Free Essay

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

In:

Submitted By yelloweagle
Words 7582
Pages 31
A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing
HUADONG(HENRY) PANG∗
Quantitative Research, J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. 277 Park Ave., New York, NY, 10017 Third draft, May 16, 2009

Abstract In this paper, we propose a novel simple but empirically very consistent stochastic model for stock price dynamics and option pricing, which not only has the same analyticity as log-normal and Black-Scholes model, but can also capture and explain all the main puzzles and phenomenons arising from empirical stock and option markets which log-normal and Black-Scholes model fail to explain. In addition, this model and its parameters have clear economic interpretations. Large sample empirical calibration and tests are performed and show strong empirical consistency with our model’s assumption and implication. Immediate applications on risk management, equity and option evaluation and trading, etc are also presented. Keywords: Nonlinear model, Random walk, Stock price, Option pricing, Default risk,
Realized volatility, Local volatility, Volatility skew, EGARCH.

This paper is self-funded and self-motivated. The author is currently working as a quantitative analyst at J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. All errors belong to the author. Email: henry.na.pang@jpmchase.com or hdpang@gmail.com.



1

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1374688

2

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

1. Introduction
The well-known log-normal model for stock price was first proposed by Louis Bachelier (1870-1946) and published in his doctoral thesis at 1900. His “theory of speculation” (Theorie de la Speculation, see Bachelier(1900)) was discounted by none other than Henri Poincare, observing that “Mr. Bachelier has evidenced an original and precise mind [but] as the subject is somewhat remote from those our other candidates are in the habit of treating.” Nevertheless, his model foresaw many of the mathematical discoveries made later by Wiener and Markov, and outlined the importance of such ideas in today’s financial markets, stating that “it is evident that the present theory solves the majority of problems in the study of speculation by the calculus of probability.” Later on, in 1973, Fischer Black and Myron Scholes first used log-normal model as underlying stock price dynamics to derive the analytical formula for stock options in their famous paper, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities” (see Black and Scholes(1973)). The now so called Black-Sholes formula is treated as foundation of option pricing and Robert C. Merton was the first to publish a paper expanding its mathematical understanding (see Merton(1973)). Due to its mathematical simplicity, the log-normal model and option pricing model based on it are now widely used at modern financial industry. Despite the success of log-normal and Black-Scholes model, lots of empirical evidence showed that the realized return of stock price diverged significantly from Brownian motion. For example, in 1988, Lo, A. and Mackinlay A.C. wrote a paper “Stock Market Prices do not follow random walk: evidence from a simple specification test” (see Lo and MacKinlay(1988)) rejected the random walk hypothesis. And the following six empirical phenomenons arising from equity and option markets have drawn much attention recently: (1) the leptokurtic feature that the realized return distribution of stocks often has a higher peak and two (asymmetric) heavier tails than those of normal distribution; (2) the default risk feature that company has positive probability to bankrupt in finite time period (e.g. Garlappi, Shu and Yan(2006)). The probability to fail in short term for many financial service, automobile, and other high leverage companies were significantly high in recent financial crisis. When the company’s stock is very stressful, the correlation between stock price and the spread of credit default swap, which measures the company’s default chance, is observed to be much higher than the one in bull market; (3) the local volatility feature that the volatility of stock highly depends on the stock

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1374688

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

3

price level and is significantly large in very stressful situation. One recent example is: at the first two weeks of September 2008, just before its filing for bankruptcy, Lehman Brother’s stock volatility is about 10 times higher than that during its 2004-2006 period. In this financial crisis, this phenomenon is observed almost everywhere; (4) the volatility clustering and EGARCH effect that for stock prices, large(small) changes tend to occur with cluster feature, in either sign, and negative changes have more impact on volatility than positive changes. In financial time series analysis, this autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity pattern and asymmetry effect of stock price change on volatility are popularly modeled by EGARCH model (see Engle(1995)); (5) the negative volatility skew phenomenon widely observed in stock option markets. If the Black-Scholes model is correct, the implied volatility from option market should be constant. In reality, the lower strike call or put option’s implied volatility is always observed to be higher. Many studies have been conducted to modify Black-Scholes model to capture this “volatility skew” feature. The most famous of them are local volatility model, stochastic volatility model, Levy process model (including jumping process model), etc; (see Cox(1996), Cox and Ross(1976), Hull and White(1987), Heston(1993), Andersen, Benzoni and Lund(1999), Duffie, Pan and Singleton(2000), Kou(2002), etc.) (6) the phenomenon that realized volatility on average tends to be lower than implied volatility (e.g. Christensen and Hansen(2002)). If the Black-Scholes model is correct, the implied volatility from option market should be able to describe the expected future volatility of stock price. However, the implied volatility seems always over-estimate the realized volatility. This may indicate that the implied volatility is the “wrong number” from a “wrong model” to get the right option price. Each phenomenon described above is a very active research topic in modern quantitative finance and there are hundreds of related research papers devoted to explain them. Some of them are very successful in explaining part of these phenomenons either in mathematics or in economics. However, by author’s knowledge, there was no single simple model which can resolve all of them simultaneously before this paper. The current paper proposes a novel model which has the following properties: (a) It resolves and explains all the above puzzles and phenomenons. (b) It is very simple. The stock price is modeled as a simple deterministic non-linear transformation of a log-normal hidden process. This simplicity induces analytical formulas for stock price and return distribution, stock local volatility, company’s future default curve (stock price implied), and many option pricing problems, including European call

4

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

and put, etc, whatever log-normal and Black-Scholes model can analytically solve. (c) The model and its parameters have clear intuitive economic explanation, which is consistent with corporate finance theory. The equity price is considered as a derivative product of company’s total asset. (d) The empirical calibrations and tests on large sample of liquid trading stocks (110 small capital, 391 mid-capital and 366 large capital stocks traded in current market with average annual volume over 1 million) show high consistency with model assumption and model implication. Though the empirical stock price is not random walk, the calibrated hidden process shows strong random walk characteristic.

2. The model
2.1 The model formulation We assume the risk-free interest rate r and the following log-normal hidden process under physical probability measure P : dV (t) = µV (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t), (2.1)

where W (t) is the standard Brownian motion, σ > 0. Then the stock price process S(t) is modeled by: S(t) = V (t) − Dδ+1 1min0≤s≤t V (s)>D , V (t)δ (2.2)

where 0 ≤ D < V (0) and δ = 2r/σ 2 . For notional simplicity and in order to get analytical solutions for option pricing, r, µ, σ and D are assumed to be constant. We also assume the stock pays no dividend. These assumptions, however, can be dropped to develop a more general theory. Solving the simple stochastic equation (2.1) gives the explicit dynamics of the equity price: S(t) = {V (0)e(µ− 2 σ
1 2 )t+σW (t)



Dδ+1 −δ(µ− 1 σ2 )t−δσW (t) 2 e }1min (µ− 1 σ 2 )s+σW (s) 2 >D 0≤s≤t V (0)e V (0)δ

(2.3)

Notice if D = 0, our model is reduced to Black-Scholes model. From now on, we concentrate on D > 0. This positive D introduces desired non-constant local volatility of equity price and negative volatility skew for option pricing as we will show later. And we have

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

5

P (S(t) = 0) = P (min0≤s≤t V (s) ≤ D) > 0, which means there is positive probability for the company to default(or bankrupt) between time 0 and t. Another interesting thing is that the risk-free interest rate r appears in our stock price dynamics through δ under physical probability measure P . We will see later, this is a key assumption in finding risk-neutral measure for S(t) in our model. This doesn’t happen in Black-Scholes model and most option pricing models since people observed the stock price change has low correlation with interest rate change. In our model, when r increases, S(t) tends to increase since S(t) is an increasing function of δ. But it doesn’t imply a high correlation between instantaneous change of r and S(t) since the change of V (t) has much more impact on change of S(t). However, in the long run, for the same path realization of V (t), S(t) seems to be larger for bigger r by our model (note this doesn’t mean strong cause and effect relationship between stock price and interest rate policy, because the realization of V (t) is more important for S(t)’s level). Interestingly, if not totally coincidentally, S&P 500 stock index did increase a lot while Federal Reserve increased rate from 2004 to 2006 and it experienced the biggest drop of last 70 years when Federal Reserve dramatically cut interest rate during this financial crisis starting from 2007. 2.2 Motivation and parameter interpretation In corporate finance, the equity is widely considered as a call option on company’s total value. The stock shareholder enjoys the infinite upside potential of company’s value growing, but has limited possible downside loss. When the company defaults (or bankrupts), all the shareholder can lose is the money which he/she used to buy the stock. However, once the company default, the stock price will be 0 hereafter (not a bad assumption, though in real life the shareholder could still get a little). So it’s reasonable to consider equity as a down-and-out call option on company’s total value with both strike and barrier equal to the total debt. Since the stock shareholders usually don’t (or can’t) liquidate the company’s asset and instead they sell the equity to other people, it’s fair to consider this option to be European but with very long maturity. We thus model the dynamics of company’s total value per share as log-normal process V (t) by (2.1), and consider the European down-and-out call option on V (t) with both strike and barrier equal D (interpreted as the debt per share) and maturity T > t. We assume the company still alive at t (i.e. min0≤s≤t V (s) > D) and assume constant risk-free interest rate r. This exotic option price at time t is well-known as (see Merton(1973) or

6 Kwok(1999)):

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

Cdo (V (t), T ) = V (t) N (d1 ) − (

D δ+1 D δ−1 ) N (d3 ) − De−rT N (d2 ) − ( ) N (d4 ) , V (t) V (t)

where N (x) is the cumulative density function of standard normal distribution, and
2 (t) √ ln( VD ) + (r + σ2 )T √ d1 = , d2 = d1 − σ T σ T 2 D D 2 2r d3 = d1 + √ ln( ), d4 = d2 + √ ln( ), δ = 2 . V (t) V (t) σ σ T σ T

˜ Note that when we compute this option price we used “risk-neutral” measure P such that ˜ dV (t) = rV (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t), ˜ ˜ where W (t) = W (t) + µ−r t is standard Brownian motion under P . For people familiar with σ ˜ derivative pricing theory, it’s obvious to see this P will be inherited as the risk-neutral measure for S(t) since the stock is modeled as a derivative product on V (t). Let T → +∞, we get our formula for stock price at time t: S(t) = lim Cdo (V (t), T ) = V (t) −
T →∞

Dδ+1 . V (t)δ

Notice that once V (t) hits D, then the stock price S(t) equals 0 (company defaults or bankrupts), and it should be stuck at 0 hereafter. So we model the dynamics of stock price as (2.2). As we described above, V (t) can be interpreted as company’s total value per share at time t and D can be interpreted as company’s debt per share. Notice the stock price is 2r an increasing function of δ = σ2 , which in fact controls the company leverage’s impact on stock price . When δ is high (the volatility of V (t) is low), the company’s high leverage (high V /(V − D) or high D/V ) will have less damage to company’s stock price than the low δ case. This is consistent with our economic intuition. 2.3 The simple non-linear function h(x) In our model, the stock price S(t) and hidden log-normal process V (t) are connected by the strictly increasing deterministic non-linear function h : [D, +∞) → [0, +∞) defined as Dδ+1 (2.4) h(x) = x − δ , x

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

7

Figure 1(a) describes the shape of h(x) for D = 10 and δ = 2. h(x) is a strictly increasing concave function, approximating to identity function as x goes to +∞. So the inverse function h−1 (x) of h is well-defined.

50 45 40 a typical shape of function h(x) the 45 degree straight line

22 20 18 the simulated log−normal process V(t) the simulated stock price S(t)=h(V(t))

35 30 25 20 15 10 10 5 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 8 6 16 14 12

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

(a) Shape of h(x)

(b) S(t)=h(V(t)) and log-normal process V(t)

Figure 1: Non-linear transformation h(x)

To give an initial intuition of the stock price dynamics S(t) given by our model, we draw a simulated log-normal process V (t) and corresponding h(V (t)) in Figure 1(b). When the stock price is high (so V (t) is far above D), S(t) behaves almost like a log-normal process. This is consistent with the stock price dynamics observed in bull market period. When the stock price drops a lot (so V (t) is low), the volatility of stock increases dramatically due to the leverage effect of h(x) (h (x) 1 as x is closing to D). And as the stock price is lower, the leverage effect on stock volatility is stronger (h (x) < 0). This describes the “panic effect” widely observed in bear market.

3. The distribution of S(t) and leptokurtic feature
To get the explicit formula for the distribution of S(t), we need the following standard result from probability theory (see Shepp(1979)): Lemma 3.1 Assume W (t) is a standard Brownian motion with drift η under probability measure P , W (0) = 0. For b < 0, Tb = inf {s ≥ 0; W (s) = b} is the first time W (t) hits

8

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

b. Then for any b < 0 and a > b, we have: b − ηt b + ηt P (Tb < t) = N ( √ ) + e2ηb N ( √ ), t t
(a−2b)2 1 ηa− η2 t − a2 − 2t 2 (e 2t − e e )da, 2πt where N (x) is the cumulative density function of standard normal distribution.

(3.1)

P (Wt ∈ da, Tb > t) = √

(3.2)

By Lemma 3.1 and (2.3), we immediately get: Theorem 3.2 The probability density function of S(t) modeled by (2.1) and (2.2) under physical probability measure P is β − γt β + γt P (S(t) = 0) = N ( √ ) + e2βγ N ( √ ), (3.3) t t g(x)2 (g(x)−2β)2 γ2t 1 P (S(t) ∈ dx) = √ eγg(x)− 2 (e− 2t − e− 2t )dx, for x > 0, σ 2πt[(1 + δ)h−1 (x) − δx] (3.4) h−1 (x) µ 1 D σ 1 where β = σ ln( h−1 (S(0)) ), γ = σ − 2 and g(x) = σ ln( h−1 (S(0)) ).

140

0.035 0.03

the distribution on positive region for S(5) with P(S(5)=0)=0.14% the log−normal distribution with same mean and variance
120

distribution histogram of realized return of S(t) normal distribution with same mean and deviation

100

0.025
80

0.02
60

0.015 0.01 0.005
40

20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

0 −10

−8

−6

−4

−2

0

2

4

6

8

(a) distribution of S(t)

(b) leptokurtic effect

Figure 2: The distribution of S(t) and the leptokurtic effect Figure 2(a) shows the distribution density function (solid curve) of S(t), with t = 5, r = 0.01, µ = 0.01, σ = 0.1, D = 20 and S(0) = 35. The log-normal density function (dashed curve) with the same mean and variance is also drawn for comparison. The distribution of S(t) has an obvious left fat and right thin tail comparing to log-normal. There is 0.14% probability for S(t) to be 0, which makes the left tail even fatter.

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

9

As we described in section 2.3, the return process of S(t) is not stationary, and it’s also not ergodic. So we can’t use the realized return in one realized S’s path to estimate the S’s true return distribution at fixed time t. If we do draw the histogram of realized daily return for one simulated S’s path by our model, we get the shape as in Figure 2(b). There is an obvious leptokurtic feature: a higher peak and two (asymmetric) heavier tails than those of normal distribution. This is consistent with what we observed in empirical stock market. Note this histogram highly depends on the realization of S’s path and has no “stationary” or “invariant” feature. In the modern financial industry, many people tend to use the realized historical stock return to estimate the stock’s future return distribution or to estimate the correlation between two stocks, which could be significantly wrong, especially in a stressful period when S(t) is very un-stationary and un-ergodic. Our model in fact provides a more accurate method for this distribution and correlation estimation problem by instead looking at the stationary and ergodic return process of V (t). The following is a simple but powerful application in dynamic hedging problem: Theorem 3.3 Assume constant interest rate is r, for i = 1, 2, stock Si (t) has hidden process Vi (t) such that, dVi (t) = µi Vi (t)dt + σi Vi (t)dWi (t) Si (t) = Vi (t) − δ Di i +1 1min0≤s≤t Vi (s)>D Vi (t)δi

2 where δi = 2r/σi . W1 (t) and W2 (t) are two standard Brownian motions with correlation ρ. Assume S1 and S2 are still alive(still positive) at time t, if we use the change of stock S2 to hedge the change of stock S1 , the optimal hedge ratio at time t is:

αhedge (t) = −

σ1 [V1 (t) + δ1 V11 δ1 ] (t) σ2 [V2 (t) +
D 2 δ2 V22 δ2 ] (t) δ +1

D

δ1 +1

ρ,

(3.5)

where Vi (t) = h−1 (Si (t)) and hi (x) = x − i

Di i xδi

δ +1

.

The proof is trivial by solving variance minimization problem minα V ar(dS1 (t)+αdS2 (t)) and using first order condition.

10

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

4. Local volatility, volatility clustering and EGARCH effect
When S(t) > 0, we use (2.1) and apply Ito’s lemma to S(t) = V (t) − DV δ to get the following local volatility representation of our model under physical probability P : dS(t) = [µ+(δµ−δr −r)( D h−1 (S(t)) )δ+1 ]h−1 (S(t))dt+[1+δ( D h−1 (S(t)) )δ+1 ]h−1 (S(t))σdW (t), δ+1 (4.1) where r, σ, δ, D and h−1 (x) are the same as in section 2. Notice when S(t) is close to 0 (then h−1 (S(t)) is close to D), the variance of dS(t) is approximating to (1 + δ)2 D2 σ 2 dt. So the process S(t) in (4.1) can hit 0, and we let S(t) = 0 after the first time S(t) hits 0. So if S(t) > 0, the local volatility of S(t)’s return at time t is σlocal (t) = σ[1 + δ( h−1 (S(t)) D )δ+1 ] . h−1 (S(t)) S(t) (4.2)

It’s very interesting to compare our model with other local volatility models, like the most famous constant elasticity of variance(CEV) model: dS(t) = κS(t)dt + νS α (t)dWt , (4.3)

where κ, ν are constants and α > 0. In CEV model, the variance of dS(t) is ν 2 S 2α (t)dt and the local volatility of stock return is thus σCEV = νS α−1 (t). To be consistent with the phenomenon that stock volatility is higher as price is lower, we must have α < 1 in CEV model. Figure 3(a) shows the variance of dS(t) to stock price S(t), and figure 3(b) shows the local volatility to stock price for both models. In CEV model, when stock price is very small, the variance of dS(t) converges to 0, while our model’s variance of dS(t) is still above a significant level. On the local volatility side, both models show significant growing as stock price is low. However, CEV’s local volatility converges to 0 when stock price is very large and the one in our model converges to a positive constant level. In reality, even when the stock price is very low, the magnitude of stock price change doesn’t converge to 0 and it’s very unrealistic for stock’s local volatility converges to 0 when stock price is very high. Our model is much more consistent with these empirical phenomenons than other local volatility models. The volatility clustering and EGARCH effect are kind of obvious from our local volatility representation (4.2). When the stock price moves into a high level region, the local volatility is almost constant and low, we are very likely to see a group of small changes clustering there. When the stock price drops into a low level region, the local volatility of stock will enter

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

11

14

50 40 the local volatility of our model to stock price the local volatility of CEV to stock price

12

30 20 10

10

8

0

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

6

0.5 0.4 the local volatility of our model to stock price the local volatility of CEV to stock price

4 the variance of dS(t) of our model to stock price the variance of dS(t) of CEV to stock price 2

0.3 0.2 0.1

0

0

1

2

3

4

5

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

(a) variance of dS(t) to stock price

(b) local volatility to stock price

Figure 3: Comparison of our model with CEV model into a high region, which expects a bundle of big changes during that period. By (4.2) and figure 3(b), starting in the same stock level, when the stock price drops, the impact on local volatility is bigger than when the stock price increases at the same amount/percentage, as the local volatility is a convex function to stock price in our model. (To prove the convexity of function in (4.2) to stock price S(t) is very easy, we leave it to readers.)

5. Risk-neutral measure and analytical option pricing formula
˜ Let Z(t) = exp − 1 ( µ−r )2 t − µ−r W (t) , then by Girsanov theorem, W (t) = W (t)+ µ−r t 2 σ σ σ ˜ defined by dP = ZdP . The ˜ is a Brownian motion under the new probability measure P ˜ dynamics equation of V (t) under P is: ˜ dV (t) = rV (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t). ˜ Let S(t) = V (t) − 0. By Ito’s formula,
Dδ+1 , V (t)δ

˜ ˜ and T = inf {s ≥ 0; S(s) = 0} be the first time of S(t) hitting

˜ ˜ ˜ d{e−rt S(t)} = e−rt {−rS(t)dt + dS(t)} = e−rt {−r[V (t) − = e−rt Dδ+1 δ 1 δ(δ + 1) 2 ]dt + dV (t) − Dδ+1 [− dV (t) + σ dt]} δ δ+1 V (t) V (t) 2 V (t)δ

1 δσDδ+1 ˜ Dδ+1 (δ + 1) (r − δσ 2 )dt + e−rt [σV (t) + ]dW (t) V (t)δ 2 V (t)δ =e
−rt

δDδ+1 ˜ (1 + )σV (t)dW (t), V (t)δ+1

12

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

˜ ˜ where we used δ = 2r/σ 2 . So e−rt S(t) is a martingale under measure P . By optional stop˜ ping time theorem, e−rt S(t) = e−r(t∧T) S(t ∧ T) is also a martingale, where t ∧ T = min(t, T). ˜ P is thus the desired risk-neutral measure for stock price S(t). Note that δ = 2r/σ 2 is a key assumption in our model to find this risk-neutral measure and thus guarantee no arbitrage in option pricing. Now under this risk neutral measure, we price the European call option with strike K > 0, maturity T (European put option can be priced according to put-call parity). As˜ sume S(0) > 0, then under risk-neutral measure P , the call option price at time 0 is ˜ C(S(0), K, T ) = E[e−rT (S(T ) − K)+ ] =e
−rT

Dδ+1 ˜ E[(V (T ) − − K)+ 1min0≤s≤T V (s)>D ], δ V (T )
˜

where V (s) = V (0)e(r− 2 )s+σW (s) . By Lemma 3.1 and after easy simplification, we get the analytical formula for call option price: Theorem 5.1 Assume stock price S(t) is modeled by (2.1)-(2.2) and is still alive at 0 (S(0) > 0), then the price of European call option with strike K and maturity T at time 0 is C(S(0), K, T ) = h−1 (S(0))[N (d1 ) − e−λ1 N (d2 )] − [h−1 (S(0)) − S(0)][N (d3 ) − eλ1 N (d4 )] −e−rT K[N (d5 ) − eλ2 N (d6 )], (5.1)

σ2

where N (x) is the cumulative density function of standard normal distribution, h−1 (x) is the δ+1 2r inverse function of h(x) = x − Dxδ , δ = σ2 and
(S(0)) ln( hh−1 (K) ) + (r + √ d1 = σ T
−1

σ2 )T 2

2 h−1 (S(0)) , d2 = d1 − √ ln( ), D σ T

d3 = d1 − (

√ √ 2r 2r + σ) T , d4 = d2 − ( + σ) T , σ σ √ √ d5 = d1 − σ T , d6 = d2 − σ T ,

h−1 (S(0)) h−1 (S(0)) λ1 = (1 + δ) ln( ), λ2 = (1 − δ) ln( ). D D Not surprisingly, as D → 0, our model for stock price converges to log-normal model and (5.1) converges to Black-Scholes formula.

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

13

6. Volatility skew and realized volatility
Our model intrinsically carries the volatility skew for option pricing. It comes from the left fat tail of stock price distribution as shown in figure 2(a). The positive probability to default feature in our model can make the left tail to be fat in any extent we want, which dramatically increases the ability of fitting very steep volatility skew curve. Figure 4(a) shows the model volatility skew for different σ and D parameters, with S(0) = 20, r = 0.01 and maturity T = 5.

2 1.8 1.6 implied volatility of call option 1.4 1.2 implied volatility

1.4

sigma=0.4, D=20 sigma=0.2, D=20 sigma=0.4, D=40 sigma=0.2, D=40

the implied volatility for 5 year call options 1.2 1 0.8

0
20 day window realized volatility

5

10

15

1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 5 10 15 20 strike 25 30 35 40

20 strike

25

30

35

40

1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 200 400 600 date 800 1000 1200 1400 simulated realized volatility in next 5 years

(a) volatility skew for different parameters

(b) realized volatility and implied volatility

Figure 4: Volatility skew and realized volatility In real life, on average, the realized volatility seems always below the implied volatility. Our model can explain this phenomenon very easily: the realized volatility is computed conditional on the stock didn’t default during that period, while the implied volatility captures the future stock volatility with default possibility. Obviously, the latter one should have a bigger number. Let r = 0.01, σ = 0.4, D = 20, S(0) = 20, figure 4(b) shows the implied volatility curve for call options with maturity T = 5 and the realized volatility in next 5 years by simulation. On average, the realized volatility is obviously below the implied volatility from option market at time 0.

14

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

7. Empirical test and applications
7.1 The empirical test Let’s take AIG(American International Group) as an empirical test example. The data we used is the AIG historical dividend and splitting adjusted close stock prices from 3/3/2003 to 9/30/2008, downloaded from http://finance.yahoo.com. The risk-free interest rate r is set to be 1%, and we get the calibrated σ = 0.0298, D = 72.7037 and µ = −0.0066. Figure 5(a) is the AIG stock price(solid curve) and its 20-day window realized volatil-

5 AIG stock price S(t) AIG stock S(t)‘s 20−day window realized volatility

100

90 AIG hidden process V(t) AIG hidden process V(t)‘s 20−day window realized volatility

50

0.1 0.05 0

80

0

Jan03

Jan04

Jan05

Jan06

Jan07

Jan08

0 Jan09

Jan03

Jan04

Jan05

Jan06

Jan07

Jan08

70 Jan09

(a) AIG stock price and 20-day window realized volatility

(b) calibrated AIG hidden process V(t) and 20-day window realized volatility

4 3 2 QQ plot curve for AIG stock price return QQ plot curve for return of AIG hidden process V(t) 45 degree straight line

3 AIG stock 20−day window realized volatility AIG stock model local volatility 2.5

2 1 0 −1 1 −2 0.5 −3 −4 −4 0 Jan03 1.5

−3

−2

−1

0

1

2

3

4

Jan04

Jan05

Jan06

Jan07

Jan08

Jan09

(c) QQ-plot with normal distribution for AIG stock price and the hidden process V (t)

(d) AIG 20-day window realized volatility and model local volatility

Figure 5: The calibration of our model for AIG stock

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

15

ity(dashed curve) between 3/3/2003 and 9/30/2008. Starting from September 2007, the realized volatility of AIG increased dramatically, and became extremely high at September 2008, when Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy, AIG had the liquidity problem and its credit rating was downgraded. The stock price of AIG was obviously not a log-normal process during this period. Figure 5(b) is the hidden V (t) process(solid curve) computed from V (t) = h−1 (S(t)) with calibrated σ and D. V (t)’s 20-day realized volatility is also drawn(dashed curve). The V (t) process shows amazing log-normal process feature with sampling volatility 0.0288. The calibrated model volatility σ = 0.0298 is not rejected by χ2 test at 5%. And V (t) is not rejected for random walk hypothesis using variance ratio test V R(q) (see Lo and MacKinlay(1988)) for q = 4, 8, 16 at 5% and for q = 2 at 4%. Figure 5(c) is the Quantile-Quantile(QQ) plot with normal distribution for AIG stock return(solid curve) and hidden V (t)’s return(dashed curve), which shows a significant improvement on the normality for V (t)’s return than the one of original stock price S(t). Figure 5(d) is the AIG 20-day window realized volatility and the model local volatility computed by formula (4.2). The model stock local volatility shows amazing consistency with realized one. We did an exhaustible empirical calibration and tests on all liquid (with average annual volume over 1 million) 110 small-cap, 391 mid-cap and 366 large-cap company stocks. The data we used is dividend and splitting adjusted close stock prices from 3/3/2003 to 3/20/2009, downloaded from http://finance.yahoo.com. We set risk-free interest rate r = 1% and a hard constraint that V (t)’s sampling volatility doesn’t reject V (t)’s model volatility σ at 5% by χ2 test. We then calibrated σ and D for each company by minimizing the distance between its V (t) return’s QQ-plot curve with normal distribution and the 45 degree straight line(we neglected the low 2.5% and high 2.5% quantiles). µ was estimated by the sampling drift of calibrated V (t) and is not a main parameter for calibration. The random walk hypothesis for V (t) is not rejected for 72% of small-cap, 71% of mid-cap, 62% of large-cap by variance ratio test V R(q) for q = 2, 4, 8, 16 at 5%. If we lower the significance level from 5% to 1%, the hypothesis for 86% of small-cap, 88% of mid-cap and 85% of large-cap is not rejected. Notice in our empirical tests we assumed D is constant during last 6 years, which could not be a good assumption for many companies. The risk-free interest rate set to be constant 1% could also be problematic as the Federal Reserve changed the rate significantly in past 6 years. Even so, thanks to the accuracy of our model, there are still more than 2/3 of liquid stock prices showing high empirical consistency with our model. The empirical test of our model in fact answers the following question: “Can stock price be modeled through random walk?”. The short answer may be: “Yes, but it need go through a simple non-linear transformation.”

16

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

7.2 Applications Due to the simple mathematical setup, the same analyticity with log-normal and BlackSholes model and high consistency with empirical stock and option markets, our model has wide applications in almost every area in equities. Besides the obvious application on option pricing and the dynamic hedge ratio mentioned in Theorem 3.3, we now exhibit several more immediate applications of our model (we neglect the detailed mathematics derivation, which is very easy if not trivial): (1) The Value at Risk(VaR) calculation. The traditional historical VaR method or other model-building VaR method on stock price could be significantly wrong especially in very stressful situation, because the return distribution of stock is neither stationary nor ergodic. Our model suggests that we could compute the tail distribution of stock return through its hidden process, which is both stationary and ergodic and the mapping between stock price and its hidden process is just a simple monotone non-linear function. This new VaR method can be easily generalized to stock portfolios and stock indexes. (2) The pair trading and statistic arbitrage strategy. As mentioned in section 3, the correlation between stock returns is not stable. It’s much better to consider the relation of stocks in stationary hidden process space. Assume we have two stocks whose hidden processes are highly correlated, but one of them has much higher default probability (very high D could cause this), there could be a statistical arbitrage opportunity by buying the low default-risk stock and selling the high default-risk one. We do the dynamic optimal hedging using Theorem 3.3 whenever their stock prices are above the initial trading prices. As the hidden processes drops, the stock price of the high default risk company will have a bigger drop than the other, by the leverage effect of non-linear transformation h(x). If there is a big increase on hidden process, even using the static hedging, the effect on both stock price is still comparable since the nonlinear function h(x) is concave and approximating to identity function as the variable is large. Not mentioning we have extra bonus of the high chance that high-default risk one does default before the other one. We have a very limited downside risk, but have very high upside potential and probability. A recent example is the stocks of Lehman Brothers and Goldman Sachs in 2008. (3) The exploration of mean reversion pattern. Possibly the greatest and oldest dream of stock investors is to detect when is the bottom and when is the peak of stock price. To realize

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

17

this dream, the stock price need show some mean-reversion pattern. However, even the stock does have the desired pattern, it could still be very hard to be captured due to the stock’s high non-stationarity. As usual, the much more stationary and ergodic hidden process V (t) can obviously help us, also thanks to the monotone feature of non-linear transformation h(x). (4) The trading signal from stock and option market. Due to the high consistency of our model on historical stock prices and the phenomenon from option markets, it is now feasible to calibrate our model using historical stock prices and currently traded option prices together. The market-model option price difference and calibrated stock distribution could indicate rich-cheap signals in either option products or stock itself.

Appendix. A simple generalization by an alternative method
In this appendix, we will give a simple generalized version to our model through an interesting mathematics way of thinking. We assume the risk-free interest rate r and a hidden process V(t) is log-normal process under some probability measure P(and assume the physical probability measure is change of measure to P): dV (t) = νV (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t), where ν is constant and W (t) is standard Brownian motion under P . Now we ask the following math question: “What’s the C 2 function h(x) such that e−rt h(V (t)) is a martingale?”. By Ito’s lemma, we have the following second order CauchyEuler equation for h(x): 1 −rh(x) + νh (x)x + σ 2 h (x)x2 = 0. 2 The general solution to this ODE is: h(x) = C1 xm1 + C2 xm2 , where m1 =
1− 2ν + 2 σ (A.1)

(A.2)

(A.3) .

( 2ν −1)2 + 8r 2 2 σ σ

2

and m2 =

1− 2ν − 2 σ ( 2ν −1)2 + 8r 2 2 σ σ

2

We model the stock price dynamics S(t) as following: S(t) = V (t)m1 − Dm1 −m2 V (t)m2 1min0≤s≤t V (s)>D , (A.4)

18

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

where D ≥ 0 is a constant and V (0) > D. By optional stopping time theorem, P is the risk-neutral measure for S(t). m2 ˜ ˜ Let V (t) = V (t)m1 , D = Dm1 , δ = − m1 , then we can rewrite (A.4) as:

˜ Dδ+1 ˜ S(t) = V (t) − 1min0≤s≤t V (s)>D . ˜ ˜ ˜ V (t)δ

(A.5)

˜ Now we have the same nonlinear function form as (2.4). V (t) is interpreted as the com˜ pany total asset per share. D is interpreted as the company debt per share. Notice when ν = r, this will be reduced to model (2.2), and when ν = r and D = 0, this will be reduced to Black-Scholes model. (A.5) can also be easily obtained by considering S(t) as a Euro˜ pean down and out call option with infinite maturity on V (t), with both barrier and strike ˜ ˜ equal D, calculated under measure P . There is no arbitrage since V (t) is in fact not tradable. By lemma 3.1 and simple calculation, we get the following analytical formula for European call option under this generalized model: Theorem A.1 Assume stock is still alive at 0 (S(0) > 0), then the price of European call option with strike K and maturity T at time 0 is: C(S(0), K, T ) = h−1 (S(0))m1 [N (d1 ) − eλ1 N (d2 )] − (h−1 (S(0))m1 − S(0))[N (d3 ) − eλ2 N (d4 )] −e−rT K[N (d5 ) − eλ3 N (d6 )], (A.6)

where N (x) is the cumulative density function of standard normal distribution, h−1 (x) is the inverse function of h(x) = xm1 − Dm1 −m2 xm2 , and
(S(0)) ln( hh−1 (K) ) + (σm1 + η)T 2 h−1 (S(0)) √ d1 = ), , d2 = d1 − √ ln( D T σ T √ √ d3 = d1 − σ T (m1 − m2 ), d4 = d2 − σ T (m1 − m2 ), √ √ d5 = d1 − σ T m1 , d6 = d2 − σ T m1 , 1 σ
−1

1 2 h−1 (S(0)) ν )(σm1 + η), η = − σ, λ1 = − ln( σ 2 σ D 2 h−1 (S(0)) 2 h−1 (S(0)) λ2 = − ln( )(σm2 + η), λ3 = − ln( )η. σ D σ D Not surprisingly, if ν = r, this formula will be reduced to (5.1), and if ν = r and D → 0 this formula will be reduced to Black-Scholes formula.

A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing

19

References
[1] Andersen,T., Benzoni,L. Lund, J. 1999. Estimating jump-diffusions for equity returns. Working paper, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL. [2] Bachelier, L. 1900. Thorie de la spculation. Annales Scientifiques de lcole Normale Suprieure. 3, (17): 21-86. [3] Black, F., Scholes, M. 1973. The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy. 81, (3): 637-654. [4] Christensen, B.J., Hansen, C.S. 2002. New evidence on the implied-realized volatility relation. The European Journal of Finance. 8, 187-205. [5] Cox, J. 1996. The constant elasticity of variance option pricing model. Journal of Portfolio Management 23, 15-17. [6] Cox, J., Ross, S. 1976. The valuation of options for alternative stochastic processes. J. of Financial Economics 3, 145-166. [7] Duffie, D., Pan, J., Singleton, K. 2000. Transform analysis and option pricing for affine jump-diffusions. Econometrica. 68, 1343-1376. [8] Engle, R. 1995. ARCH, Selected Readings. Oxford University Press, Oxford, U.K . [9] Garlappi, L., Shu, T., Yan, H. 2006. Default Risk, Shareholder Advantage, and Stock Returns. Third Credit Risk Conference Moodys Corporation & The Salomon Center, NYU Stern. [10] Heston, S. 1993. A closed-form solution of options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options. Rev. Financial Stud. 6, 327-343. [11] Hull, J., White, A. 1987. The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities.J. Finance 42, 281-300. [12] Kou, S.G. 2002. A jump diffusion model for option pricing. Management Science. 48, 1086-1101. [13] Kwok, Y.K. 1999. Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Springer Finance. [14] Lo, A., MacKinlay, C. 1988. Stock Market Prices Do Not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test Review of Financial Studies, 1, 41-66.

20

Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co.

[15] Merton, R.C. 1973. Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Ecnomics and Management Sciences, 4, 141-183. [16] Shepp, L.A. 1979. The joint density of the maximum and its location for a Wiener process with drift. J. Appl. Prob. 16, 423-427.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Modeling

...EXCEL MODELING AND ESTIMATION IN CORPORATE FINANCE Third Edition CRAIG W. HOLDEN Max Barney Faculty Fellow and Associate Professor Kelley School of Business Indiana University Copyright © 2008 by Prentice Hall, Inc., Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458 To Kathryn, Diana, and Jimmy. Contents iii CONTENTS   Preface ..................................................................................... vii  Third Edition Changes .................................................................................... vii  What Is Unique About This Book ..................................................................... x  Conventions Used In This Book .......................................................................xi  Craig’s Challenge ........................................................................................... xiii  The Excel Modeling and Estimation Series .................................................. xiii  Suggestions for Faculty Members ..................................................................xiv  Acknowledgements ........................................................................................... xv  About The Author ................................................................. xvi  PART 1 TIME VALUE OF MONEY ..... 1  Chapter 1 Single Cash Flow ....................................................1  1.1 Present Value .......................................................................................

Words: 33587 - Pages: 135

Premium Essay

Spreadsheet Modeling

...joy and pride. Craig CONTENTS Preface PART 1 TIME VALUE OF MONEY Chapter 1 Single Cash Flow 1.1 Present Value 1.2 Future Value Problems Chapter 2 Annuity 2.1 Present Value 2.2 Future Value 2.3 System of Four Annuity Variables Problems Chapter 3 Net Present Value 3.1 Constant Discount Rate 3.2 General Discount Rate Problems Chapter 4 Real and Inflation 4.1 Constant Discount Rate 4.2 General Discount Rate Problems Chapter 5 Loan Amortization 5.1 Basics 5.2 Sensitivity Analysis Problems PART 2 VALUATION Chapter 6 Bond Valuation 6.1 Basics 6.2 By Yield To Maturity 6.3 System Of Five Bond Variables 6.4 Dynamic Chart Problems Chapter 7 Stock Valuation 7.1 Two Stage 7.2 Dynamic Chart Problems Chapter 8 The Yield Curve 8.1 Obtaining It From Bond Listings 8.2 Using It To Price A Coupon Bond 8.3 Using It To Determine Forward Rates Problems Chapter 9 U.S. Yield Curve Dynamics 9.1 Dynamic Chart Problems PART 3 CAPITAL BUDGETING Chapter 10 Project NPV 10.1 Basics 10.2 Forecasting Cash Flows 10.3 Working Capital 10.4 Sensitivity Analysis Problems Chapter 11 Cost-Reducing Project 11.1 Basics 11.2 Sensitivity Analysis Problems Chapter 12 Break-Even Analysis 12.1 Based On Accounting Profit 12.2 Based On NPV Problems Chapter 13 Three Valuation Methods 13.1 Adjusted Present Value 13.2 Flows To Equity 13.3 Weighted Average Cost of Capital Problems PART 4 FINANCIAL PLANNING Chapter 14 Corporate Financial Planning 14.1 Actual 14...

Words: 49278 - Pages: 198

Free Essay

Ltcm

...Abstract Arbitrage is a key process in the practice of financial markets and in their theoretical depiction: it allows markets to be posited as efficient without all investors being assumed to be rational. This article explores the sociology of arbitrage by means of an examination of the arbitrageurs, Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM). LTCM’s 1998 crisis is analysed using both qualitative, interview-based data and quantitative examination of price movements. It is suggested that the roots of the crisis lay in an unstable pattern of imitation that had developed in the markets within which LTCM operated. As the resulting ‘superportfolio’ began to unravel, arbitrageurs other than LTCM fled the market, even as arbitrage opportunities became more attractive, causing huge price movements against LTCM. Three features of the sociology of arbitrage are discussed: its conduct by people often personally known to each other; the possibility and consequences of imitation; and the limits on the capacity of arbitrage to close price discrepancies. It is suggested that by 1998 imitative arbitrage formed a ‘global microstructure’ in the sense of Knorr Cetina and Bruegger. Keywords: arbitrage; economic sociology; imitation; Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM); globalization; risk. Introduction Of all the contested boundaries that define the discipline of sociology, none is more crucial than the divide between sociology and economics. Despite his synthesizing ambitions, Talcott...

Words: 16475 - Pages: 66

Premium Essay

Momentum–Trading Strategy

...Slow Diffusion of Information and Price Momentum in Stocks: Evidence from Options Markets Zhuo Chen∗ Andrea Lu† September 6, 2014 Abstract This paper investigates the source of price momentum in the equity market using information from options markets. The empirical results provide direct evidence of the gradual information diffusion model in Hong and Stein (1999). Consistent with their theory, we show that a successful identification of stocks’ information diffusion stage helps explain momentum profits. We are able to enhance momentum profits by longing winner stocks with higher growth (and shorting loser stocks with larger drop) in call options implied volatility. Our empirical strategy generates a risk-adjusted alpha of 1.8% per month for a hedged winner-minus-loser portfolio over the 1996–2011 period, during which the simple momentum strategy fails to perform. The results are stronger and clearer if we use call options compared with put options, which are consistent with managers’ tendency to reveal good news and hide bad news. Our results are robust to transaction costs, choice of options’ moneyness, elimination of implied volatility persistence, and choice of options’ time-to-maturity. Finally, our results are not driven by existing stock-level characteristics, such as size, trading volume, and analyst coverage. JEL Classification: G10, G11, G12, G13 Keywords: Momentum, Implied Volatility PBC School of Finance, Tsinghua University. Email: chenzh@pbcsf.tsinghua.edu.cn...

Words: 22536 - Pages: 91

Premium Essay

Textbook

...introduction to econometrics specifically written for finance students. It includes examples and case studies which finance students will recognise and relate to. This new edition builds on the successful data- and problem-driven approach of the first edition, giving students the skills to estimate and interpret models while developing an intuitive grasp of underlying theoretical concepts. Key features: ● Thoroughly revised and updated, including two new chapters on ● ● ● ● ● ● panel data and limited dependent variable models Problem-solving approach assumes no prior knowledge of econometrics emphasising intuition rather than formulae, giving students the skills and confidence to estimate and interpret models Detailed examples and case studies from finance show students how techniques are applied in real research Sample instructions and output from the popular computer package EViews enable students to implement models themselves and understand how to interpret results Gives advice on planning and executing a project in empirical finance, preparing students for using econometrics in practice Covers important modern topics such as time-series forecasting, volatility modelling, switching models and simulation methods Thoroughly class-tested in leading finance schools Chris Brooks is Professor of Finance at the ICMA Centre, University of Reading, UK, where he also obtained his PhD. He has published over sixty articles in leading academic and practitioner journals including the Journal of...

Words: 195008 - Pages: 781

Premium Essay

Econometrics

...econometrics specifically written for finance students. It includes examples and case studies which finance students will recognise and relate to. This new edition builds on the successful data- and problem-driven approach of the first edition, giving students the skills to estimate and interpret models while developing an intuitive grasp of underlying theoretical concepts. Key features: ● Thoroughly revised and updated, including two new chapters on ● ● ● ● ● ● panel data and limited dependent variable models Problem-solving approach assumes no prior knowledge of econometrics emphasising intuition rather than formulae, giving students the skills and confidence to estimate and interpret models Detailed examples and case studies from finance show students how techniques are applied in real research Sample instructions and output from the popular computer package EViews enable students to implement models themselves and understand how to interpret results Gives advice on planning and executing a project in empirical finance, preparing students for using econometrics in practice Covers important modern topics such as time-series forecasting, volatility modelling, switching models and simulation methods Thoroughly class-tested in leading finance schools Chris Brooks is Professor of Finance at the ICMA Centre, University of Reading, UK, where he also obtained his PhD. He has published over sixty articles in leading academic and practitioner journals including ...

Words: 195008 - Pages: 781

Premium Essay

Ggggggg

...Retailing in the 21st Century Manfred Krafft ´ Murali K. Mantrala (Editors) Retailing in the 21st Century Current and Future Trends With 79 Figures and 32 Tables 12 Professor Dr. Manfred Krafft University of Muenster Institute of Marketing Am Stadtgraben 13±15 48143 Muenster Germany mkrafft@uni-muenster.de Professor Murali K. Mantrala, PhD University of Missouri ± Columbia College of Business 438 Cornell Hall Columbia, MO 65211 USA mantralam@missouri.edu ISBN-10 3-540-28399-4 Springer Berlin Heidelberg New York ISBN-13 978-3-540-28399-7 Springer Berlin Heidelberg New York Cataloging-in-Publication Data Library of Congress Control Number: 2005932316 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilm or in any other way, and storage in data banks. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of the German Copyright Law of September 9, 1965, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer-Verlag. Violations are liable for prosecution under the German Copyright Law. Springer is a part of Springer Science+Business Media springeronline.com ° Springer Berlin ´ Heidelberg 2006 Printed in Germany The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, etc. in this publication does not...

Words: 158632 - Pages: 635

Premium Essay

Finance

...in a database or retrieval system, without prior written permission of the publisher. This McGraw−Hill Primis text may include materials submitted to McGraw−Hill for publication by the instructor of this course. The instructor is solely responsible for the editorial content of such materials. 111 FINAGEN ISBN: 0−390−55204−6 Finance Contents Ross−Westerfield−Jaffe • Corporate Finance, Seventh Edition I. Overview 1 1 20 34 34 35 70 98 130 152 152 193 219 219 241 241 275 1. Introduction to Corporate Finance 2. Accounting Statements and Cash Flow II. Value and Capital Budgeting Introduction 4. Net Present Value 5. How to Value Bonds and Stocks 7. Net Present Value and Capital Budgeting 8. Risk Analysis, Real Options, and Capital Budgeting III: Risk 10. Return and Risk: The Capital−Asset−Pricing Model (CAPM) 12. Risk, Cost of Capital, and Capital Budgeting VII. Short−Term Finance 27. Cash Management VIII. Special Topics 29. Mergers and Acquisitions 31. International Corporate Finance Harvard Business School Entrepreneurship Cases JAFCO American Ventures, Inc.: Building a Venture Capital Firm 299 299 Case Harvard Business School Finance Cases Pioneer...

Words: 179333 - Pages: 718

Free Essay

Ibfm

...Scotland Abstract: This paper develops a model of the information intermediation role of analysts in the ‘market for information’ (MFI). It illustrates how the same type of ‘soft’ intangibles information changes as it progresses through analyst information intermediation processes. The latter concern: company disclosure; analyst acquisition and analysis of company information; analyst reporting processes; and market impacts. The common information concerns ‘soft’ or qualitative information about the company intellectual capital (IC) or intangibles in the company business model. Banks and bank analysts are used as examples. Knowledge, social and economic factors in the wider ‘market for information’ (MFI) are shown to be major influences on ‘soft information’ and how it changes in analyst information intermediation processes. Negative knowledge and social factors play a role in weakening and eventually destabilising economic processes in analyst and the MFI. They were important factors in creating knowledge and information problems in analysts and the MFI, both ongoing, and during the crisis of 2007-09. These factors are also part of a solution to the problems. The solutions include improved, transparent knowledge of business models of companies, analysts, and rest of MFI. They also include active use of social forces to create critical and reflexive performativity conditions in the MFI. The empirical analysis is discussed in a novel theoretical...

Words: 28563 - Pages: 115

Premium Essay

Basic Mba

...BU Basic M.B.A. International Master of Business Administration |Index | Accounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 Business Law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 Entrepreneurship. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 Finance. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119 Management. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160 Marketing. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180 Operations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220 Statistics. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 252 Strategic Management. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ...

Words: 103642 - Pages: 415

Premium Essay

Corporate Competitive Strategy

...Quantitative Business Valuation Other Titles in the Irwin Library of Investment and Finance Convertible Securities by John P. Calamos Pricing and Managing Exotic and Hybrid Options by Vineer Bhansali Risk Management and Financial Derivatives by Satyajit Das Valuing Intangible Assets by Robert F. Reilly and Robert P. Schweihs Managing Financial Risk by Charles W. Smithson High-Yield Bonds by Theodore Barnhill, William Maxwell, and Mark Shenkman Valuing Small Business and Professional Practices, 3rd edition by Shannon Pratt, Robert F. Reilly, and Robert P. Schweihs Implementing Credit Derivatives by Israel Nelken The Handbook of Credit Derivatives by Jack Clark Francis, Joyce Frost, and J. Gregg Whittaker The Handbook of Advanced Business Valuation by Robert F. Reilly and Robert P. Schweihs Global Investment Risk Management by Ezra Zask Active Portfolio Management 2nd edition by Richard Grinold and Ronald Kahn The Hedge Fund Handbook by Stefano Lavinio Pricing, Hedging, and Trading Exotic Options by Israel Nelken Equity Management by Bruce Jacobs and Kenneth Levy Asset Allocation, 3rd edition by Roger Gibson Valuing a Business, 4th edition by Shannon P. Pratt, Robert F. Reilly, and Robert Schweihs The Relative Strength Index Advantage by Andrew Cardwell and John Hayden Quantitative Business Valuation A Mathematical Approach for Today’s Professional JAY B. ABRAMS, ASA, CPA, MBA McGRAW-HILL New York San Francisco Washington, D.C. Auckland Bogota ´ Caracas Lisbon London...

Words: 214584 - Pages: 859

Premium Essay

Health Care Finance

...any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without prior written permission of the publisher. This McGraw−Hill Primis text may include materials submitted to McGraw−Hill for publication by the instructor of this course. The instructor is solely responsible for the editorial content of such materials. 111 FINAGEN ISBN: 0−390−55313−1 Finance Contents Ross−Westerfield−Jaffe • Corporate Finance, Seventh Edition I. Overview 1 1 20 34 34 69 97 129 151 151 192 192 214 214 248 1. Introduction to Corporate Finance 2. Accounting Statements and Cash Flow II. Value and Capital Budgeting 4. Net Present Value 5. How to Value Bonds and Stocks 7. Net Present Value and Capital Budgeting 8. Risk Analysis, Real Options, and Capital Budgeting III: Risk 10. Return and Risk: The Capital−Asset−Pricing Model (CAPM) VII. Short−Term Finance 27. Cash Management VIII. Special Topics 29. Mergers and Acquisitions 31. International Corporate Finance Baker−Lembke−King • Advanced Financial Accounting, Sixth Edition 19. Not−for−Profit Entities 272 272 Text...

Words: 226746 - Pages: 907

Free Essay

Gravity Equation

...NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GRAVITY EQUATION IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE: AN EXPLANATION Thomas Chaney Working Paper 19285 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19285 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 2013 I want to thank Fernando Alvarez, Michal Fabinger, Xavier Gabaix, Sam Kortum, Bob Lucas, Jim Tybout, Jon Vogel and seminar participants in Berkeley, Bilkent, Bocconi, Boston University, Chicago, Erasmus, Hitotsubashi, LBS, Louvain-CORE, LSE, the NY Fed, Oxford, Princeton, Rochester, Sciences Po, Toulouse, UBC Vancouver, Yale and Zurich for helpful discussions, and NSF grant SES-1061622 for financial support. I am indebted to Jong Hyun Chung, Stefano Mosso and Adriaan Ten Kate for their research assistance. During the last year, I have received compensation for teaching activities from the Toulouse School of Economics, as well a research grant from the National Science Foundation (SES-1061622), in excess of $10,000. The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peerreviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2013 by Thomas Chaney. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit...

Words: 18767 - Pages: 76

Premium Essay

Acc 803: Leo’s Four-Plex Theater Case

...Accounting, Organizations and Society 28 (2003) 127–168 www.elsevier.com/locate/aos Management control systems design within its organizational context: findings from contingency-based research and directions for the future Robert H. Chenhall Department of Accounting and Finance, Monash University, Clayton, Victoria 3168, Australia Abstract Contingency-based research has a long tradition in the study of management control systems (MCS). Researchers have attempted to explain the effectiveness of MCS by examining designs that best suit the nature of the environment, technology, size, structure, strategy and national culture. In recent years, contingency-based research has maintained its popularity with studies including these variables but redefining them in contemporary terms. This paper provides a critical review of findings from contingency-based studies over the past 20 years, deriving a series of propositions relating MCS to organizational context. The paper examines issues related to the purpose of MCS, the elements of MCS, the meaning and measurement of contextual variables, and issues concerning theory development. A final section considers the possibility that contingency-based ideas could encompass insights from a variety of theories to help understand MCS within its organizational context. # 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction The three purposes of this paper are to provide a review of empirical, contingency-based research as it has developed...

Words: 26957 - Pages: 108

Premium Essay

Gaurav

...9690010114 Yogendera sharma CONTRIBUTED PAPERS A41, Thursday, December 28, 4:00-5:30 P.M. Session: Case Studies - I Session Chair: Prashant Kulkarni Institute of Finance and International Ma 418 Global Marketing and Challenges for Future: Franchising in Banks K. Ravichandran, Gandhigram Rural University, drkravichandran@yahoo.co.in R. Muruganandham, Sudharsana Raamanujan, R, P. Nandakumar, M. Sasi Siddharth Thiagarajar College of Engineering, vr_muruganandham@hotmail.com, siddharth_mss@sify.com raamanujan@gmail.com, nandacivil@gmail.com The global economic scenario is undergoing a major innovative metamorphosis at a rate never experienced before. All organizations have their brands to face the global marketing challenges to secure a role of leader in this state of economic revolution. Our paper identifies the current marketing challenges and global economic threats for service industries. Besides our paper also explores the management strategies to overcome these challenges in the liberalized economy. The banking service is considered, where the franchising marketing strategies, introduction of new products and delightful customer service by new private sector banks and foreign banks pose a serious threat to the existence and survival of public sector banks profitwise. Hence our paper deeply discusses the benefits of e-banking with a view to minimize transaction cost cum operating expenses thereby increasing the overall net profit...

Words: 23823 - Pages: 96