示,在非会展高峰期,广州会展游客占所有游客的8%。 2010年后,随着亚运会、亚残运会在广州的成功举办,广州城市形象和城市地位得到了极大的提升,同时也带动了广州旅游业的快速发展,城市接待游客数量持续增长。2010年我市接待游客总人数1.27亿人次,比09年增长7.13%。据不完全统计,2010年广州亚运会期间,预计需安排运动员、随行官员、媒体人员等饭店住宿宾客约2万人, 2万名宾客,按照每人5000元的消费标准,就是1亿元的商机。 ------------------------------------------------- 广州W酒店 2013年03月,广州W酒店作为中国内地首家W酒店在繁华的珠江新城炫丽亮相。酒店拥有前卫的建筑外观配以充满时尚活力的室内设计,进门处19米高的LED水幕瀑布,让客人从走进酒店开始便可感受到W酒店的时尚无处不在。在此,不难找到适合每位客人尽情享受的地方,充满设计元素的酒吧与餐厅呈献各国料理,美酒佳肴,充分演绎了广州多元化的城市魅力,体验中国内地首家AWAY水疗中心,在城市中心享受舒适静谧,设计新颖的客房,全城首个客房内运动传感器与各种高科技配套设备为客人带来的全新入住感受。逾2000平方米的会议空间包括一个拥有户外场地的开放式会议室,配备先进高科技设施的宴会厅,设有便携式会议系统及同声传译系统,让客户的会议与活动打破传统,充满创意。无论什么时候,无论客人需要什么,广州W酒店的24小时随时/随需服务都尽可能让客人如愿以偿。  ...

Words: 471 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Marketing In The Hospitality Industry Essay

...concepts of marketing for a relevant services industry This research is about the concepts of marketing. I will therefore start by introducing the key terms marketing and marketing management. (Allen, 2007) stated that "Marketing pertains to the interactive process that requires developing, pricing, placing and promoting goods, ideas or services in order to facilitate exchanges between customers and sellers to satisfy the needs and wants of consumers". (Kotler et al, 1996) suggested that "Marketing is the process used to determine what products or services may be of interest to customers and the strategy to use in sales, communications and business development'. The American Association of marketing (Gronroos, 1989) define marketing management...

Words: 826 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Pop Culture

...“Pop” Culture “If there are 12 million people with our stuff, let’s have them be 12 million 18 year olds.” Says Dave Burwick vice president of marketing for Pepsi-Cola(Hey Kids Buy This pg. 98), and why not, child spending has risen from $122 billion to $172 billion in the past 5 years(familyed.org). In a time when advertising agencies are trying to get the most for their buck, and who isn’t, the smartest thing to do is target the ever growing population of children. In today’s society children’s average weekly allowance is just $5(Children and Money pg. 1), amounting over $260 a year, if you multiply this number by the number of children in the US today, it is outrageous, close to $5 billion. Seeing as children only save about half a billion dollars a year(Children and Money pg. 1), that’s a lot of money being spent on clothes, video games, toys, soda and candy. The funny thing is, marketers that had long ignored children, now systematically pursue them. Today, as well as clothing and toys, it’s also computers, airlines, hotels and banks(Hey Kids Buy This pg. 97). Pepsi, being one of the major soft drink companies in the United States today, has the right idea. By using a different pop icon, such as Brittany Spears, Christina Agulara Johansson 2 and Beyonce Knowles in each new advertisement, they are guaranteed to have the attention of the younger...

Words: 739 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Sample Resume

...Anderson 1234, West 67 Street, Carlisle, MA 01741, (123)-456 7890. OBJECTIVE Give more than 9 years of experience in Training, Marketing, and Consultancy as well as MBA degree and extra highly applicable experience to your business in a managerial ability. TECHNICAL SKILLS In Software Java, Visual Basic, MS Office, Oracle Other Skills Team Management, Channel Sales Management, Franchisee Training, Sales and Customer Care Training, Business Development, Sales and Product Development. EXPERIENCE Consultant (1998 - Present) Aptech Inst., New Delhi, India Responsibilities includes: * Training employees, franchisees, distributors & conducting training requirement analysis. Senior Manager - Marketing & Sales (1996 - 1998) Adobe, Noida, India Responsibilities includes: * Directing the sales team, business development and identification of latest business channels. Asst. Manager Sales (1995 - 1996) Hotel Le Meridien, New Delhi Responsibilities includes: * Examined market competition & its costs to stay ahead of the main players in the market place. * Supervised staff of 5 members who given support to sales as well as marketing. * Assisted in establishing baseline process and report formats to be used in subsequent years. EDUCATION B.A (Eco) from Aligarh University, 1991 MBA/PGDM (Marketing) from Aligarh University, 1995 Other Certification(s) Attended * PENTASOFT * ------------------------------------------------- ...

Words: 434 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Best Idea Ever

...Partyline.com (Marketing plan) Today I would like to introduce a new service to you called “Partyline.com”. Partyline.com will be website available to all that register a valid email and are 21 and older. What will be offered on this website is a new technology and idea I came up with. The main offering on this website will be a live feed of bar’s and the bar’s line to get in. In addition, you will be able to create your own group chats, and instant message other users. Other services provided will be bar specials, bar themes, local taxi number, late night food, and live updates by promoters. The overall marketing plan place, promotion, price, and product will make or break this service especially place. I would like to set this website up in three different area’s consisting of West Virginia, Morgan Town, George Town, and New Haven, Connecticut. Promotion will be another key factor, and I am hoping to sell Facebook or YouTube that this next big idea so they will help with advertising. Otherwise, it will be up to me and the investors I obtain. Price to use the website will be free and Product is the service were providing. The industry size and target market are two key components to making this business succeed. The reason I picked those three areas is because they are highly populated and they are highly populated with bars and college students. College students will be the primary target of this company. The more people this website can engage, the more...

Words: 1401 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Marketing

...Objectives * Integrate marketing strategies and channels – web, mobile, email, Facebook, POS system – for multiple promotions throughout the year * Utilize existing media to drive traffic to Facebook Fanpage and increase Fanbase through 5 “fan-gated” contests * Capture Fan profile data and build database of e-newsletter and mobile subscribers * Maintain “top of mind” with customers through monthly e-newsletter * Drive traffic to Mavi stores with SMS promo code and track redemption rates About Mavi Jeans™ philosophy is to build a brand around perfect fitting jeans that convey a Mediterranean feeling in terms of fashion and detail. Maviterranean is sexy, intimate, inspirational and breezy. Mavi, which means blue in Turkish, is known for high quality, great fitting and fashion-forward denim.  Mavi's Jeans development from a jeans brand to an international clothing brand has been achieved through a successful marketing strategy that evolved around the "Perfect Fit". The Perfect Fit is not just about fitting the body. It is also about fitting the culture. The connection of Mavi to its customer is more than just lifestyle. It is being a part of their life and the consumers being part of Mavi clothing.  Founded in Istanbul in 1991, Mavi Jeans designs a full collection of jeanswear for young women and men. Mavi sells 7,000,000 pairs of jeans a year and is now sold at over 4600 specialty stores, better department stores and specialty chains stores in 50 countries...

Words: 288 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Hunter Business Group

...The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania Marketing 777 MARKETING STRATEGY Professor: George S. Day, Suite 700 JMHH, Telephone: 215 898 8245 Email: dayg@wharton.upenn.edu Administrative Mary Donegan Assistant: Suite 700 JMHH Telephone: 215 898 2104 Email: mdonegan@wharton.upenn.edu Office Hours: By appointment Web Café Address: http://webcafe.wharton.upenn.edu/eRoom/mktg/777c Class Schedule: Monday and Wednesday 9:00am – 10:20am 10:30am – 12:00 noon Introduction This course views marketing as both a general management responsibility and an orientation of an organization. Relatively less attention will be given to the specific activities of the marketing department, sales group, or advertising function in implementing strategic decisions. We will take the viewpoint of the general manager and the senior marketing executive to address the issues of: ➢ Formulating segmentation and focus strategies ➢ Understanding, attracting and keeping valuable customers ➢ Positioning the business to achieve an advantage over competitors ➢ Identifying and exploiting growth opportunities ➢ Allocating resources across businesses and segments ➢ Managing the channels for gaining access to the served markets, and ➢ Aligning the organization to changing market requirements. The course will use a mix of cases, lecture/discussion, outside speakers, and group...

Words: 3247 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

Marketing

...MARKETING STRAGETIES: Successfully marketing an apartment complex requires you to find people who are seeking housing and place your advertisements in front of them at the right time and place. As you consider marketing strategies, list the places your target renters or buyers are likely to go when searching for properties. Be sure that your marketing materials are present in each place. Banners: One of the most effective ways to market an apartment complex is by hanging a simple banner off of the building facing the street; this is particularly useful if your complex is near a major highway. If you are located away from main streets, consider putting up a sign that says "Apartments for Rent" with an arrow indicating the direction. Many people search for apartments by driving around neighborhoods that they like, and a banner or a sign is an easy-to-see advertisement that does not require a large investment. Before using signs, check your area's regulations on their use to avoid incurring fines or other penalties. Craigslist: When searching for a place to live, many people head directly to the Craigslist postings for their city. To post your apartments, simply visit the Craigslist page for your area and click on the "post to classifieds" button. When advertising on the site, avoid placing logos and generic floor plans; often, readers will skip directly over these. Instead, write a basic listing for each available unit and include details about utilities. To increase...

Words: 1759 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Business

...1.1 Product 2 1.1.2 Price 3 1.1.3 Promotion 3 1.1.4 Place 3 1.2 Purpose of the report 4 1.3 Brief information of product 4 2. Application of 4P’s of Marketing and iPhone 5 5 2.1 Product 5 2.1.1 Design 5 2.1.2 Features 6 2.1.3 Brand Image 7 2.2 Price 7 2.3 Promotion 9 2.4 Place 12 3. Conclusion 13 References 14 Figure 1 10 Figure 2 11 1. INTRODUCTION Marketing is defined by Dr Philip Kotler as “The science and art of exploring, creating, and delivering value to satisfy the needs of a target market at a profit. Marketing identifies unfulfilled needs and desires.” (Goldblatt 2012, p 238) Therefore, marketing is the process that enlightens the potential customers about how a product or service is capable of delivering the value. This paper aims to analyze the 4P’s of marketing and how they are helpful in devising an effective marketing strategy capable of depicting the significance of the product in the customers’ life. For this purpose, iPhone 5 has been selected as the product for analysis. 1.1 Background of 4P’s principal 4P’s stands for four basic elements involved in the marketing of a commodity. These elements include Product, Price, Promotion and Place. This classification was first proposed by E. Jerome McCarthy in 1960s and ever since it has become an important part of the marketing strategies of organizations around the world (Middleton 2012). The four P’s represent four controllable factors which can be manipulated by the management of a company...

Words: 332 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Flower Production

...PROFITABILITY OF FLOWER PRODUCTION AND MARKETING This study examines the production and profitability of some selected flowers in comparison with their competing crops. Identified some problems of flower marketing which are, * Unavailability of sufficient flowers according to demand at right time * Lack of adequate and suitable transportation system. Measures to overcome these problems, * Establishment of mode storage facilities, * Improvement of cultivation practices of flower for the whole year * Arrangement of contract marketing. The flower traders face various problems: * Institutional credit should be made available to the intermediaries on easyterms and at a lower rate of interest. * Marketing loss should be reduced by improving storage, handling andprocessing facilities. Government should arrange training for flowers traderson post harvesting handling and storage of flowers on scientific basis. * Market facilities, such as tin shed, drainage, etc. should beimproved Based on the findings of the study, some recommendations for facilitating flower production and developing an improved marketing system in Bangladesh may be feasible if government and non- government agencies should take a concentrated effort - * to enhance flower production by train-up the flower-farmers, * to provide appropriate production assistance and storage facility, * to provide support farmers in marketing of the produced flowers, * to train...

Words: 874 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Marketing

...ASSIGNMENT QUESTION Marketing Plan: Your company has just developed a new sports drink that is in a container which will keep it cool for up to 6 hours.  Write a 3 page paper discussing how you would market the product.  Running Head: COOL CONTAINERS MARKETING PLAN 1 Cool-Containers Marketing Plan COOL-CONTAINERS MARKETING PLAN 2 Abstract Cool-Containers, a successful company has recently developed a new and improved sports drink. This sports drink comes in a newly designed container that keeps it cold for a maximum of 6 hours. As a way to introduce the product into the market, the company chose the flavor strawberry for this drink and the product name, “Strawberry Sports Juice Drink”. This flavor was picked because of a previous research study that was conducted on flavors most in demand by consumers. The creation of our new design for a container was due to the outcome of a research study in marketing that significantly showed the actual need to keep drinks cool. To keep the position of the drinks we sell and continue to be proactive to how our competitors react, the company will seek to apply a marketing strategy plan that is based on innovation, target audience, differentiation, strategic partnerships, outsourcing, advertising and pricing. This marketing strategy will provide the...

Words: 1564 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Business Summary

...[pic] I. Table of Contents I. Table of Contents……………………………………………………....02 II. Executive Summary…………………………………………………....03 III. Management Resume...........……………………………………….05 IV. Company Fact Sheet………………………………………………......06 V. Smack Energy Bar Ingredient list.............………………........07 VI. Smack Energy Bar Nutrition information...........................08 VII. Marketing Plan.......................…………………………….………..09 VIII. Retail Outlet Commitments………………………….............…….12 IX. Promissory Note ………………………………………………….……...14 Executive summary 3WAY Enterprises is a marketing and branding firm registered in the state of Maryland with operations in the state of Virginia and Washington DC. 3WAY Enterprises was founded by three friends who saw a window of opportunity, in bringing together two All-American phenomena: sports figures and energy bars. 3WAY Enterprises will produce, market, and distribute uniquely- branded products in partnership with sports and entertainment personalities. Each of our well-known partners will work with 3WAY Enterprises to develop a product that complements the personality’s style and appeals to their audience and fan base. Tailored originally as a performance food used in conjunction with athletic activity, the energy bar market has grown from its meek market entrance as an energy supplement...

Words: 2998 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

Consulting

...and Client Communication Strategies MGT/527 In today’s turbulent and uncertain economy, the functioning area of business that many clients will be looking at is marketing strategy. This function is most effective when you combine marketing strategy with a successful marketing campaign. A successful plan will allow the business to reach the maximum amount of consumers, which if done correctly will increase the customer base dramatically. Marketing strategies for developing an effective client and consultant relationship The most effective marketing plan will combine product strategy, price marketing strategy and communication marketing together. If executed efficiently, it will result in a customer base that will accommodate many levels of income and various economic situations all of which will find something pleasing about the same products. As a marketing consultant for say a restaurant I would present the client with a detailed strategy in preparation for establishing an effective client, consultant relationship. The presentation would begin with a production strategy which will enunciate the soundness of the business’s products, with emphasis on any specialty the restaurant has to offer. This strategy will illustrate how to get the restaurant in the minds of the consumer, which in turn will generate loyal customers who will keep returning again and again. Next I would present a price marketing strategy. This strategy is useful in keeping your...

Words: 628 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Service Encounter

...5. My Service Encounter Essay Reflections Through the course of my service encounter essay, I feel that I have learnt many new things about services marketing and have improved a variety of my personal skills as well as developing many new skills. This essay has really made me more aware of the amount of interactions that I have with services on a daily basis and the role that they play within my life. Also, the fact that services, on their own, account for more than 70% of our nations GDP really outlines the importance that there is on developing effective marketing strategies. 5.1 One of the most important factors that I can take from this essay is the importance of building relationships between the customer and the firm through marking techniques. One of the main reasons for failure within services firms is the fact that they concentrate far too much on initially attracting customers and not enough emphasis on customer retention. When I enter the business world I will ensure that I pay huge attention toward building relationships with my customers and this will enable me to sustain constant growth of sales through an extensive customer base. I have also been able to understand the importance of the service environment toward the perceptions of the customers. I think that in the future I will pay much more attention to the environment that I am being given a service within and the effect that various emotional cues and aspects have on me as a customer so that I can apply...

Words: 877 - Pages: 4