Free Essay

The End of Rational Economics

In:

Submitted By tsuya0218
Words 3426
Pages 14
THE NEW ECONOMICS in the
SPECIAL ISSUE

NEW WORLD

The End of

Rational Economics
Your company has been operating on the premise that people – customers, employees, managers – make logical decisions. It’s time to abandon that assumption. | by Dan Ariely
IN 2008, a massive earthquake reduced the financial world to rubble. Standing in the smoke and ash, Alan Greenspan, the former chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve once hailed as “the greatest banker who ever lived,” confessed to Congress that he was “shocked” that the markets did not operate according to his lifelong expectations. He had “made a mistake in presuming that the self-interest of organizations, specifically banks and others, was such that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders.”
Jacob Thomas

78 Harvard Business Review

|

July–August 2009

|

hbr.org

hbr.org

|

July–August 2009

|

Harvard Business Review 79

THE NEW ECONOMICS

in the

NEW WORLD.

We are now paying a terrible price for our unblinking faith in the power of the invisible hand. We’re painfully blinking awake to the falsity of standard economic theory – that human beings are capable of always making rational decisions and that markets and institutions, in the aggregate, are healthily self-regulating. If assumptions about the way things are supposed to work have failed us in the hyperrational world of IN BRIEF Wall Street, what damage have they done in other institutions » The global economic crisis has and organizations that are also shattered two articles of faith in standard economic theory: made up of fallible, less-thanthat human beings usually make logical people? And where do rational decisions and that the corporate managers, schooled market’s invisible hand serves as in rational assumptions but who a trustworthy corrective to imbalrun messy, often unpredictable ance. We need to replace these businesses, go from here? and other assumptions and adopt We are finally beginning to una new approach. derstand that irrationality is the real invisible hand that drives hu» Behavioral economics is founded on the premise that man decision making. It’s been a human beings are fundamenpainful lesson, but the silver lintally irrational and motivated by ing may be that companies now unconscious cognitive biases. see how important it is to safeThis emerging discipline offers a guard against bad assumptions. radically different view about the Armed with the knowledge that ways people and organizations human beings are motivated by really operate. cognitive biases of which they are largely unaware (a true invisible » By adopting an experimental approach, firms can discover the hand if there ever was one), busitruth underlying their assumpnesses can start to better defend tions about customers, employees, against foolishness and waste. operations, and policies. The emerging field of behavioral economics offers a radically different view of how people and organizations operate. In this article I will examine a small set of long-held business assumptions through a behavioral economics lens. In doing so I hope to show not only that companies can do a better job of making their products and services more effective, their customers happier, and their employees more productive but that they can also avoid catastrophic mistakes.

IDEA

Behavioral Economics 101
Drawing on aspects of both psychology and economics, the operating assumption of behavioral economics is that cognitive biases often prevent people from making rational decisions, despite their best efforts. (If humans were comic book characters, we’d be more closely related to Homer

Simpson than to Superman.) Behavioral economics eschews the broad tenets of standard economics, long taught as guiding principles in business schools, and examines the real decisions people make – how much to spend on a cup of coffee, whether or not to save for retirement, deciding whether to cheat and by how much, whether to make healthy choices in diet or sex, and so on. For example, in one study where people were offered a choice of a fancy Lindt truffle for 15 cents and a Hershey’s kiss for a penny, a large majority (73%) chose the truffle. But when we offered the same chocolates for one penny less each – the truffle for 14 cents and the kiss for nothing – only 31% of participants selected it. The word “free,” we discovered, is an immensely strong lure, one that can even turn us away from a better deal and toward the “free” one. For the past few decades, behavioral economics has been largely considered a fringe discipline – a somewhat estranged little cousin of standard economics. Though practitioners of traditional economics reluctantly admitted that people may behave irrationally from time to time, they have tended to stick to their theoretical guns. They have argued that experiments conducted by behavioral economists and psychologists, albeit interesting, do not undercut rational models because they are carried out under controlled conditions and without the most important regulator of rational behavior: the large, competitive environment of the market. Then, in October 2008, Greenspan made his confession. Belief in the ultimate rationality of humans, organizations, and markets crumbled, and the attendant dangers to business and public policy were fully exposed. Unlike the FDA, for example, which forces medical practitioners and pharmaceutical companies to test their assumptions before sending treatments into the marketplace, no entity requires business (and also the public sector) to get at the truth of things. Accordingly, it’s up to firms to begin investigating basic beliefs about customers, employees, operations, and policies. When organizations acknowledge and anticipate irrational behavior, they can learn to offset it and avoid damaging results. Let’s take a closer look at a few examples.

The Dark Side of Teamwork
A few years ago, my colleagues and I found that most individuals, operating on their own and given the opportunity, will cheat – but just a little bit, all the while indulging in rationalization that allows

80 Harvard Business Review

|

July–August 2009

|

hbr.org

them to live with themselves. (See “How Honest People Cheat,” HBR, February 2008.) We also found that the simple act of asking people to think of their ethical foundations – say, the Ten Commandments – or their own moral code before they had the opportunity to cheat eliminated the dishonesty. But what happens when people collaborate? Do autonomous teams make better, more ethical decisions? We decided to find out. In a series of three experiments, we gave participants 20 math problems to solve in five minutes and paid them 50 cents for each correct answer. In our first treatment (the control condition), individual participants were asked to write the number of problems they answered correctly on collection slips and give them to an experimenter, who checked the totals against the problem sheets. In a second treatment, participants shredded their answer sheets without verification and simply submitted their collection slips to the experimenter. Perhaps not surprisingly, we found these participants lied, saying that they’d correctly answered two more questions, on average, than those in the control treatment. Things got more interesting in the third treatment, where participants worked in pairs and shared the spoils. The results showed that when a person realizes that his or her fudging would benefit other team members by increasing the payout, dishonesty further increased by 25%. In another setup, we tried to discover whether monitoring and supervision would counteract team cheating. In fact, it did not. Though cheating decreased somewhat, it didn’t disappear. More disturbingly, as the members of our experimental group became better acquainted, the tendency to cheat for the sake of the team increased even more. Other experiments revealed that if one person is clearly seen to be cheating, team members – particularly those who feel connected to the cheater – are likely to depart from their own moral compasses and increase their cheating. It seems that cheating is infectious. These findings have serious implications for unsupervised collaborative work in organizations. Although work groups can have many social and

Most individuals, operating on their own and given the opportunity, will cheat – but just a little bit.

functional advantages, they may also be more vulnerable to unethical conduct.

The Revenge Motive: When Customers Are Unhappy
Now let’s look at customer behavior, an area that is particularly fraught with irrationality. It’s a rare company that consistently makes its customers happy, though many nobly try. And well they should; too many firms fail to understand the price of customer unhappiness. Indeed, given the right circumstances, most of us are more than happy to seek revenge.

hbr.org

|

July–August 2009

|

Harvard Business Review 81

THE NEW ECONOMICS

in the

NEW WORLD.

Revenge and cheating are only two of the irrational behaviors that underlie employees’ and customers’ decisions.

hbr.org the need to take revenge, they don’t Ayalet Gneezy of the University of Find more on Managing differentiate between the two. San Diego and I set out to discover if in the New World at This is bad news for employers. If even low levels of annoyance would landscape.hbr.org. someone who works for you upsets a cause people to seek retribution. If so, customer – even in ways unrelated to we could assume that vengeful behavthe job – you will very likely pay the price. Even the ior in the real world of dropped calls, flight cancelsmallest transgression on the part of an employee lations, and credit card penalties would be even can ignite the instinct for strong revenge against greater. the employer, regardless of who is at fault. Daniel, an actor who was our hired “agent,” gave What can company representatives or individuparticipants in a coffee shop several sheets of paper als do to soothe the instinct for revenge in business covered with letters and asked them to find matchor personal exchanges? Apologies work, at least ing pairs. Participants were promised $5 each for temporarily. In yet another version of our expericompleting the task. On doing so, each signed a ment, Daniel apologized for the phone call interreceipt and received a stack of $1 bills. Daniel “misruption. We were surprised to find that the show takenly” overpaid some of them by two, three, or of regret was a perfect remedy. The percentage of four dollars. people who returned the extra cash was the same In the “no annoyance” condition, Daniel exin the “apology condition” as in the “no annoyance” plained the task and set the participants to it. In condition. As it turns out the word “sorry” comthe “annoyance” condition, he pretended to answer pletely counteracted the annoyance. (Of course, his cell phone in the midst of giving instructions, the effectiveness of an apology is likely to diminish talked for 15 seconds with a friend about pizza, with the frequency of the annoyance.) hung up the phone, and then continued with the inRevenge and cheating are only two of the irrational behaviors that companies will find underlying their employees’ and customers’ decisions and actions. Recognizing that, what is the way forward?

Experimenting with Behavior
Behavioral economics experiments that get to the bottom of people’s decisions and actions are very different from the kinds of tests companies traditionally use to try out new product ideas and marketing concepts or to discover opportunities. The difference is not in the research methodology itself but in the process of selecting ideas to be tested. The standard business approach to experiments is similar to an engineering project. It makes strong assumptions about the laws that govern the behavior of the different actors; the only question is how to combine them in a way that makes sense for a particular application. (Companies that gather large amounts of transaction data are well ahead in this area. The casino giant Harrahs, for example, is famous for running experiments using customer data to develop a set of tailored services and offers.) A behavioral economics approach, in contrast, is more like a science project: We search simultaneously for the governing principles and how to implement them. Consider, for example:

structions without acknowledging or apologizing for taking the call. We wanted to discover whether the “annoyed” participants would exact revenge by keeping the extra money he gave them. A mere 14% of those subjected to Daniel’s rude treatment returned the additional money, compared with 45% of those in the other group. The fact that only 45% returned the extra cash was depressing enough, but it was striking that a 15second phone call vastly decreased the likelihood that the participants would return the cash. In another version of the experiment, we wanted to find out more about the impulse to punish. Would it make a difference whether Daniel claimed that he was working for someone else? Would participants punish the principal (the researchers behind the study) for the agent’s misbehavior? Our results suggested that if people feel

82 Harvard Business Review

|

July–August 2009

|

hbr.org

Pricing. I don’t know whether Apple’s executives were conducting a behavioral economics experiment when they introduced the iPhone at a price of $600 and then quickly discounted it to $400, but that move revealed something important about human behavior. By imprinting the price of $600 in people’s minds, Apple was able to make consumers think that $400 was a real bargain. In a standard approach to price setting, the people running Apple’s pricing group might have asked focus groups about various price points for the phone, and based on participants’ feedback, picked the price they thought would maximize profits ($400). But if Apple had set the initial price at $400, consumers would have had no basis for comparison, since they’d never seen such a product before. Adopting a behavioral economics perspective, Apple might have started by questioning the assumption that people would know how to value the pathbreaking product and so set up various pricing experiments. In this type of test, the goal is not simply to find out the optimal price but also to discover how people arrive at a decision to buy at that price. Companies also need to consider how the introductory price could influence the perception of value for a long time. Product launches. Behavioral economists might also look at the roles of habit and trust in consumer choice. Take a manufacturer who is planning to sell a triple-concentrated detergent, on the theory that environmentally conscious consumers would prefer to eliminate waste. Given shoppers’ almost automatic impulse to reach for the same detergent, should the manufacturer package the concentrate in the standard-size bottle and charge more for it? Or should the manufacturer try to break consumers’ force of habit and package the concentrate in a bottle one-third the size of the original? And what about trust? If consumers don’t trust the manufacturer to deliver a more concentrated product, given that the product smells and looks the same as before, will they be willing to pay for it? How can the manufacturer overcome this hurdle? Customers. A variety of companies now use a behavioral economics approach to more closely examine customer and employee behavior. For example, one automobile insurer discovered that most people, when filling out forms that ask how many miles they’ve driven in a year, claimed that they drove less than they actually had. Building on the discovery that people are less inclined to cheat after being reminded of their own ethical standards, the company moved the signature line

The Trust Game
A GROUP OF SWISS RESEARCHERS led by Ernst Fehr conducted an experiment now known as “the trust game with revenge” that reveals a lot about the motivation for vengeance. It goes something like this: You and an anonymous partner are each given $10, and you get to make the first move. You must decide whether to send your money over to your partner or keep it for yourself. If you keep it, each of you gets your $10 and the game is over. If you send it, the experimenters quadruple the amount to $40 – so now your partner has $50. The obvious question is: Why would you give away your $10 in the first place? The answer is that you hope you can trust your partner when he makes the next move. He can choose either to keep the $50 – leaving you with nothing – or send $25 back to you, so that you share equally in the spoils. If your partner is acting rationally and in his own best interest, he would never send you the $25. Knowing this, and acting equally rationally, you would never send him the money to start with. Ergo, you will do nothing and go home. The good news is that people are more trusting and reciprocating than standard economic theory would have us believe. In the experiment, many people gave away their $10, and many partners reciprocated by sending $25 back. But the Swiss game didn’t end there. If your partner chose to keep the $50, the experimenter would give you an opportunity in the next phase of the game to use some of your own money to punish him. For every dollar you spend, your greedy partner loses $2. So if you decided to spend $25, your partner would lose all his winnings. You might think that people who had just lost some money would be unwilling to lose even more just to “get their own back.” Seated comfortably right now, you might not be able to appreciate these feelings, but most of the people who were given the opportunity exacted severe revenge on their greedy partners. This finding was not the most interesting part of the study, however. While the participants were making their decisions, their brains were being scanned by positron emission tomography (PET). The experimenters saw activity in the striatum, the part of the brain associated with experiencing reward. In other words, the decision to punish the greedy partners appeared to be related to a feeling of pleasure. What’s more, those who had a high level of striatum activation punished their partners to a greater degree. This suggests that the desire for revenge, even when it costs us something and is fully irrational (you have no idea who this other person is, and you will never meet him again), has biological underpinnings.

hbr.org

|

July–August 2009

|

Harvard Business Review 83

THE NEW ECONOMICS

in the

NEW WORLD.

to the top of the form. Applicants who signed the form at the top reported driving an average of 2,700 more miles a year than those who signed at the end. In another example, the cable giant Comcast began addressing the customer-revenge problem by using Twitter to respond to problems proactively. The director of digital care, Frank Eliason, discovered that by searching for the word “Comcast” (or, sometimes, “Comcrap”), he could locate unhappy customers who were simply venting to themselves and to their friends, and respond to their problems before they became formal complaints. (Other companies, including JetBlue, General Motors, Kodak, Dell, and Whole Foods Market are now also tracking customers’ comments on Twitter.)

Building a Behavioral Economics Capability
Behavioral economics can be seen as depressing; after all, many of our experiments show human beings as incapable of making good decisions. Multiple findings demonstrate that we are emotional, myopic, and easily confused and distracted. Nevertheless, companies that make an investment in behavioral experimentation can radically improve decision making and lessen risk. Firms interested in experimenting with behavior should understand that the process is timeconsuming and delicate. All too often, companies

set out to learn something about their customers’ habits only to find that the way they devised their research was invalid and the conclusions incorrect. Smart organizations will develop a behavioral economics capability by hiring qualified experimenters and conducting small trials that build on each other. Once the understanding of irrationality is embedded in the fabric of the organization, a behavioral economics approach can be applied to virtually every area of the business, from governance and employee relations to marketing and customer service. It is probably most useful in the areas that we know the least about – such as the relationships between compensation and performance, risk and reward, loyalty and consumer habits, and pricing and purchasing behavior. As companies become more willing to question their assumptions, discover something about their stakeholders’ predilections, and share the results of their learning, they will no doubt become a good deal wiser.
Dan Ariely (dandan@duke.edu) is the James B. Duke Professor of Behavioral Economics at Duke University, in Durham, North Carolina, and the author of Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions (HarperCollins, 2008). Reprint R0907H To order, see page 158.

“I thought they were grooming me for something big but, apparently, they were just grooming me.”

84 Harvard Business Review

|

July–August 2009

|

hbr.org

Leo Cullum

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Bounded Rationality and Consumer Choice Theory

...coined by Hebert Simon surrounded the limitation of humans to process the amount of information available to make a logical, economic decision and the consumer would therefore, settle for something that satisfyingly sufficient, or ‘satisfice’(Simon 1955). Furthermore, the theory expanded over time to also include mans use of heuristics to simplify cognitive effort in the decision making process (Simon and Newell 1972) and it was argued that ‘logical and economic’ decisions were never reached by humans due to emotions and judgement controlling the decision making process and causing a range of biases and errors (Tversky and Kahneman 1986). The theory identified that humans would use these heuristics, such as rule of thumb or an estimation, to find something that is satisfactory to their needs rather than making the ideal economic decision. I agree with the notion that the world is ‘too complex for people to solve problems by employing strict logical rules and comprehensive thought processes’ (Simon 1955) and am also of the belief that humans will rely on heuristics to make the cognitive process more straightforward. Rational Consumer Choice Rational consumer choice theory has been around for many years and stems from the ideal that consumers act in a ‘rational’ fashion when making economic decisions. Not as complex as strict rationality, rational consumer choice considers some of the objections to the aforementioned theory and alters them accordingly to a more evidence...

Words: 2256 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Mmmmmmm

...Simon (1972) as a style of behaviour that is appropriate to the achievement of given goals, within the limits imposed by given conditions and constraints. The principal meaning of rationality is a condition of consistency among choices made from different sets of alternatives. In his view, rationality is defined by the existence of a preference relation which is complete and transitive (Arrow, 1996) .The essay is concerned with giving a brief overview of rationality and it will also discuss the different aspects on the concept of rationality identified in different management theories. Types of Rationality Rational behaviour is behaviour in accordance with reason, behaviour that in some sense serves the actor’s interests. Most writers seem to accept that rationality is an essential premise for any science of economics. In so far as economics is a science of human action, there seems to be little one can say of action, which is unreasonable. However, much work has gone into distinguishing alternative concepts of rationality, which it is suggested, could serve as this premise (Hargreaves Heap, 1989). In particular, following Max Weber, academics have distinguished between a range of rationalities including instrumental, value, substantive, procedural and expressive rationality. Lagueux (2010) has...

Words: 2049 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Robert Leckie, Book Review of Okinawa: the Last Battle of World War Ii

...battle of World War II and lasted a whopping eighty-three days. This invasion greatly outnumbered D-Day in weapons and in men. Former Marine and Pacific War veteran, Robert Leckie describes this battle in depth, not only telling you about the Americans, but showing the Japanese side as well. This book clearly informs the readers of the bloodshed and techniques that were used throughout the entire battle. From the American soldiers struggling to adapt to the new and unfamiliar terrain, to the Japanese kamikaze attacks, this book successfully sheds light on the individuals who fought in this epic battle. Many people over time have argued that this battle was unnecessary because the U.S. could’ve just dropped the atomic bombs on Japan to end the war. However, Leckie is able to show the strategic importance of this battle. Okinawa was the entrance to Japan. If America successfully invaded Okinawa, then the Americans would only be 375 miles from Kyusha, which is one of the home islands of Japan. This would provide a glimpse of a possible invasion. The island also had many airfields which the Americans wanted to use as a base for operations. Leckie defends this importance by showing that if the Japanese would’ve won the battle of the Pacific War, the Imperial Conference could not have been influenced to accept the Allied surrender offer, thus the war would have been prolonged. Although Leckie makes a...

Words: 991 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

A Theory of Justice

...advance in order to regulate the society more efficiently, a group of chosen people must determine the set of principles of justice. Given the importance of such task, there is no doubt that the group of chosen people ought to have the knowledge in relative fields and the capacity to think rationally in order to make the best decisions, if not for anyone else, at least for themselves. In this case, we refer to the participant with rationality a rational agent. If we assumed that every party were a rational agent, we are, in fact, acknowledging that rational agent would determine the principles of justice with the purpose of maximizing benefits for him and for people with similar background based on the given status quo and specific traits of society he is currently living in. Hence, if we only choose people who are rational, we would face two problems including constant argument, which would fail to deliver any reasonable agreement when rational agents have different background; and the possibility of exploitative agreement when every rational agent comes from similar background. Therefore, in order to nullify the potential negative effects, Rawls introduced the hypothetical scenario: The Original Position. All the parties selected have to determine the principles of justice in the Original Position behind the veil of ignorance....

Words: 1288 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Max Weber

...systematic. Western law, or rational jurisprudence, was Roman in origin. The subject of Weber's investigation is capitalism, and Weber defines this as more than just an impulse to acquisition, because even this impulse exists among physicians, noblemen, soldiers, gamblers, and so on (p. 17). For Weber, capitalism is more likely to "be identical with the restraint, or at least a rational tempering, of this irrational impulse. But capitalism is identical with the pursuit of profit, and forever renewed profit, by means of continuous, rational, capitalistic enterprise"(p.17). For Weber, rationality in the form of using balances, and the development of a monetary system, with measurement in money, is part of this. Rational, capitalistic acquisition is the systematic use of goods and services so that the balance at the end exceeds the capital originally invested. Weber also showed that a rational or systematic approach to economic activity means that that economic actors consider which of the several different possible courses of action they will take. Each course of action has consequences, either positive or negative, and decisions concerning action are not made on the basis of tradition, religion, or by invoking magical powers. Rather, in a rational capitalism, actors are problem solvers and calculate balances of gains and losses so that action yields the greatest expansion in money. He also argues that the west is the only place where this rational type of capitalism developed...

Words: 683 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Behavioral Finance

...an alternative to risk-based pricing models. While supported empirically, these characteristic-based models lack theoretical support. This paper seeks to reformulate an asset-pricing model (RAPM) to demonstrate why firm characteristics help to explain stock returns. Design/methodology/approach – The RAPM is grounded in an economic setting where two groups of agents hold different beliefs about firm fundamental values, and the more sophisticated ¨ group (rationals) adopts contrarian strategies against the naıve group (quasis). The model is derived in a static equilibrium within the consumption-investment framework with heterogeneous agents. Findings – The key theoretical result is a parsimonious equation of cross-sectional expected returns that not only are specified by the traditional risk-return relation, but also are determined by contrarian adjustments at both market-wide and firm-specific levels. When the model is taken to empirical specifications, it leads to consistent explanations for the behaviors of growth and value stocks, and for size and book-to-market effects. Research limitations/implications – The RAPM is a one-period model that assumes that “rationals” have perfect knowledge about “quasis” sentiment parameter and their relative market weights. In future research, it is planned to extend this static model to multiple periods to incorporate a learning process by which...

Words: 7898 - Pages: 32

Premium Essay

Fukushima Energy Debate

...The value disagreement exists between the economic benefit of nuclear power versus the nuclear risk as evidenced in the disaster and the interest disagreement occurs for economic security versus environmental and safety risks. Their analysis primarily focusses on the actors in the energy conflict, the role they play and the ingrained institutional barrier to reform in the Japanese nuclear energy sector (Fam et al.: 2014). Fam et al. concludes that the...

Words: 1180 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Mark Setterfield: a Model of Institutional Hysterisis

...Setterfield, M. (1993). A Model of Institutional Hysteresis. Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 27, No. 3 (Sep., 1993), pp. 755-774. Available online at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4226717 Institutions institutions are important for the functioning of capitalism as well as dynamics of capitalism affects the nature of institutions institutions in the context of capitalist economy can be defined as any correlated behaviour of agents that reoccurs under the same or similar conditions or simply as a well-established arrangements and structures that are part of the culture or society within which individual action in the economy takes place (e.g., competitive markets, the banking system, kids' allowances, customary tipping etc.) Institutional Economics Old and New we can observe significant disagreement that exists between different school of thought – this conflict of opinons may be illustrated by the contrast between two highly influential methodologies in institutional analysis, what may be referred to as “old" institutional economics (OIE) and the neoclassical “new" institutional economics (NIE) OIE OIE (such as Common, Veblen, Ayres) explains institutions by means of historical analysis using holistic methodology which emphasises that the economy cannot be understood as a set of separable parts and the system and its properties should be viewed as wholes, not as collections of parts for instance, in the OIE, the behavior of individual agents in the economy is seen as...

Words: 1316 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Economics Has Chosen Its Enemy and It Is Economics

...ts enemy Economics has met the enemy, and it is economics Ira basen From Saturday's Globe and Mail Published Saturday, Oct. 15, 2011 6:00AM EDT Last updated Tuesday, Oct. 18, 2011 8:41AM EDT After Thomas Sargent learned on Monday morning that he and colleague Christopher Sims had been awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for 2011, the 68-year-old New York University professor struck an aw-shucks tone with an interviewer from the official Nobel website: “We're just bookish types that look at numbers and try to figure out what's going on.” But no one who'd followed Prof. Sargent's long, distinguished career would have been fooled by his attempt at modesty. He'd won for his part in developing one of economists' main models of cause and effect: How can we expect people to respond to changes in prices, for example, or interest rates? According to the laureates' theories, they'll do whatever's most beneficial to them, and they'll do it every time. They don't need governments to instruct them; they figure it out for themselves. Economists call this the “rational expectations” model. And it's not just an abstraction: Bankers and policy-makers apply these formulae in the real world, so bad models lead to bad policy. Which is perhaps why, by the end of that interview on Monday, Prof. Sargent was adopting a more realistic tone: “We experiment with our models,” he explained, “before we wreck the world.” Rational-expectations theory and its corollary, the efficient-market hypothesis...

Words: 3105 - Pages: 13

Free Essay

Audi

...Emotive Brands Need Rational Benefits The most desired brands – the brands that regularly feature towards the top of car buyers’ shopping lists of preferred brands, tend to be the brands where the purchase decision is based more on emotive factors and less on rational factors. These ‘emotive brands’ are more likely to include the premium brands such as Audi, BMW, Jaguar and Mercedes-Benz. Many people end up not buying these brands because of budget – either they cannot afford the purchase price or cannot afford the running costs. The main factor that contributes to a car brand’s emotional status is its style and design which differentiates the brand from the rest. But the main weaknesses of most of the ‘emotive’ premium brands are their affordability, economy and practicality. To increase sales across a broader base of customers, especially for those premium brands that are developing smaller models with stronger retail appeal, the premium brands need to offer more rational purchase benefits in the form of lower running costs coupled with smaller and more practical models. Primary benefits sought by premium brand car buyers compared with buyers of all brands, June 2011 Base: 6,162 car buyers [pic] Source: Trend Tracker Alfa Romeo Brand Example Making a brand appeal on a more emotive basis with a strong or unique style and design does not automatically translate into stronger sales, as has occurred, for instance, with the Mini brand. A case in point is...

Words: 1294 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Rational Management

...Management process, linear and nonlinear management, ordinary and extraordinary management, rational management, chaos theory Management - from rational management to chaos theory Submitted to Dr. D. Coleman By JJ de Klerk In partial fulfillment of the requirement for the Doctorate in Business Administration Swiss Management University March 3, 2012 1 1. Introduction Developments over the last few decades have led to a new way of thinking in economic and management approaches. The scientific approach to management, which emphasizes the basic management functions of planning, organizing, leadership and control, now seems unable to explain the era of change that characterizes economies and organizations alike. This paper will focus on explaining the rational management model, focusing on ordinary management, and go on to discuss the new approaches such as chaos theory – also called complexity theory - and the need for extraordinary management and innovation. 2. Rational management Management and organization science literature have until recently focused on the objective control of agents and worked on the assumption that interactions can be described in linear terms (Webb, 2005). When difficult decisions have to be made, many managers and strategists rely on the economics view in which profit maximization is the guiding principle. Executives will us the rational model tools described above, and believe that precise solutions should be achieved through precise...

Words: 2151 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Game Theory in Economics

...elements beyond just benefits minus costs. Specifically, it includes the interaction between participants. In economics, the theory attempts to predict the participants’ optimal decisions. It has found a core place in economic decision-making and policy-making for its inherent ability to predict reactions in resource allocation, business negotiation, and other economic aspects. Game theory is mostly associated with decision-theory and other contexts such as cooperation and negotiations. From its definition, it is evident that the game theory is largely used in the study of the human decision making processes. In psychology, its equivalent is known as the theory of social situations. In economics, however, game theory tends to focus on sets of outcomes known as equilibrium that represent the most rational solutions to each situation. Game theory emanates from the complexity of human interactions; thus, in a situation where an individual is dealing with an inanimate object such as a tree, he or she does not expect the tree to fight back or respond (Leyton-Brown and Shoham 51). The environment can also be considered neutral to what is done to the tree, at least in direct and rational response. In human interactions, however, each action by an actor emanates from a situation and elicits a response. Each actor must thus recognize how his of her interaction with other rational actors works so as to foster cooperation and stem conflict. Every game is primarily dependent on a core...

Words: 2332 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Herberet Simon (Artintl).

...social sciences and mathematics His most important mentor at the University was Henry Schultz who was an econometrician and mathematical economist. After enrolling in a course on "Measuring Municipal Governments," Simon was invited to be a research assistant for Clarence Ridley, with whom he coauthored the book Measuring Municipal Activities in 1948. Eventually his studies led him to the field of organizational decision-making, which would become the subject of his doctoral dissertation in (1943). He joined the faculty of Illinois Institute of Technology, where he was a professor of political science from 1942 to 1949, He thus began a more in-depth study of economics in the area of institutionalism, Marschak brought Simon in to assist in the study he was currently undertaking with Sam Schurr of the “prospective economic effects of atomic energy”. In 1949, Simon became a professor of administrations and chairman of the Department of Industrial Management at Carnegie Tech (later to become Carnegie Mellon University). He continued to teach in various departments at Carnegie Mellon, including psychology and computer science, until his death in 2001. From 1950 to 1955, Simon discovered and proved the Hawkins-Simon theorem on the “conditions for the...

Words: 1172 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Occupy Wall Street Movement

...protests, with thousands arriving in New York City answering the call, soon spreading to well over 500 cities. I would like to discuss more of the details of the movement, the moral and economic implications, as well as the different ethics theories to see which theory best applies to the movement. The Arab Springs protest on February 11, 2011 was the most notable inspiration of the Occupy Wall Street movement. According to the website occupy together, the occupy movement is an international movement driven by individuals. They are organized in over 100 cities in the United States, and they aim to fight back against the system that has allowed the rich to get richer and the poor to get poorer. “All of us have many different backgrounds and political beliefs but feel that, since we can no longer trust our elected officials to represent anyone other than their wealthiest donors, we need real people to create real change from the bottom up… We no longer want the wealthiest to hold all the power, to write the rules governing an unbalanced and inequitable global economy, and thus foreclosing on our future.” The movement works to achieve their goals by resist, In the spirit and tradition of civil disobedience #occupy takes to the streets to protest corporate greed, abuse of power, and growing economic disparity; Restructure, #occupy empowers individuals to lead others into action by gathering in the commons as engaged citizens to demonstrate a culture based on community and mutual aid...

Words: 1630 - Pages: 7

Free Essay

Bubbles & Global Trends

...Bubbles & Global Trends An economic bubble is trade in high volumes at prices that are considerably at variance with intrinsic values. It could also be described as a trade in products or assets with inflated values. The cause of bubbles is unknown, however many explanations have been suggested, it has been recently shown that bubbles appear even randomly at time, without any rationality. I was very intrigued by the idea of bubbles, how a good can become the leading product in the market that everybody wants with such high demand then suddenly it falls because everybody starts selling. This type of activity in the market can easily cause a collapse in the economy especially if it is dominating the public (everybody is trading in it). The Tulip bubble also known as Tulip-mania was the most interesting to me, because of the price it got to. At the peak of tulip mania, in March 1637, some single tulip bulbs sold for more than 10 times the annual income of a skilled craftsman this equates to the price of mansions and fine art in modern times. I was never clear to me why this would happen, if you think about it now, if I saw that this was going on then I would grow my own tulips because it was worth so much money. Eventually that's what everyone did until the most expensive tulip in the world failed to sell. this caused everyone to lower their prices because their was over production which then lead to the collapse of the tulip industry and ultimately the collapse of the...

Words: 1434 - Pages: 6