Free Essay

Fairness Prevention

In:

Submitted By cindyyqs
Words 9679
Pages 39
Does Fairness Prevent Market Clearing? An Experimental Investigation Ernst Fehr; Georg Kirchsteiger; Arno Riedl The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, No. 2. (May, 1993), pp. 437-459.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28199305%29108%3A2%3C437%3ADFPMCA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E The Quarterly Journal of Economics is currently published by The MIT Press.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/journals/mitpress.html. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

The JSTOR Archive is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academic journals and scholarly literature from around the world. The Archive is supported by libraries, scholarly societies, publishers, and foundations. It is an initiative of JSTOR, a not-for-profit organization with a mission to help the scholarly community take advantage of advances in technology. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

http://www.jstor.org Tue Mar 18 16:15:54 2008

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING? AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION*

This paper reports the results of an experiment that was designed to test the impact of fairness on market prices. Prices were determined in a one-sided oral auction, with buyers as price-makers. Upon acceptance of an offer, sellers determined the quality of the good. Buyers offered prices that were substantially above the market-clearing level and expected sellers to respond with high quality levels. This expectation was, on average, confirmed by the behavior of sellers. These results provide, therefore, experimental support for the fair wage-effort theory of involuntary unemployment.

Fairness is an elusive term. Yet, in actual business practice the parties involved in a transaction seem to refer quite frequently to the notion of fairness. This observation had already been made by Marshall [19251, who wrote: ". . . the phrase is constantly used in the market place; it is frequent in the mouths both of employers and the employed; and almost every phrase in common use has a real meaning, though it may be difficult to get at." In a recent study Blinder and Choi [19901 asked nineteen managers whether they and their workers would perceive a wage reduction to take advantage of labor market slack as (a) completely fair, (b) acceptable, (c) unfair, or (d) very unfair. While three managers considered this as a n irrelevant question, all but one of the remaining sixteen said that such a wage cut is unfair or very unfair. Moreover, all but one believed that their workers would consider this wage cut as unfair or very unfair. In their study of community standards of fairness for the setting of prices and wages, Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler [I9861 infer rules of fairness for conduct in the market from their interviewees' answers to hypothetical questions. Their empirical findings confirm the existence of such rules. However, what people say is one thing, but what they actually do may be quite a different thing. The possible divergence between
*This paper is part of a research project (No. 8327) on equilibrium unemployment financed by the Austrian Science Foundation. We would like to thank W. Giith, J. D. Hey, L. F. Katz, G. Loomes, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. In addition, we thank Ulrike Freisleben and Sylvia Staudinger for their participation in the organization of the experiments. o 1993 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The Quarter1.y Journal of Economics, May 1993

438

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

revealed opinion and actual behavior raises the question of to what extent fairness considerations affect the behavior of people in markets. In several papers Akerlof [I9821 and Akerlof and Yellen [1988, 19901 have put forward the view that fairness-oriented behavior of workers may lead to involuntary unemployment. Based on psychological and sociological theories [Adams, 1963; Homans, 19611 and on experimental evidence,l they postulate a positive relationship between work effort and wages. Because of this relatiqnship, it may be profitable for employers to pay wages above the market-clearing level. There is by now overwhelming evidence that experimental markets converge toward the competitive equilibrium under rather weak conditions. This raises the question whether equity and fairness effects, which have been observed by psychologists in nonmarket experiments, will survive in a competitive market [Smith 19911. To our knowledge, the fair wage-effort hypothesis has not been tested in the context of a competitive experimental market. Our two-stage market experiment may be viewed as such a test of Akerlof and Yellen's efficiency wage approach. In the first stage of the experiment, a one-sided oral auction took place in which employers and workers could exchange one unit of labor time. In the second stage, workers chose their effort levels. Our experiment can, however, also be interpreted as a stylized version of certain kinds of goods or service markets. In many markets, the price of the good or the service is fixed before the good is produced or the service is rendered. If the quality of this good or service cannot be completely specified in the contract, or if the quality is not verifiable by third parties, a similar problem arises as in the labor market. The sellers in our experiment had no pecuniary incentive to raise the quality of the good above the exogenously given minimum. Therefore, if self-interested buyers expect sellers to be pure money maximizers, that is, if they expect sellers always to choose the minimum quality, they have no reason to pay prices above the market-clearing level. Contrary to this prediction, however, most buyers tried to induce sellers to choose higher quality levels by offering them high ("fair") prices for the good. Buyers offered prices that were on average substantially (by more than 100 percent) above the market-clearing level and expected sellers to reciprocate, that is, to respond with "fair" quality levels. This
1. See Mowday [19911 for a recent survey.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

439

expectation was on average confirmed by the behavior of sellers, although buyers' attempts have also been frustrated in specific cases. As the experiment was repeated, there was no tendency for prices to converge toward the market-clearing level.

The fair wage-effort hypothesis should be distinguished from the shirking version of the efficiency wage hypothesis [Bowles, 1985; Fehr, 1984,1986; Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984; Stoft 1982].2In the latter, wage variations are accompanied by different degrees of punishment for shirking. A wage increase raises the costs of shirking because if the worker is detected shirking and is fired, he will lose more money. The fair wage-effort hypothesis stipulates, however, that wage increases raise workers' effort levels even in the absence of any increase in the penalty for shirking. In Fehr, Kirchsteiger, and Riedl [I9921 we designed an experimental test of the shirking version of the efficiency wage hypothesis. To test experimentally for the validity of the fair wage-effort hypothesis, we set up the following two-stage game. The first stage was a one-sided oral auction with employers as bidders which lasted three minutes. At this stage employers made wage proposals, but they had no opportunity to choose the worker with whom they traded because every worker could accept every offer. Employers' wage offers had to be multiples of five.3 If a worker accepted an offered wage p, a binding contract was concluded, and stage 1 was finished for both the worker and the employer. If an employer's bid was not accepted, he was free to change his bid, but the new bid had to be higher than the previous highest bid (possibly from other employers) which had not yet been
2. In the following, we frame our presentation in labor market terms because, by referring to other labor market theories, the logic of our argument can be most easily illustrated. The labor market terms, however, can be easily replaced by equivalent goods market terms. Instead of, e.g., fair wage-effort hypothesis, we could also use the term fair price-quality hypothesis. In fact, our experiment was framed in goods market terms. Neither in the instructions, nor in our oral explanations, did we use terms like employer, worker, labor market, effort, etc. Instead, we spoke of buyers, sellers, goods, conversion rates, etc. The reason for this is that we conjecture that fairness considerations are more prevalent in labor markets than in goods markets because, in general, the social interaction between firms and their representatives, on the one hand, and workers, on the other hand, is more intensive than the interaction between buyers and sellers in goods markets. Therefore, agents in our experiment would have been more likely to exhibit fair behavior if they had identified with employers and workers. 3. Instead of introducing a commission fee, we imposed this restriction. It enabled workers to earn a small amount of money a t marginal trades.

440

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

accepted. After three minutes the market was closed, and those parties who did not succeed in trading earned zero profits for this period. At the second stage, workers had to choose their effort anonymously; i.e., their choice was revealed only to "their" employer. Moreover, their choice was completely unconstrained in the sense that there were no sanctions associated with it. In total, we organized four experimental sessions. In all sessions we deliberately created an excess supply of workers. In three, sessions we had nine workers and six employers, and in one session there were eight workers and five employer^.^ In each session there was at least one trial period with only the first stage in order to allow agents to become acquainted with the one-sided oral auction. Stage 1 and stage 2 together constituted one period, and to allow for learning effects, we had twelve periods in each session. A session lasted approximately two hours, and on average an experimental subject earned 296 Austrian Schillings (AS 296 %14,5 $25) per s e ~ s i o n . ~ Before the beginning of a session, each subject had to choose a card. If there was an S on the card, shelhe was a seller (worker), if a B, shelhe was a buyer (employer). Workers and employers were located in different rooms. During the experiment communication took place by means of a telephone. Four supervisors were engaged in each session: two in the employers' room and two in the workers' room. In each room one supervisor transmitted the price (acceptance) and effort messages over the telephone. While price messages were public knowledge, the information about effort choices was coded. It was known only to the two parties involved. In addition, employers and workers did not know the identity of their trading partners. These information restrictions have been chosen to exclude group pressure effects on effort choice and to reduce strategic spillovers between periods as much as possible. Moreover, we wanted to rule out the possibility of hidden side payments between parties after the experiment.

-

-

4. Unfortunately, two subjects did not show up a t this session, although they applied for participation. Session 1 took place in the morning, and session 2 in the afternoon of October 11, 1991; session 3 (morning) and session 4 (afternoon) took place one week later. 5. All experimental subjects were volunteers. They were all participating for the first time in such a n experiment, and each participant could only participate in one session. Most participants were students of computer science or electrical engineering from the University of Technology in Vienna. In addition, there were a few students of economics without any knowledge of experimental economics. They were recruited from the University of Vienna and not from the University of Technology.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?
TABLE I m(e)-SCHEDULE e m(e)

44 1

0.1 0

0.2 1

0.3 2

0.4 4

0.5 6

0.6 8

0.7 10

0.8 12

0.9 15

1 18

Although we think that in real labor processes group pressure effects and repeated game effects play an important role in enhapcing cooperation and developing fairness ties among workers (employers), as well as between workers and employers, we wanted to isolate pure one-period-fairness effects. In this respect, the conditions were most unfavorable for fairness effects to occur. It was, for example, impossible for employers (workers) to reward the past action of a specific worker (employer) because they did not know the identities of their trading partners. Let ej denote the effort of worker j , and let pj be the wage for one unit of labor time accepted by j . The monetary effort costs for workers were given by the increasing function, Schedule (1)was the same for each worker. emin> 0 represented the minimum effort level; it was associated with zero effort costs. The monetary costs of providing one unit of labor time were c, and the total monetary payoff of workerj, who received a wage ofpj and provided effort of ej, was given by The payoff of employer i whose worker has chosen an effort of ei was determined by vei may be interpreted as the revenue of the employer; one unit of effort produces v units of output which is sold for a price of one. The assumption that wage costs vary also with the level of e, has been made to rule out the possibility of losses for employers. In all four experimental sessions we fixed v = 126, c = 26; whereas the m(e)-schedule is given by Table I. Although it is difficult to give an exact definition of f a i r n e ~ s , ~ the term necessarily involves some comparison between the gains of transactors. Therefore, if an agent is motivated by fairness
6. In Fehr [19911an attempt is made in the context of ultimatum games.

442

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

considerations, his actions are based not only on his own gains, but also on the gains of other parties. Our experiment aimed at detecting whether agents exhibit intrinsic fairness preferences, and whether they base their actions on the expectation that others a d fairly. To allow for this possibility, we avoided any use of terms like fairness, equity, etc., but we informed all workers and employers about u , c , the cost of effort schedule m(e), and about the number of employers and workers. We also told them that everybody knows these parameter^.^

Early research [Smith 19641about the effects of one-sided oral auctions has shown that if only buyers are allowed to make price quotations, the mean price per trading period tends to converge to prices which are slightly above the competitive market-clearing price.8 The fact that mean prices are only slightly above the competitive price has been confirmed by a study of Plott and Smith [I9781 for the multiple-unit case: in both of the oral bid experiments they conducted, the market-clearing price was $0.60.9After seven periods the mean price in one experiment was $0.6065; in the other it was exactly 0.60. In a more recent extensive study [Walker and Williams, 19881 of one- and double-sided auctions, the authors could not find significant differences in mean prices across trading institutions. Mean prices in bid- offer- and double-auctions tended to converge to the competitive equilibrium price. It seems that the results provided by Walker and Williams are now accepted as showing that oral bid markets converge to the competitive equilibrium, and that the process of convergence is not different from
7. To make sure that the experimental subjects are capable of computing their own monetary payoffs, and the payoffs of their (unknown) trading partners, they had to solve a problem before the start of the trial period. The experiment did not start until all subjects had solved this problem correctly. 8. Smith reports the results of two experimental sessions. Session 1 had six periods; ten sellers and ten buyers each of whom could trade one unit per period. Session 2 lasted five periods with fourteen buyers and fourteen sellers as participants. In both sessions the competitive price was $2.10; the highest redemption value was $3.15, whereas the lowest marginal cost was given as $1.20. From charts 5 and 6 in Smith [I9641 we infer that in either session the average price in the last two periods was well below $2.25 and above $2.10. 9. For each trader the marginal costs of the first units sold were strictly smaller than $0.60 (marginal costs of the first unit was 0.26 (0.28) in experiment 1(2)). The redemption values of the first units bought were strictly above 0.60 (for the first unit 0.92 (0.94) in experiment 1 (2)). Thus, the competitive price involved positive profits for each trader.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

443

convergence in oral double auctions or oral offer markets [Plott 1989, p. 11261. Suppose for a moment that all agents in our two-stage experiment are money maximizers, and that this fact is common knowledge. Since, first, effort is costly for the workers and, second, they cannot be punished for providing a low effort, they have no pecuniary incentive to choose e > e ~ , .It follows that rational employers will, irrespective of their wage offers, expect e to be equal to emin. e = efinthe opportunity cost of accepting a job is given by ,At c = 26. Remember that wage offers have to be multiples of five and that there is an excess supply of workers. Under these conditions, the competitive equilibrium wage is equal to 30. Notice further, that, since everybody knows that workers will always choose emin, the addition of a second stage to the oral bid auction does not change the bidding and acceptance incentives relative to a familiar one-stage auction. In view of the above cited previous research, one should expect, therefore, wages to converge toward 30. In the following we call the outcome [p = 30, e = 0.11 the standard prediction, and the above reasoning that leads to this prediction the standard theory. At a wage of 30, workers earn T = 30 - c = 4 AS. We interpret T as a compensation for a real input, namely, the effort of active participation. Therefore, we say that workers who trade at p = 30 receive their reservation wage (in case that e = 0.1), while if some trading workers receive p > 30, nontraders are involuntarily rationed because they would strictly prefer to be a trader a t p > 30. More generally (i.e., for e 2 0.1), nontraders are involuntarily rationed, if some workers receivedpj > 30 + m(ej).

IV. THEFAIR WAGE-EFFORT HYPOTHESIS
In this section we introduce the hypotheses that will be used to test the validity of the fair wage-effort theory. In contrast to standard theory, the fair wage-effort hypothesis stipulates that the effort level e depends positively on the wage and that, therefore, employers may be willing to pay a wage greater than the marketclearing wage. This leads to HYPOTHESIS The effort level is increasing in the wage. 1. Of course, the situation in the experiment is very unfamiliar to the subjects. Therefore, one cannot expect them to act in a fully

444

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

rational way from the beginning. In particular, since employers do not know to what extent workers will exhibit reciprocal behavior, they may not offer the appropriate wage at the beginning. But when the game is repeated, the price of labor should converge to the market-clearing wage if fairness plays no role. However, if workers behave according to Hypothesis 1, wages above the market-clearing level should be observed. This leads to HYPOT~ESISAverage wages in the experiment are considerably 2. greater than the market-clearing wage c + T. Furthermore, if the game is repeated, the average wage does not converge to c + 7. Combining Hypotheses 1and 2 gives us HYPOTHESIS The average effort per period is above emin. f the 3. I game is repeated, it does not converge to emin. To investigate Hypothesis 2, we define an "average relative overpayment" variable r. This variable is just the difference between the average wage of a period p O and the market-clearing wage divided by the surplus:

If Hypothesis 2 is true, r should be considerably greater than zero and should exhibit no tendency to converge to zero. To test Hypothesis 1, we fit the regressionlo where p is white noise. If p is significantly greater than zero, , Hypothesis 1cannot be rejected. Regression (5) does not take into consideration that fairness notions may vary substantially across workers. There may be different types of workers with respect to their idea of what is a fair response to a certain wage. Of course, in "real world" situations, which are repeated many times, the individuals' conception of fairness may converge toward a common norm. But this could not happen in our experiment because workers did not know the effort levels chosen by other workers (see Section 11). Therefore, a worker had no opportunity to adjust his
10. All regressions reported in this paper are estimated with OLS. But we also run two-sided censored Tobit regressions, to take into account the nonlinearity of the wage-effort relation. Furthermore, we estimated log-linear regression models with OLS and two-sided censored Tobit. Because the main results of these different specifications do not differ from the OLS estimation of the linear model, only the results of the latter are reported in Section V.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

445

individual fairness notion to that of the others. A natural way to tackle this problem is to use dummy variables difor the workers to run the following regression:

To support Hypothesis 1, P again has to be significantly greater than zero. To test for the significance of behavioral differencesamong workers, we also computed the Wald-statistic for the dull hypothesis that all estimated y i are equal to the estimated a-coefficient of regression (5). It is also possible that effort varies systematically across periods. In order to test for this effect, we use period dummies pt which have value one if the relevant observation is made in period t and value zero otherwise. This leads toll

To test whether at least some 0, differ significantly from a , we again computed the Wald-statistic. Finally, we take a look at efficiency. If worker j sells his labor time to employer i, the sum of their payoffs is given by As already mentioned, the standard theory predicts that the wage equals (c + T) and that workers choose emin 0.1. Therefore, = the joint monetary g a b predicted by standard theory is rather small. It is given by Note that G, is substantially below the maximum total gain that could be achieved by an employer-worker pair. Therefore, if all agents are money maximizers, there is a conflict between individual and collective rationality. Fairness considerations may, however, help the subjects resolve this conflict at least partly.12 As a measure of the efficiency of the transaction between i and j,we use

11. In general, one should, of course, use a model with dummies for workers and periods. However, this would lead to an intolerable increase in the number of dummies relative to the number of observations. 12. For the effects of fairness on efficiency in an ultimatum game, see Giith, Ockenfels, and Wendel [19911.

446

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE I1 THEWAGE-EFFORT RELATION

Wage

Average observed effort level

Median observed effort level

Because m(emi,) = 0, the highest possible G is nearly 100 (when the wage is 125). Therefore, f;j. will be somewhere between one and seven.

On the whole, the experimental results are rather favorable for the fair wage-effort hypothesis.13 The lowest price observed was 30 (one time in the tenth period of the third session), the highest 110 (one time in the seventh period of the first session). The average price taken over all observations in the four sessions was 72, the average relative overpayment was 0,42. On average, employers gave workers 42 percent of the surplus, although there were more workers than jobs. On the other hand, workers chose all possible effort levels from 0.1 to 1. While emin was chosen in 44 of the 276 cases (16 percent of the cases), em, was chosen in six cases. The average effort chosen by the workers was 0.4 -four times as high as predicted by standard theory. To check Hypothesis 1, we have constructed Table 11. It shows the observed average and median effort levels of workers in response to a wage within a certain interval. As can be seen, average and median effort increased with the wage. The positive relationship between wages and effort is confirmed by Figure I which is based on the observations of all four experimental sessions. It shows that the graph of regression (5) is sloping upward. I n addition, it exhibits the average effort levels14
13. The data set is available from the authors upon request. 14. Due to the discreteness of our data, different workers chose the same effort level at a particular wage several times. As a consequence, many observations are not visible in a two-dimensional figure of effort-wage data points. Such a figure would, therefore, provide a misleading picture of the evidence. To avoid this problem, we plotted the average effort.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

447

0.6

average observed effort

effort
0.4

- estimated effort

I

30

50

70

90

110

130

wage

FIGURE I
The Wage-Effort Relation

that were associated with different wages. The pattern of these data points is also clearly sloping upward. In Table I11 we present the results of regression (5) with the whole data set as well as with the data of the individual sessions and with the last period observations of all sessions. Notice that the p-coefficient is positive and highly significant in all regressions. In Table IV the results of regression (6) are listed. Table IV confirms the results of Table I11 with respect to the sign and significance of P. Furthermore, the adjusted R 2s of Table IV are approximately two times the R2s of Table 111. As the
TABLE 111

RESULTS REGRESSION5 ) :e OF (
N
S1-4 SL1-4 S1 S2 S3 S4 276 23 72 72 72 60 cu = cu

+ pp +
P

)L

t(a) -3.1 -2.2 -2.8 -2.3 -1.6 -1.7

t(P) 9.6 3.5 6.2 5.4 4.9 3.9

R2 0.25 0.34 0.34 0.28 0.25 0.19

-0.18 -0.6 -0.27 -0.34 -0.14 -0.38

0.0078 0.0129 0.0076 0.0111 0.0066 0.0113

S#: Session#. SL1-4: Results of the estimation with the last period data of all sessions. N: number of observations. tO:t-value of the relevant coefficients. R2: Adjusted coefficientof determination.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE IV

RESULTS REGRESSION e OF (6):
N
S1-4 S1 S2 S3 S4 276 72 72 72 60

=

i=l

x

n

y,d,

+ pp + p.
W-st
275 56.9 81.3 45.1 25.0

n
35 9 9 9 8

P
0.0076 0.0067 0.0081 0.0072 0.0118

t(P) 10.8 5.9 5.4 6.3 4.4

R2
0.6 0.61 0.65 0.51 0.38

prob
0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.002

S#: Session#. N: Number of observations. n: Number of workers. t(P): 1-value of the @-coefficient. R2:Adjusted coefficient of determination. W-st: Wald-statistic for the hypothesis that ally, are equal to a (the relevant a can be found in Table 111). This statistic is CHI(n-1) distributed. prob: Significance level of W-st.

Wald-statistic shows, the hypothesis that all yi are equal to a has to be rejected for the whole data set as well as for the data of each individual session, even at a significance level of 1 percent. This allows us to conclude that the intercept of the effort-wage relation differed across workers. The results of regression (7) are shown in Table V. The P-coefficient is again always significantly positive, but the adjusted R2s are lower than those of regression (5) (compare Table V with Table 111). Furthermore, the hypothesis that all 0, are equal to a
TABLE V

RESULTS REGRESSION ) :e OF (7
N

=

IOtpt+ $p + p : l=l
R2

12

P

t(P)

W-st

prob

S#: Session#. N: Number of observations. t(P): 1-value of the @-coefficient. R2:Adjusted coefficient of determination. W-st: Wald-statistic for the hypothesis that all 13,are equal to a (the relevant a can be found in Table 11). This statistic is CHI(l1) distributed. prob: Significance level of W-st.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

449

cannot be rejected for any regression at a significance level of 60 percent (!). This indicates that workers do not behave significantly differently in different periods. Tables 111-V reveal evidence in favor of the hypothesis that the effort decision of the workers depends positively on the wage, and on their fairness notion but not on the timing. To examine Hypothesis 2, we take a look at the evolution of the average relative overpayment per period, r, over time. As can be seen from Figure 11, r is significantly greater than zero in all periods of all four experimental sessions. Furthermore, r does not converge toward zero, although each session took twelve periods. In session 1,r was decreasing in the eleventh and twelfth periods. But such a decrease can also be seen in the fourth and
Session 1 Session 2

period

period

Session 3

Session 4

period

period

-

average relative overpayment

-

average effort

FIGURE I1 Average Relative Overpayment and Average Effort per Period

450

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

sixth periods, each followed by an increase in r. In session 2, r was nearly constant over the last periods. In session 4, r was increasing in the last period. In session 3 a sharp decrease of r in the ninth and tenth periods was followed by a similar sharp increase of r in the last two periods. Moreover, except for session 1the value of r in the last period exceeds its value in the first five periods. On the whole, one cannot conclude from the data whether the price converges to a particular positive level, but it clearly does not converge to the market-clearing level. Therefore, Hypothesis 2 seems to be supported by the data. Figure I1 also shows the evolution of the average effort per period over time. Contrary to the standard prediction, average in effort exceeds emin all periods of all four sessions. Figure I1 also confirms once more that wages and effort are positively related. As with average wages, there seems to be no convergence toward the standard prediction. Therefore, Hypothesis 3 is supported by the data. The payment of high wages and the associated positive effort response of the workers increased the efficiency of almost all transactions considerably. The efficiency measure f-, was one in only one case, as predicted by standard theory. On average, f was 4.5, and in eight cases it was even higher than six. Thus, reciprocal behavior increased the overall gains by several hundred percent.

VI. INTERPRETATION OBJECTIONS AND
In our view, the above results indicate that fairness effectively prevented the wage from decreasing to the market-clearing level. Firms expected that paying high wages will, on average, induce workers to reciprocate, i.e., to choose high effort levels. When employers made their wage offers, they took into account that the effort levels of workers depended, contrary to the standard prediction, on the wage. This hypothesis is not only based on our experimental results, but is also supported by two additional observations. First, since we deliberately created an excess supply of workers, which was explained to all agents from the very beginning, employers knew that workers were willing to accept virtually any offer above the market-clearing wage. Moreover, during the experiment this fact was established over and over again. Competition among workers was extremely intense, and the most difficult task of the supervisor in the workers' room was to detect which subject

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

45 1

cried "accepted" first. Most wage bids were accepted after fractions of a second. Employers very quickly noticed that their bids were accepted immediately. This was also true for wages well below average wages, for example, in the tenth and eleventh periods of the third session. Furthermore, this conclusion was confirmed by the workers' answers to a questionnaire. When asked for the reason why they did not trade, they answered in only ten of the 144 cases that they had received no acceptable offers. In all other cases, the offers acceptable to them had already been accepted by other workirs. Almost always, the "unemployed" were simply not fast enough; faster workers snatched the jobs away from them. Obviously, the unemployed would have preferred to get a job; their unemployment was involuntary. Despite the existence of involuntary unemployment, most employers did not try to offer wages that were (relative to average wages) closer to the market-clearing level. This fact leads us directly to the second observation. At the end of an experimental session, a questionnaire was given to each employer. When asked about the motives for their price quotations, most employers answered that they tried to get a high effort from "their" worker by offering a relatively high price. Two employers answered that they tried to share equally with "their" workers. One answered that initially he tried to pay a low wage but that he later changed his behavior and paid a high wage to get a higher effort. Only one of 23 employers said that he tried to pay a low wage in all periods. Employers' hope that fairness considerations will induce workers to choose a high effort in response to high wages has been justified. This can also be seen from the answers the workers gave when asked at the end of the experiment for their motives in making their effort choice. Two workers answered that they tried to equalize their gains with the profits of their employers. Twentynine of the 35 workers answered that their effort decisions were dependent on the wages they received. The higher the wage, the greater was their effort. Only six workers answered that they simply tried to get a high gain when choosing their effort. But even the average effort chosen by these six workers was about 0.25, considerably greater than emin. Since each experimental session lasted twelve periods, one might suspect that our data are generated by a desire to gain a reputation. Workers might have reasoned that if they provide a high effort to employer j in the present period, they will receive a high wage offer from employer j in future periods. If it had been

452

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

possible to profit in this way from a reputation as a high-effort worker, our interpretation would indeed be questionable. Yet, our experimental procedures did not allow individual subjects to gain such a reputation. Remember that workers and employers were located in different rooms, and that employers (workers) could neither choose their trading partners, nor identify their trading partner. Moreover, the effort choice of workers was revealed neither to other workers, nor to the other employers. It was, therefore, impossible for experimental subjects to reward the past action of a specific trading partner. The claim that reputation formation is unlikely to be the driving force behind the deviation from the standard prediction can also be supported by the regularities of the data. Toward the end of the game, the pecuniary value of a good reputation becomes increasingly lower, and in the last period workers can gain nothing from a high effort. Thus, if reputation formation were the major motivational factor, we should have observed declining effort levels toward the end, and furthermore, in the twelfth period the average effort should have been close to emin.But this prediction is invalidated by the effort data exhibited in Figure 11, and by the results of our regression. Notice that the data of each session do not support the hypothesis that the wage-effort relation differs across periods (see Table V), and that a significant positive relation could also be established with the data of the twelfth period (see SL1-4 in Table 111). In our experiment employers could not suffer losses. A frequent (Darwinian) argument in discussions about fairness in the market place is that, in the long run, fair behavior will be driven out of the market. It might seem, therefore, that the impossibility to experience losses represents a severe restriction. Yet, if workers behave reciprocally, paying high (fair) wages is not profit reducing but profit increasing. In the previous section we mentioned that subjects were able to increase considerably the efficiency of the transactions, relative to the standard prediction. Employers reaped part of this efficiency gain. The average profit per period of employers in all four sessions was AS 18.9, while according to the standard prediction they should earn only AS 9.6. In session 1 (session 2) average profits per period amounted to AS 13.4 (AS 23.9); in session 3 (session 4) they were AS 16.2 (AS 22.8). A further objection to our interpretation of the data could be that experimental subjects might want to seem fair to the experimenters, but not to each other. For several reasons we think that

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

453

this interpretation is unlikely to account for the empirical regularities. First, the subjects were not students of ours. To them we were strangers, just like the other subjects. Second, they were recruited with the help of an information sheet in which any use of terms like fairness, equity, etc. was avoided, whereas we explicitly noted that they could earn "a considerable amount of money." To earn money seemed to be a major motivation for their participation. Third, in pure market experiments (without "our" second stage), it has been observed that a rapid convergence toward the competitive equilibrium occurs in a wide variety of circumstances. Smith [1976, 1980, 19821 reports that even in the case of similarly strong rent asymmetries as in our experiment,15and even if all agents were completely informed about these asymmetries, convergence could be observed. Although in the competitive equilibrium of these experiments, buyers (sellers) earned the whole rent (zero profits), buyers still did not want to seem fair in front of the researcher. Sellers, however, who "believed that it is 'fair' for trading profits to be shared between buyers and sellers (tried) to resist price decreases more vigorously than when they do not know what constitutes such a fair price" [Smith 1976, p. 2781. In accordance with Smith, we think that the combination of an extreme rent asymmetry, with complete information about payoffs, opens the way "for 'equity considerations' to modify self-interest choices" [1976, p. 2781. But, whereas in a one-stage market experiment sellers' 'equity considerations' are only temporarily successful in preventing a fall in the price, the addition of the second stage renders them much more powerful. Our results indicate that the effort decision is a very effective weapon for sellers, because it renders a high wage policy profitable for the buyers.

VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS
On the whole, our results provide evidence for the validity of the fair wage-effort hypothesis. But, of course, some questions remain open. The experiment is designed to test experimentally the "pure" fair wage-effort hypothesis. Therefore, our experimental design does not include features that are important in "real world" labor relations. In reality, employers and workers have the possibility to decide whether they want to stay together or not. In fact, most employment relations exhibit some durability. Long-term
15. Recall that if the standard outcome prevails, the whole rent is reaped by the firms.

454

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

interaction among workers, and between workers and employers, is likely to enhance the development of social ties that may well increase the fairness and reciprocity effects relative to the one-shot game. Of course, in long-term relations reputation effects and purely pecuniary incentives for high effort levels will in general exist. Until now, however, little is known about the impact of these long-term effects on the outcomes of experimental markets. In reality, firms also have some possibilities to control the effort of their employees. In most cases, they have no perfect control, but there is some probability that "lazy" workers will be punished, e.g., by losing their jobs. It is not clear how the possibility of punishing low effort levels will interact with fairness. On the one hand, it may weaken the impact of fairness. On the other hand, fairness considerations may then be applied to the severity and kind of punishment, too. If the latter is the case, it can be shown theoretically [Fehr, 19911that bonding and entrance fees may not be sufficient instruments to allow for market clearing. Whether this hypothesis can be established to hold in experimental markets, however, is left to future research.

The instructions given to the subjects were, of course, written in German. As already mentioned, we framed the experiments in goods market terms. The employers are called buyers, the workers are called sellers, the wage is called price, etc. Notice that buyers and sellers were located in separate rooms.

General Instructions (for both market sides)
The experiment you will participate in is part of a research project financed by the Austrian Science Foundation. It is used to analyze the decision behavior in markets. The instructions are simple, and if you read them carefully and make appropriate decisions,you can earn a considerable amount of money. At the end of the whole experiment, all the profits you have made by your decisions will be added up and paid to you in cash. The experiment you will participate in consists of two stages. In the first stage six of you act as buyers, and nine of you as sellers. In the second stage, the sellers will determine the value of the goods for the buyers (for details of the second stage see below). We have distributed two kinds of instructions-information for the buyers, and information for the sellers, respectively. This information is for private use only-you

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

455

are not allowed to reveal this information to anyone. Furthermore, you will find at the end of these instructions a second sheet (sheet 2) that is used to document your decisions. Insert your buyer or seller number there.

Specific Instructions for Sellers
At the market, a good is traded, and each seller sells the same good. A seller can sell this good to any buyer, and a buyer can buy it from any seller. The market is organized in the following way: we open the market for a trading period (a "trading day"), and each trading day lasts three minutes. Every buyer can offer a price that will be relayed to us by telephone.16We list these offers on the blackboard, and you can accept one of these offers. If, e.g., a price of 50 is offered and you as seller number 5 want to accept this offer, you just say: "Number 5 sells for 50." In this case, the transaction is concluded. The good is sold to the buyer who made the offer of 50. The buyer will not know your identity. He will just know that his offer is accepted. You have to note your accepted price on sheet 2. You can sell one unit of the good on each trading day. Therefore, the trading day ends for you after the acceptance of an offer. Note also that each buyer can buy, at most, one unit of the good per trading day. Each seller may accept an offer or not, but the sellers cannot make counteroffers. After three minutes the trading day ends, and the second stage of the experiment is conducted. After this, a new trading day is opened. In total there will be twelve trading days. At the second stage of the experiment, you can fix the value the good will have for the buyers. Buyers receive a certain amount of experimental money (reselling price) from us for each unit that they have bought. This reselling price is noted in the middle of sheet 2. The profit of a buyer (measured in experimental money) is the difference between the reselling price and the price at which he has bought the good from you. If "your" buyer has bought the good for 205 and the reselling price is 405, he makes a profit of 405-205 = 200 (measured in experimental money). How much one unit of experimental money is worth for "your" buyer depends on you. By the choice of a conversion rate, you decide how much real money "your" buyer gets from us for one unit of experimental money. If
16. In this context "us" meant that a supervisor in the buyers' room gave the price to a supervisor in the sellers' room who publicly announced the price. The second supervisor in the sellers' room then wrote this price on the blackboard.

456

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

you choose, e.g., the rate 0.5, your buyer gets AS 100 for 200 units of experimental money. Which conversion rates you are allowed to choose, is noted on the lower part of sheet 2. You have to write down your decision on the upper part of sheet 2. Do not announce your decision publicly. You, as a seller, have two kinds of costs: production costs and "decision costs." The latter are associated with your decision about the conversion rate. Of course, you incur costs only in case of a deal. If you do not trade on a certain day, your costs are zero for this day. Production costs are noted on the upper part of sheet 2. Decision costs depend on your choice of the conversion rate. The higher the conversion rate you decide to give to "your" buyer, the greater are your decision costs. The costs, which are associated with the conversion rate, are noted on the lower part of sheet 2. Your profit paid in AS is given by the formula: profit = price production costs - decision costs. If, for example, you sell your good for 175, while your production costs are 100, and you choose a conversion rate of 0.6 which leads to decision costs of 5, your profit is given by 175 - 100 - 5 = 70. Do you have any questions?

Sheet 2 (for sellers)
Seller number: Trading day: conversion rate price (1) production costs (2) decision costs (3) profit (4) = (1) - (2) - (3) 26

reselling price of the buyers: 126 profit of the buyer = (reselling price - price) . conversion rate Feasible conversion rates (CR) and associated decision costs (DC)

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

457

Specific Instructions for Buyers
At the market, a good is traded, and each seller sells the same good. A seller can sell this good to any buyer, and a buyer can buy it from every seller. The market is organized in the following way: we open the market for a trading period (a "trading day"), and each trading day lasts three minutes. As a buyer you can offer a price that must be divisible by 5, for example, prices like 15,60,80,275are allowed, but prices like 48, 67, 124, 83 are not. These offers will be announced to the sellers by us over the telephone. The sellers will not know your identity, that is, your buyer number; they will only know the price offered. If a seller accepts your offer, all buyers are informed about this acceptance. In this case, an agreement is concluded, and the good is bought by you at the offered price. During each trading day you can buy one unit of the good. Therefore, a trading day ends for you when your offer is accepted. Note also that each seller can sell one unit of the good per day at most. If your offer is not accepted, you are free to change your offer, that is, to make a new offer. But the new price you offer must be higher than all the prices that have not been accepted. Each seller may accept an offer or not, but he cannot make a counteroffer. After three minutes the day ends, and you cannot buy any more of a good. Then the second stage of the experiment will be conducted. After this, a new trading day is opened. On the whole, there will be twelve trading days. In the second stage of the experiment, the seller who has sold the good to you on this day can fix the value that the good will have for you. You as a buyer get a certain amount of experimental money (reselling price) from us for each unit you have bought. This reselling price is noted in the upper part of sheet 2. Your profit (measured in experimental money) is the difference between the reselling price and the price at which you have bought the good. If you bought the good for 205 and the reselling price is 405, you make a profit of 405 - 205 = 200 (measured in experimental money). How much one unit of experimental money is worth to you depends on "your" seller. By the choice of a conversion rate, he decides how much real money you receive from us for one unit of experimental money. Which conversion rates he is allowed to choose are noted on the lower part of sheet 2. If he chooses, for example, the rate 0.5, you will get AS 100 for 200 units of experimental money. Sellers have two kinds of costs: production costs and decision costs. The latter are associated with the decision about the conversion rate. Production costs are noted in the middle of sheet

458

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

2, and decision costs on the lower part of sheet 2. As you can see from sheet 2, the higher the conversion rate "your" seller chooses, the greater are his decision costs. The profit of the sellers paid in AS is given by the formula: profit = (price - production costs - decision costs). Suppose, for example, that you have bought the good for 175. The production costs of the seller are 100, and he chooses a conversion rate of 0.6 (which is associated with decision costs of 5), the profits of "your" seller are given by 175 - 100 - 5 = 70 AS. Do you have any questions?

REFERENCES
Adams, J . Stacy, "Toward an Understanding of Inequity," Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, LXVII (1963), 422-36. Akerlof, George A,, "Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange," Quarterly Journal of Economics, XCVII (1982), 543-69. Akerlof, George A., and Janet L. Yellen, "Fairness and Unemployment," American Economic Review (P&P), LXXVIII (1988), 44-49. Akerlof, George, and Janet L. Yellen, "The F a r Wage-Effort Hypothesis and Unemployment," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CV (1990), 255-83. Blinder, Alan S., and Don H. Choi, "A Shred of Evidence on Theories of Wage Stickiness," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CV (1990), 1003-16. Bowles, Samuel, "The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models," American Economic Review, LXXV (1985), 16-36. Fehr, Ernst, "Involuntary Unemployment, Power, and Asymmetric Mobility Costs," Quartalhefte der Girozentrale, XIX (1984), 67-82. , "A Theory of Involuntary Equilibrium Unemployment," Journal of Znstitutional and Theoretical Economics, CXLII (1986), 405-30. , "Fair Wages and Unemployment," discussion paper, University of Technology, Vienna, 1991. Fehr, Ernst, Georg Kirchsteiger, and Arno Riedl, "Involuntary Unemployment in the Laboratory-An Experimental Investigation of the Efficiency Wage Hypothesis," discussion paper, University of Vienna, 1992. Giith, W., P. Ockenfels, and M. Wendel, "Efficiency by Trust in Fairness?Multiperiod Ultimatum Bargaining Experiments with an Increasing Cake," discussion paper, University of Frankfurt, 1991. Homans, G. C., Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms (New York: Harcourt, Brace &World, 1961). Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard Thaler, "Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market," American Economic Review, LXXVI (1986), 728-41. Marshall, Alfred, "A Fair Rate of Wages," in A. C. Pigou, ed., Memorials of Alfred Marshall (London: Macmillan, 1925). Mowday, Richard T., "Equity Theory Predictions of Behavior in Organizations," in R. M. Steers and L. W. Porter, eds., Motivation and Work Behavior (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1991). Plott, Charles R., "An Updated Review of Industrial Organisation: Applications of Ex erimental Methods," in R. Schmalensee and R. Willig, eds., Handbook of ~nd)ustrial Organisation-Volume 2 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1989). Plott, Charles R., and Vernon L. Smith, "An Ex erimental Examination of Two Exchange Institutions," Review of Economic Jtudies, XLV (1978), 133-53.

DOES FAIRNESS PREVENT MARKET CLEARING?

459

Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph E. Stiglitz, "Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device," American Economic Review, LXXIV (1984), 4 3 3 4 4 . Smith, Vernon L., "Effect of Market Organization on Competitive Equilibrium," Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXVIII (1964), 181-201. "Experimental Economics: Induced Value Theory," American Economic keview, LXVI (1976), 274-79. , "Relevance of Laboratory Experiments to Testing Resource Allocation Theory," in J . Kmenta and J . Ramsey, eds., Evaluation of Econometric Models (New York: Academic Press, 1980). , "Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology," Journal of Political Economy, XCIX (1991), 877-97. Stoft, Steven, "Cheat Threat Theory: An Explanation of Involuntary Unemployment," mimeo, Boston University, 1982. Walker, James M., and Arlington W. Williams, "Market Behavior in Bid, Offer, and Double Auctions: A Reexamination," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, M (1988), 301-14.

http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 1 of 2 -

You have printed the following article: Does Fairness Prevent Market Clearing? An Experimental Investigation Ernst Fehr; Georg Kirchsteiger; Arno Riedl The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, No. 2. (May, 1993), pp. 437-459.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28199305%29108%3A2%3C437%3ADFPMCA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E This article references the following linked citations. If you are trying to access articles from an off-campus location, you may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR. Please visit your library's website or contact a librarian to learn about options for remote access to JSTOR.

References
Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange George A. Akerlof The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 97, No. 4. (Nov., 1982), pp. 543-569.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28198211%2997%3A4%3C543%3ALCAPGE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E The Fair Wage-Effort Hypothesis and Unemployment George A. Akerlof; Janet L. Yellen The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 2. (May, 1990), pp. 255-283.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28199005%29105%3A2%3C255%3ATFWHAU%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q A Shred of Evidence on Theories of Wage Stickiness Alan S. Blinder; Don H. Choi The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 4. (Nov., 1990), pp. 1003-1015.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28199011%29105%3A4%3C1003%3AASOEOT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-3 The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models Samuel Bowles The American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 1. (Mar., 1985), pp. 16-36.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198503%2975%3A1%3C16%3ATPPIAC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-N

http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 2 of 2 -

Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking: Entitlements in the Market Daniel Kahneman; Jack L. Knetsch; Richard Thaler The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 4. (Sep., 1986), pp. 728-741.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198609%2976%3A4%3C728%3AFAACOP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I An Experimental Examination of Two Exchange Institutions Charles R. Plott; Vernon L. Smith The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 45, No. 1. (Feb., 1978), pp. 133-153.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0034-6527%28197802%2945%3A1%3C133%3AAEEOTE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6 Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device Carl Shapiro; Joseph E. Stiglitz The American Economic Review, Vol. 74, No. 3. (Jun., 1984), pp. 433-444.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198406%2974%3A3%3C433%3AEUAAWD%3E2.0.CO%3B2-G Experimental Economics: Induced Value Theory Vernon L. Smith The American Economic Review, Vol. 66, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Eighty-eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1976), pp. 274-279.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28197605%2966%3A2%3C274%3AEEIVT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

Review: Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology Vernon L. Smith The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, No. 4. (Aug., 1991), pp. 877-897.
Stable URL: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199108%2999%3A4%3C877%3ARCTCBE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Net Neutrality

...Are you for or against Net Neutrality? I am in favor of Net Neutrality. I believe in Net Neutrality and the freedom of speech on the Internet. Content within a site should be free to the public. By protecting open Internet, it will insure that the Internet is not own by only a hand full of key players in the industry like Google, Verizon, Comcast dominating the Internet. What are your thoughts concerning this? My major concern about net neutrality is that few key companies would dominate the Internet. It might means pushing small companies out of business due to key players in the industry would take control over the cost of Internet, speed of the Internet, and even take control of access to information over the Internet. Internet became a part of our lives and in past 10 years most of our offline activities like banking, shopping, and professional recruitment are following the trends and move to the online world. For better or for worse, the Internet is changing the way we are evolving. At “The Future of the Internet” public hearing, FCC Commissioner Mignon L. Clyburn said “New and innovative media companies are constantly starting-up today, citizen journalism is on the rise, blogs have an increasing influence on public discourse, and media providers from broadcast networks to newspapers are shifting their strategies online. For these reasons and more, I say without hesitation, that an open Internet is indeed the great equalizer. It enables traditionally...

Words: 356 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Using Examples, Explain the Difference Between Obscene and Indecent Materials.

...1. Using examples, explain the difference between obscene and indecent materials. Obscene and indecent both have different meanings but are similar in many ways. Obscene material is described as disgusting or repulsive but indecent material is described as being offensive to the public. Both obscene and indecent can be view differently by the public; however, the Constitution plays a role with indecent material. Obscene material "is not protected by the First Amendment,” (The Dynamics of Mass Communication Tenth Edition, page 377) and broadcast stations cannot air obscene material at anytime. The problem with this is that no one had come up with a set standard of what obscene material is. Due to the difference in beliefs between families and individuals, no two people have the same beliefs and will not agree to a set standard of what obscene material really is. Since obscene material is can not be banned completely and therefore can be view during nighttime broadcasting. A good example of this is the adult swim channel. During the day children can view cartoons like Spongebob and Rugrats; but when 10 o’clock p.m. hit, the channel switches to adult swim when there are show with naked women and sex scenes. According to the U.S. Supreme Court, to be obscene, material must meet a three-prong test, "(1) an average person, applying contemporary community standards, must find that the material, as a whole, appeals to the prurient interest (i.e., material having a tendency to excite...

Words: 1267 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Fairness Opinion

...FAIRNESS OPINIONS IN MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS Anil K. Makhija* The Ohio State University Rajesh P. Narayanan Ohio University April 11, 2007 ____________________________________________________________ __________________ Abstract Fairness opinions provided by investment banks advising on mergers and acquisitions have been criticized for being conflicted in aiding bankers further their goal of completing the deal as opposed to aiding boards (and shareholders) by providing an honest appraisal of deal value. We find empirical support for this criticism. We find that shareholders on both sides of the deal, aware of the conflict of interest facing advisors, rationally discount deals where advisors provide fairness opinions. The reputation of the advisor serves to mitigate this discount, while the contingent nature of advisory fees appears to have no impact. We also find support for allegations that fairness opinions are sought by boards for the legal cover they provide against shareholders unhappy with the deal’s terms. JEL Classification: G34, G24 Keywords: Fairness Opinions, Mergers and Acquisitions, Investment Banking ____________________________________________________________ __________________ *Corresponding author: Anil K. Makhija, 700 E. Fisher Hall, Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University, Columbus, OH 43210. Tel: (614) 292-1899. E-Mail: Makhija.1@osu.edu. We are grateful for comments from Angie Low, Brian Nocco, Robert Rosholt, and René Stulz,...

Words: 14214 - Pages: 57

Free Essay

Media Forum

...Back when my mother was my age, the only media source they had was newspapers, radio, and television. Back then phones only had one function which was to communicate by voice and then came text. Now days our phone is a one stop shop for all media. All together though we do have: TV, phone, newspapers, radio, and the internet for our source media source. I personally don’t have cable anymore because of the dreaded news on each channel you turn to these days. I normally get my news from yahoo in whom I get an update in the morning and again in the evening. While serving in the Military, they told us that the only news we can really trust to be accurate was CNN and the Military News Network, that everyone else was exaggerated for higher program ratings. Should I be held accountable for their information? No. They should be, because the public values the truth and sometime the severity of it. According to Spark notes (http://www.sparknotes.com/us-government-and-politics/american-government/the-media/section3.rhtml) Printed media and Internet are unregulated. They can print whatever they want as long as they don’t slander anyone’s name. Broadcast Media is under strict regulations by the government. The FCC acts as a police agency over the airwaves. “Since the 1980s the government has loosened restrictions on media ownership, and Congress passed the Telecommunications Act in 1996 to allow companies to own even more media outlets. Due to the loosening of ownership restrictions, more...

Words: 359 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Understanding Teamsn

...With respect to what particular type of fairness did you score highest? What specific experiences contributed to this assessment?   My score was the highest in Interpersonal justice in the area of fairness that I received. My interpersonal justice score reflects the relationship that I have with my superior and my perception of fairness by my supervisor (Greenberg, 2010). I work for the same company for many years and my last boss was one of the best ever. He was concerned with family first and always treated all of the leaders and line level with respect. He also promoted from with in.   2. With respect to what particular type of fairness did you score lowest? What specific experiences contributed to this assessment?   Procedural justice was the type of fairness I received the lowest score for. The hospitality industry is tough. Often you work long hours and weekends. In the very beginning of your career, you work many holidays that keep you away form the family. When you first start off, the pay is not the best and you have to relocate to grow your career faster.   3. What kinds of problems resulted from any violations of any type of organizational justice you may have experienced? What could have been done to avoid these violations?   For me, I feel there is a disconnect in the field due the informational justice. Often leaders in the corporate office fail to provide information and explanations to the field. For management to be successful...

Words: 356 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Casue and Prevention of Burnout

...cause and prevention of burnout The human service field can be stressful for the professionals and wreck havoc to the organization. Burnout affects the employees as well as the organization; an organization suffers from burnout by having high turnover rates, accidents, and so on. This paper will define burnout and describe some of the individual, cultural, organizational, and social support factors that cause burnout. The paper provides an explanation of various individual, job role, and organizational methods to prevent burnout. In this paper I have shared the ways I react and respond to personal and work related stress as well as my reaction to combat the effects of burnout. Lastly this paper discussed how human service managers assist with staff burnout. Define Burnout According to help guide (2012,” Burnout is a state of emotional, mental, and physical exhaustion caused by excessive and prolonged stress. It occurs when you feel overwhelmed and unable to meet constant demands”. As the stress continues it causes you to lose interest or motivation I your work role. Individual, Cultural, Organizational, Supervisory, & Social Support Causes of Burnout Human service professionals may become overwhelmed and stressed especially when dealing with large case loads, overtime, and balancing work and home duties. Some of the personal lifestyle stressors include insufficient sleep, little or no time off, lack of social supports, and so on. Cultural factors contributing...

Words: 844 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Loss Prevention Policies

...Loss Prevention Policies Unit 5 IP Jessica Payne Loss Prevention Policies Each year companies stand to lose at least five percent of revenues to internal fraud. This may seem like a small percentage but it adds up. That five percent can be the difference between staying afloat or filing bankruptcy. When a company spends time and money to prevent fraud it is far less than running the risk of internal fraud. The most effective way to prevent fraud is to establish a proactive fraud prevention program. It is best if a company seeks the advice from a qualified fraud expert. A successful fraud prevention program requires three elements: education, investigation, and proactive preventative techniques. Most internal frauds are brought to attention from employees, customers, or vendor tips. Employees are the most likely source to provide tips of misconducts. So implementing a company-wide education program is a crucial part of a fraud prevention program (Coenen, 2011). Fraud education should focus on fraud awareness and should be presented to all employees. Investigating fraud is important to a comprehensive fraud prevention program. Although investigations are time consuming and costly the benefits are worth it. Investigations can have deterrent effects on potential thieves. Investigations send a company-wide message that management is aware and looking for fraud. Proactive fraud prevention techniques are the biggest asset in the company’s fraud prevention plan. Proactive...

Words: 1240 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Primary Prevention

...Primary Prevention University of Phoenix Axia September 19, 2010 Applying the strategy of primary prevention would be ideal with the issue of child welfare. However, there is no way of educating and predicting the problems that will arise from abuse and neglect in every household. To some extent there is a potential way of identifying those who are at a higher risk of becoming abusers, but when it’s never been reported in their cases, that could also pose a problem. To the best of the knowledge and abilities those in the human services organizations are equipped with, this can be an effective way to resolve or prevent these unfortunate situations from happening in the first place. Some policies or regulations that could be enforced to alleviate some of the tension brought about with child abuse and neglect, is to engage the parents in as much education as possible when they are expecting, or already have children. Some individuals, who are in stressful situations like poverty or chemical dependency, should be a top priority to serve with the resources and tools to assist them with any struggles. Those that are higher at risk of becoming abusers should take top priority with being given the opportunity to take mandated parenting classes. As this may be a difficult process to follow through with, the idea of being reprimanded with fines and community service may be just enough to lead those with these issues in the right direction. Creating government programs for those...

Words: 763 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Nursing, an Integral Part of Health Promotion

...Running head: NURSING, AN INTEGRAL PART OF HEALTH PROMOTION Nursing, an Integral Part of Health Promotion Grand Canyon University: NRS 429V September 18, 2011 Nursing, an Integral Part of Health Promotion Introduction Everyone in this global society has rights. All humans are born free regardless of race, color or creed. Everyone is entitled to these freedoms. In the pursuit of these freedoms, health is encompassed under these dignities. Everyone on this planet has the right to be healthy. This paper will examine the nurses’ role in helping people attain these rights. What and Why of Health Promotion? According to the World Health Organization (WHO), health is defined as “a state of complete physical, social and mental well-being, and not merely the absence of disease or infirmity” (WHO, 1998, p. 1). Health promotion is the process of empowering people to expand control over, and to improve their health. Health promotion is an encompassing process- it is social, it is political, it is economical, it is ever-changing. It not only embodies measures focused on strengthening the skills and capabilities of individuals to attain their inalienable right to attain optimal health, but it is also directed towards changing global perspective as well. Health promotion is the process of enabling people to increase control over the factors of health, thereby improving their health (WHO, p. 1). Nursing Roles and Responsibilities Involvement is essential to sustain health promotion...

Words: 1113 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Health Promotion in Nursing

...(O’Donnell, 2009). The purpose of health promotion in nursing is to keep people as healthy as possible. Nurses have the encounters with patients in the community whether it is in the outpatient or inpatient setting. As a nurse you have many opportunities to speak with your patients and family members and educate them on healthy behavior and risks factors that they may be involved in to prevent further illnesses if possible. Nurses use a plan of care to identify, implement, and evaluate that the goals are being met. This gives them a tool to make sure the patients are getting what they need. There are three levels of health promotion primary, secondary and tertiary prevention. The primary prevention is to prevent disease. The secondary prevention is to find the disease before there are any symptoms. The tertiary prevention is to slow down the disease process. “Health Promotion is the art and science of helping people discover the synergies between their core passions and optimal health, enhancing their motivation to strive for optimal health, and supporting them in changing their lifestyle to move toward a state of optimal health. Optimal health is a dynamic balance of physical, emotional, social, spiritual, and intellectual health. Lifestyle change can be facilitated through a combination of learning experiences that enhance awareness, increase motivation, and build skills and, most important, through the creation of opportunities that open access to environments that make positive...

Words: 962 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Health Promotion Gcu

...Running head: HEALTH PROMOTION Health Promotion: Educating The Nurse and The Public Kurt Luedtke Grand Canyon University Family Centered Health Promotion NRS-429V Vicki Denson Health Promotion The Healthy People 2010 report designates nursing as one of the prime proponents of health promotion. Nurses are the largest single group of health care providers in the United States with an estimated 2.6 million registered nurses practicing (ANA) throughout the country. As the largest field of health care providers nurses will have a huge affect on health promotion and health education through community, hospital and legislative based activity. More importantly, health promotion will need to be a greater part of the nursing education curriculum as nursing education has had a heavy emphasis on acute care and health education but only recently has there been an emphasis on health promotion. The World Health Organization [WHO] defines health promotion as the process of enabling
people to increase control over, and to improve, their health (WHO, 1986, p. 1). WHO broadly describes health as well being in the social, the mental, the environmental and the physical attributes of an individual or group not just a state from being free from disease. The idea that health promotion can help achieve health by assisting individuals and groups to become more active in their own health by various means such as education, promoting positive lifestyle choices, health...

Words: 1097 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Hjghjk

...DATE: January 12, 2012 TO: All Employees of Denver Branch FROM: Leonard Schwartz, Branch Manager SUBJECT: New Loss-Prevention System As you may have heard, we received news from corporate headquarters that it would be in the best interest of the company to pay more attention in matters of preventing accidents or any safety related measures. This would include both office and field related activities. Every employee should be mindful in this regard, so that each and every one is efficient and effective in their performance of everyday tasks. With this goal in mind, I believe that we should put more emphasis on safety. Everyone should consider their training they received in the beginning and also throughout their employment at M-Global, so that we are always aware on how to operate in a safe manner. Also, the training vehicle should provide each of you with the elements of safety that relate to the specific requirements of your particular job. I’ve come to a conclusion that we need to give greater scrutiny and analysis in a way that we can prevent accidents and emphasize the concern of safety for every employee. Kendra Jones will be assembling a written training program for every employee that will take effect June of this year. When this plan has been approved and written, I will be conducting a meeting with every department to emphasize the major and minor components of the safety program. It is my great pleasure to announce that effective February; I will be giving...

Words: 371 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Health Promotion

...Health Promotion Initially when health promotion was developed it grew and improved the healthy status and health conditions of the public. Health promotion is a relationship between actions, knowledge, attitudes, and behavior and health outcomes from the individual to the societal level. In the past the focus was more on disease prevention and control of communicable disease, when contagious and communicable disease like measles, polio and small pox were present. As government and health care agencies are involved communicable disease are under control and now focus on health promotion. This paper explore the concept of health , health promotion, multiple health models , nursing roles and responsibilities and multiple health models and its approach taken towards health promotion. According to each individual health is defined and can be affected by many factors. According to World Health Organization (WHO) (World Health Organization, 2003) health is a state of complete physical, mental and social well-being and not merely the absence of disease or infirmity. “Health is a complex state of metabolic efficiency that represents the biological integration associated with physical, mental, and emotional stability of a person. It represents the ability to identify and realize aspiration, satisfy needs and to change and or adapt to its environment. Health is therefore a resource for everyday life.” (Green, 2010) Health promotion is “the art and science of helping people discover the...

Words: 1358 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Single Parenting

...Primary Prevention: Single Parenthood Week 6 Individual Work Charryse Mason University of Phoenix HSM/210 Human Services in the United States April 22, 2014 Primary Prevention: Single Parenthood State and federal prevention programs direct their resources based on the level of prevention. This three-tiered system includes primary prevention, secondary prevention, and tertiary prevention. To address the issue of single parenting, primary prevention was chosen. The goal of primary prevention is to aid in minimizing the occurrence of single parenting, promoting awareness and recommending positive coping techniques. The text states that “Primary Prevention involves building strengths, resources, and competence inn individuals, families, and communities that can reduce the flow of a variety of unfortunate outcomes.(Burger and Youkeles,2004,p. 308) I think that this ties in with single parenting because it can help people cope well with difficult problems. For instance, a single parent may run into technical difficulties and may need help. This prevention can provide help like counseling or something to help prevent any psychological orders like depression. I know from experience that depression can take a toll on someone’s body. A single parent can have so many emotions. Primary prevention can help them cope with depression if it shall arise. Social Policies and Government Regulations A single parent comes across so many different obstacles. In today’s society the...

Words: 892 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Health Promotion

...Heath promotion as well-defined by the World Health Organization is the course of empowering individuals to upsurge control over, and to progress health. The theory of wellbeing advancement can be described as the art and science of serving individuals modify their life style attain a state of ideal health (Edelman and Mandle, 2010). This paper will present an integrative review upon the health promotion and its three stages of health prevention. The nursing roles and responsibilities sprouting in health promotion and the implementation of health will also be discussed in this paper. Purpose of Health promotion The goal of health promotion is to stimulate the health behavior of persons and societies and in same manner the physical and operational circumstances that affect their wellbeing. In other words, the aim of health promotion is to emphasis on “to focus on the person's potential for wellness and to encourage him or her to alter personal habits, lifestyle and environment in ways that will reduce risk and enhance health and will being (Smeltzer & Bare, 2006).” The chief motive of nursing in health promotion is to instruct inspire and support the patient to preserve an prevailing class of life by avoiding ailment, decelerating the advancement of a disorder or handling an sickness. Nursing Roles and Responsibilities Nurses have a significant impact in supporting community health. There have...

Words: 1190 - Pages: 5