Free Essay

Budget Deficits, National Saving, and Interest Rates

In:

Submitted By quarto
Words 31953
Pages 128
Budget Deficits, National Saving, and Interest Rates

William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag
September 2004

Brookings Institution and Tax Policy Center. This paper was prepared for the Brookings
Panel on Economic Activity, September 9-10, 2004. We thank Emil Apostolov, Matt
Hall, Brennan Kelly, and Melody Keung for outstanding research assistance; Alan
Auerbach, William Brainard, Robert Cumby, Bill Dickens, Doug Elmendorf, Eric Engen,
Laurence Kotlikoff, Thomas Laubach, Maria Perozek, George Perry, Frank Russek,
Matthew Shapiro, and David Wilcox for helpful discussions; and Eric Engen, Jane
Gravelle, and Thomas Laubach for sharing data.

ABSTRACT

This paper provides new evidence that sustained budget deficits reduce national saving and raise interest rates by economically and statistically significant quantities.
Using a series of econometric specifications that nest Ricardian and non-Ricardian models, we obtain evidence of strong non-Ricardian behavior in aggregate consumption.
Consistent with several recent studies, we find that projected future deficits affect longterm interest rates, but current deficits do not. Our estimates suggest that each percent-ofGDP in current deficits reduces national saving by 0.5 to 0.8 percent of GDP. Each percent-of-GDP in projected future unified deficits raises forward long-term interest rates by 25 to 35 basis points, and each percent-of-GDP in projected future primary deficits raises interest rates by 40 to 70 basis points.

Budget Deficits, National Saving, and Interest Rates
September 2004
I. Introduction
Economic analysis of the aggregate effects of fiscal policy dates back at least to the work of David Ricardo. Modern academic interest was reinvigorated by the work of
Barro (1974) and others, and by the large U.S. federal budget deficits in the 1980s and early 1990s. These factors led to a substantial amount of research that is summarized in several excellent surveys.1 The rapid but short-lived transition to unified budget surpluses in the late 1990s, followed by the sharp reversal in budget outcomes since
2000, has raised interest in this question again.
Economists tend to view the aggregate effects of fiscal policy from one of three principal perspectives. To sharpen the distinctions among the models, it is helpful to consider deficits induced by changes in the timing of lump-sum taxes, holding the path of government purchases constant. Under the Ricardian Equivalence hypothesis, such deficits are fully offset by increases in private saving and have no effect on national saving, interest rates, exchange rates, future domestic production, or future national income. A second model, the small open economy view, suggests that budget deficits reduce national saving, but that international capital inflows finance the entire reduction in national saving. In this model, budget deficits increase borrowing from abroad and therefore reduce future national income, but they do not affect interest rates or future domestic production. A third model, which we call the conventional view, suggests that deficits reduce national saving and that the reduction in national saving is at least partly reflected in lower domestic investment. In this model, budget deficits partly crowd out private investment and partly increase borrowing from abroad, both of which reduce future national income and future domestic production. The reduction in domestic investment in this model is facilitated by an increase in interest rates, establishing a connection between deficits and interest rates.
We emphasize throughout this paper that the distinction between the first model and the latter two is the most fundamental: that is, the relationship between deficits and national saving is central to analysis of the economic effects of fiscal policy. National saving, which is the sum of private and government saving, finances national investment, which is the sum of domestic investment (the accumulation by Americans of assets at home) or net foreign investment (the net accumulation by Americans of assets abroad).
The accumulation of assets associated with national saving means that the capital stock owned by Americans rises. The returns to those additional assets raise the income of
Americans in the future.
An increase in the budget deficit reduces national saving unless it is fully offset by an increase in private saving. If national saving falls, then national investment and
1

See Barro (1989), Barth et al (1991), Bernheim (1987, 1989), Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999), and Seater
(1993).

1

future national income must fall as well, all else equal. In other words, to the extent that budget deficits reduce national saving, they reduce future national income. This reduction in future national income occurs even if the reduction in national saving associated with budget deficits manifests itself solely in increased borrowing from abroad
(as under the small open economy view), with no increase in domestic interest rates.
If national saving falls, a second question is how the elements of the identity that national saving equals national investment come back into alignment. The possibilities are limited: either domestic investment falls and/or net foreign investment falls. These changes in investment quantities can occur through different combinations of changes in prices (interest rates and exchange rates), but they must occur even if one of the prices does not move. This is the sense in which the effect of deficits on interest rates and exchange rates (the distinction between the small open economy view and the conventional one) is subsidiary to the question of the effects on national saving (the
Ricardian view versus the other two).
A key objective of this paper is to distinguish among the three models empirically. We test the Ricardian view against the small open economy and conventional views by estimating the effect on national saving of budget deficits associated with tax reductions, controlling for government purchases, transfers, marginal tax rates, and other factors. Our empirical results imply that such budget deficits substantially reduce national saving, suggesting that the Ricardian view is not a reasonable approximation to reality. We then test the small open economy view against the conventional one by examining whether deficits affect interest rates. Our results suggest that projected budget deficits raise long-term interest rates in the United States.
(Indeed, despite a rancorous public debate, there appears to be a surprising degree of convergence in recent estimates of the effects of sustained budget deficits on interest rates.) The relationship between deficits and interest rates not only provides further evidence against the Ricardian view, but also implies that the conventional view is a better description of reality for the United States than the small open economy view.
A second objective is to apply the findings to analysis of recent and projected fiscal policy actions. Under plausible assumptions described below, the unified deficit over the next decade will average about 3.5 percent of GDP. Our estimates suggest that these deficits will reduce national income by about 1 to 2 percent, on an ongoing basis, by 2015. In addition, in conjunction with other information, the estimates imply that making the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts permanent would raise the cost of capital for new investment, and reduce long-term investment and economic growth.
Section II provides information on historical patterns and projections for federal debt, deficits, and components. Section III provides a framework for evaluating fiscal policy by comparing the three models noted above and discussing other, less traditional, ways that deficits can affect economic performance. Section IV provides preliminary empirical analysis that generally supports the conventional view, and simulates the likely magnitude of fiscal policy effects in the conventional approach. Section V examines the

2

effects of deficits on aggregate consumption. Section VI explores links between deficits and interest rates. A final section discusses some of the implications of our findings.
II. Fiscal Policy: Trends and Projections
The federal budget deficit in any year can be measured in a variety of ways; the most appropriate measure is likely to be dependent on the particular model or application employed. The most widely-used measure, the unified budget balance, is fundamentally a cash-flow metric that includes both the Social Security and non-Social Security components of the Federal budget. To a first approximation, the unified deficit shows the extent to which the government borrows or lends in credit markets.2 For some purposes, it is more informative to examine the primary budget, which excludes interest payments from unified budget. The standardized budget balance adjusts the unified budget for the business cycle and special items.3 We focus primarily on these traditional cash-flow measures. In particular, while we recognize the importance of the implicit debt created by promises of future government benefits, we do not incorporate these promises directly into our analysis, in part because historical time series are not generally available and in part because it is unclear how the market and households value this implicit debt relative to the government’s explicit debt.4
Figure 1 shows the evolution since 1962 of the surplus or deficit in the unified budget and the Congressional Budget Office's (2004b) standardized surplus or deficit.
Both measures clearly show a rise in the deficit relative to GDP in the early and mid1980s, a dramatic correction over the course of the 1990s, and an equally dramatic deterioration since 2000. In fiscal year 2004, the unified deficit is projected to be about 4 percent of GDP, while the standardized surplus is projected to be only slightly smaller.
As the figure shows, deficits of this magnitude are substantial relative to historical norms.
Even so, the current budget situation would not be a concern if future fiscal prospects were auspicious. Unfortunately, the budget outlook is dismal.
The top line of Figure 2 shows CBO’s (2004a) baseline projections for the deficit in the unified budget as of March 2004. The projections assume that the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts expire as scheduled. CBO projects a 10-year baseline unified budget deficit of
$2.0 trillion, or 1.3 percent of GDP, for fiscal years 2005 to 2014, with the deficits shrinking over time and almost disappearing by 2014.
2

The unified budget is not recorded entirely on a cash-flow basis, and so the unified deficit does not precisely match the increase in debt held by the public. For example, only the subsidy cost of direct loan transactions are now recorded in the unified budget. The government must, however, finance the full value of the loan. Therefore, the unified budget deficit (which reflects only the subsidy cost of a direct loan) is smaller than the increase in debt held by the public (which reflects the full value of the direct loan).
3

These include losses due to deposit insurance, receipts from auctions of licenses to use the electromagnetic spectrum, timing adjustments, and contributions of Allied Nations for Operation Desert
Storm (CBO 2004b).

4

Auerbach, Gale, Orszag, and Potter (2003) discuss the relationship between the cash-flow measures, accrual accounting, generational accounting and other ways of measuring the fiscal status of the government. 3

The baseline projection is intended to provide a benchmark for legislative purposes. It is explicitly not intended to be a projection of actual or likely budget outcomes, or a measure of the financial status of the federal government (CBO 2004a).
Thus, adjustments to the baseline are required to generate a more plausible budget scenario and to develop more meaningful measures of the fiscal status of the government.5 One concern is that the baseline holds real discretionary spending constant over time. In a growing economy with an expanding population and evolving security needs, this assumption is not credible. A second concern is that the baseline assumes that all temporary tax provisions expire as scheduled, even though most have been routinely extended in the past.6 A third concern is that the alternative minimum tax grows exponentially under the baseline, a development that few observers regard as plausible.7 Finally, the baseline uses cash-flow accounting, which is appropriate for many programs, but which can distort the financial status of programs with liabilities that increase substantially outside the projection period.
Adjusting for these factors has an enormous impact on 10-year budget projections. Figure 2 shows that if (a) discretionary spending is allowed to grow with inflation and population, (b) the expiring tax provisions that are not related to extension of the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts are extended, and (c) the AMT problem is resolved by indexing the AMT for inflation,8 the adjusted unified budget deficit rises to 2.3 percent of
GDP over the decade and 1.4 percent of GDP in 2014. If, in addition, the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts are made permanent, the adjusted unified deficit would average 3.5 percent of
GDP over the decade and would equal 3.6 percent of GDP (almost $700 billion) in 2014.9
One way to gauge the implications of the adjusted unified baseline is to examine the implied ratio of public debt to GDP, as in Figure 3. Under the adjusted baseline, the
5

See Auerbach, Gale, Orszag, and Potter (2003) for an extended discussion of these issues.

6

The statement regarding past practice refers to a number of provisions (often dubbed “the extenders” and including items such as tax credits for work opportunity or for research and experimentation) that have existed for years, are narrow in scope, have relatively minor budget costs, and for which extensions occur as a matter of routine. The “temporary” provisions having to do with 2001 and 2003 tax cuts are quite different in nature and scope. Whether they are extended is a major fiscal policy choice, not a matter of routine. See Gale and Orszag (2003b) for further discussion of expiring provisions and Gale and Orszag
(2004a) on the effects of making the tax cuts permanent.

7

See Burman, Gale, and Rohaly (2003) for discussion of AMT projections and trends.

8

To distinguish the AMT adjustments required from making the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts permanent from those that would have been required under pre-2001 law, our calculations of the cost of indexing the AMT use pre-2001 law to calculate the cost of indexing the AMT for inflation. The AMT adjustments required from making the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts permanent are counted as part of the cost of making the tax cuts permanent (see Gale and Orszag 2004a).
9

The estimate of the cost of making the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts permanent comes from Gale and Orszag
(2004a) and includes an adjustment to keep the number of AMT taxpayers the same as it would have been under pre-2001 law.

4

debt-GDP ratio would rise steadily throughout the decade and by 2014 would equal 55 percent, well above the most recent high of 49 percent in 1992 and the highest level since
1955. The debt-GDP would continue to rise thereafter.
The ratio of marketable public debt to GDP only tells part of the long-term budget story, however. Social Security, Medicare Part A, and government employee pensions programs are projected to run surpluses over the next decade but face shortfalls in the long term. One way to control for these effects is to examine a 10-year horizon and separate the retirement trust funds from the rest of the budget. For example, Figure 2 shows that omitting retirement funds, the rest of the budget would face deficits of 5.4 percent of GDP over the decade (and 5.4 percent of GDP in 2014) under the assumptions above. An alternative way to incorporate the entitlement trust funds is to extend the time horizon of the analysis so that future shortfalls are included. To do this, we report estimates of the fiscal gap, the size of the immediate and permanent increase in taxes and/or reductions in non-interest expenditures that would be required to establish the same debt-GDP ratio in the long run as holds currently.10 Auerbach, Gale, and Orszag
(2004) estimate that under the adjustments made in Figure 2, the nation faces a long-term fiscal gap in 2004 of 7.1 percent of GDP through 2080 and 10.3 percent of GDP on a permanent basis.11 Gokhale and Smetters (2003) and the Bush Administration (OMB
2004) have made similar projections.
The main drivers of the fiscal gap, under the assumptions made, are the revenue losses from making the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts permanent and the spending growth from
Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security. The recent tax cuts, if extended and not eroded over time by the alternative minimum tax, would cost roughly 2 percent of GDP over the long term (Gale and Orszag 2004a). To help put these figures in context, over the next
75 years, the actuarial deficit in Social Security is 0.7 percent of GDP under the Trustees’ assumptions and 0.4 percent of GDP under new projections issued by CBO (2004c).12
The deficit in Medicare’s Hospital Insurance (Part A) program is 1.4 percent of GDP over the next 75 years. Thus, extending the tax cuts would reduce revenue over the next
75 years by an amount about as large as the entire shortfall in the Social Security and
10

See Auerbach (1994). Over an infinite planning horizon, the requirement is equivalent to assuming that the debt-GDP ratio does not explode. Alternatively, the adjustments set the present value of all future primary surpluses equal to the current value of the national debt, where the primary surplus is the difference between revenues and non-interest expenditures. Auerbach, Gale, Orszag, and Potter (2003) discuss the relationship between the fiscal gap, generational accounting, accrual accounting and other ways of accounting for government.

11

In perhaps more familiar terms, the primary deficit would be 4.1 percent of GDP in 2030, 5.5 percent in
2060 and 5.8 percent by 2080; the unified deficit would rise much faster because of accruing interest payments and would be 13 percent of GDP in 2030, 37 percent by 2060 and 64 percent by 2080. Public debt would be 139 percent of GDP in 2030, 505 percent in 2060 and 942 percent in 2080.

12
The actuarial deficit in Social Security over an infinite horizon amounts to 1.2 percent of GDP under the
Trustees’ assumptions.

5

Medicare Part A trust funds over the same period.
Even if the tax cuts are not made permanent, though, the fiscal gap would be 5.1 percent of GDP through 2080 and 8.2 percent on a permanent basis. A primary reason is substantial projected increases in entitlement costs. Figure 4 shows the projected increases in Social Security, Medicare -- including Part A (Hospital Insurance), Part B
(Supplementary Medicare Insurance) and Part D (Prescription Drug Benefits) -- and
Federal Medicaid costs as a share of GDP over the long term (Auerbach, Gale, and
Orszag 2004). The projected retirement of the baby boomers, ongoing increases in life expectancy, and growth in health care costs per beneficiary that exceed per capita GDP combine to drive Federal expenditures on these three programs from 8.1 percent of GDP in 2004 to a projected 10.2 percent by 2015, 13.3 percent by 2025, and 22.7 percent by
2075. 13 Figure 4 also shows that the vast majority of the growth occurs in the healthrelated programs, not in Social Security. Indeed, after about 2030, Social Security costs are roughly stable relative to GDP. Unfortunately, the health-related programs are much more difficult to reform than Social Security.
To be sure, substantial uncertainty surrounds the short- and long-term budget projections described above. Much of the problem stems from the fact that the surplus or deficit is the difference between two large quantities, taxes and spending. Small percentage errors in either one can cause large percentage changes in the difference between them. Furthermore, small differences in growth rates sustained for extended periods can have surprisingly large economic effects. Variations in assumed health care cost inflation, in particular, can have a substantial effect on the precise projections (CBO
2003). Nonetheless, almost all studies that have examined the issue suggest that even if major sources of uncertainty are accounted for, serious long-term fiscal imbalances will remain.14 III. The Economic Effects of Budget Deficits
A. Traditional Models
Figure 5 provides a summary of the three distinct views of deficits (at least, of deficits created by changes in the timing of lump-sum taxes, holding the path of government purchases constant) described earlier. Under Ricardian Equivalence, private saving rises by the same amount as government saving falls (i.e., by the same amount as the deficit rises), national saving is constant and no further adjustments would be required or expected (Barro 1974).

13

Although it is clear that entitlement spending is a major factor in generating long-term fiscal shortfalls, it is not straightforward to determine how much of the fiscal gap is due to such programs because to a large extent they are supposed to be funded from general revenues. Auerbach, Gale, and Orszag (2004) examine different ways of decomposing the long-term fiscal gap.

14

Lee and Edwards (2001) and Shoven (2002).

6

If private saving rises by less than the full amount that public saving falls, then national saving falls, and further adjustments are required to bring national saving and the sum of domestic and net foreign investment back into balance.15 If private saving does not fully offset the change in public saving, but the flow of capital from overseas is infinitely elastic, the entire quantity adjustment occurs through higher capital inflows. In this case, net foreign investment declines, but the domestic capital stock remains constant. Since the domestic capital stock remains the same, domestic output (Gross
Domestic Product) is constant. Americans' claims on that output, however, decline because the increased borrowing from abroad must be repaid in the future. In other words, the repayments effectively create a mortgage against future national income; as a result, future Gross National Product declines even though Gross Domestic Product is constant.16 Because the capital inflow in this example is assumed to be infinitely elastic, interest rates do not change. Notably, even though interest rates do not change in this scenario, higher deficits still reduce future national income (GNP). We refer to this scenario as the small open economy view.
A third possibility is that the supply of international capital is not infinitely elastic. In this case, the relative price and quantity adjustments are different than under the small open economy model, but the end result -- a decline in future national income -remains the same. In the absence of perfect capital mobility, the reduction in national saving implies a shortage of funds to finance investments given existing interest rates and exchange rates. That imbalance puts upward pressure on interest rates as firms compete for the limited pool of funds to finance investments. The increase in interest rates serves to reduce domestic investment. In a closed economy, the entire adjustment to the reduction in national saving occurs through domestic investment. In an open economy with imperfect capital mobility, the decline in national saving and the resulting rise in interest rates induce some combination of a decline in domestic investment and a decline in net foreign investment (i.e., increases in capital inflows). These changes must be sufficient to ensure that the change in national investment equals the change in national saving. Following Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999), we refer to this scenario as the conventional view.
B. Non-traditional effects
Beyond their direct effect on national saving, future national income, and interest
15

The effects described in the text, in response to a change in the deficit, would occur simultaneously. Our ordering of the discussion is intended merely to provide a way of thinking about the channels through which deficits affect the economy. It does not imply or require that the particular changes discussed occur in some particular order over time.

16

The distinction between domestic investment and net foreign investment is of secondary importance in determining national income (GNP), though it clearly affects domestic income (GDP). Elmendorf and
Mankiw (1999, page 1637) note that “As long as the returns to wealth are the same at home and abroad, the location of the...[change in] wealth does not affect our income… Tomorrow’s national output and income depend on today’s national saving, wherever this saving is ultimately invested.” They also note several caveats to this statement, including differential tax implications of investment abroad relative to investment at home and income distributional implications.

7

rates, deficits can affect the economy in other ways. For example, increased deficits may cause investors gradually to lose confidence in U.S. economic leadership. As Truman
(2001) emphasizes, a substantial fiscal deterioration over the longer-term may cause “a loss of confidence in the orientation of US economic policies...” Such a loss in confidence could then put upward pressure on domestic interest rates, as investors demand a higher risk premium on dollar-denominated assets. The costs of current account deficits -- which are in part induced by large budget deficits -- may even extend beyond narrow economic ones. More broadly, Friedman (1988) notes that, “World power and influence have historically accrued to creditor countries. It is not coincidental that America emerged as a world power simultaneously with our transition from a debtor nation…to a creditor supplying investment capital to the rest of the world.”
Both the traditional models and the non-traditional effects noted above focus on gradual negative effects from reduced national saving. This focus may be too limited, however, in that it ignores the possibility of much more sudden and severe adverse consequences (Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai 2004). In particular, the traditional analysis of budget deficits in advanced economies does not seriously entertain the possibility of explicit default or implicit default through high inflation.17 If market expectations regarding the avoidance of default were to change and investors had difficulty seeing how the policy process could avoid extreme steps, the consequences could be much more severe than traditional estimates suggest. The role of financial market expectations in this type of scenario is central. In particular, one of the key triggers would occur if investors begin to doubt whether the strong historical commitment to avoiding substantial inflation in order to reduce the real value the public debt would be weakened. As Ball and Mankiw (1995, page 117) note, “We can only guess what level of debt will trigger a shift in investor confidence, and about the nature and severity of the effects. Despite the vagueness of fears about hard landings, these fears may be the most important reason for seeking to reduce budget deficits…as countries increase their debt, they wander into unfamiliar territory in which hard landings may lurk. If policymakers are prudent, they will not take the chance of learning what hard landings in G-7 countries are really like.”
Although we do not explicitly incorporate non-traditional effects in our analysis below, they serve as an important reminder of why the effects of deficits, especially chronic deficits, could prove important. Our focus on traditional effects is certainly justifiable in the context of historical analysis of post-war data from United States. That does not imply, however, that ignoring such issues is appropriate when examining the likely impacts of future deficits. The nation has never before faced substantial deficits that are projected to be sustained and indeed grow over many decades.

17

The traditional view also suggests that the exchange rate would either stay constant or appreciate in response to the inflow of capital from abroad. The sign of the exchange rate change, however, is unclear if a country-specific risk premium exists. If that premium increases as a nation’s net international indebtedness (or flow of new international borrowing) increases, the exchange rate could depreciate. In other words, while non-traditional effects are likely to accentuate the impact of deficits on interest rates, they may alter even the sign of the exchange rate dynamics.

8

IV. Preliminary Evidence and Benchmark Calculations
A. A Preliminary Examination of the Data
Figure 6 shows net national saving and net federal government saving as shares of net national product (NNP) since 1950.18 Federal saving has fluctuated significantly over time. The variation in Federal saving is visibly correlated with swings in national saving.
Both series follow a secular decline from 1950 to 1975, rise somewhat in the late 1970s, and then fall through the mid-1980s. The correlation is even more apparent in the last two years. The two series both rise moderately in the mid-1980s, decline from the late
1980s to early 1990s, rise significantly during the 1990s, and then decline again over the past few years. Over the whole period, a regression of national saving on federal saving
(with each expressed as a share of NNP) yields a coefficient of 1.02 (t=7), and a regression of changes in national saving/NNP on changes in federal saving/NNP yields a coefficient of 0.86 (t=9).19
Figure 7 shows net national saving and net domestic investment as a share of net national product (NNP) since 1950.20 The two series follow very similar patterns over time. Domestic investment has declined by less than national saving over the past 20 years and has exceeded national saving in every year since the early 1980s. The difference is reflected in chronic current account deficits (not shown) and a substantial decline in the nation’s net international investment position.21 The decline in national saving over the past few years has been much sharper than the decline in net domestic investment. Between 1998 and 2003, national saving declined by 6 percent of NNP, with about half of the decline made up by increased capital inflows, and half by reduced net domestic investment. A regression of net domestic investment/NNP on net national saving/NNP yields a coefficient of 0.57 (t=15). In first-differences, the coefficient is 0.83
(t=10).
Figure 8 plots annuals observations of the projected 5-year ahead, long-term interest rate on Treasury bonds, and the Congressional Budget Office’s projected deficits

18

Net national saving is defined as gross saving minus depreciation of the capital stock, and is taken from the National Income and Product Accounts Table 5.1, line 2. Net federal saving is defined as gross Federal saving minus depreciation on the Federal government’s physical capital stock and is taken from Table 5.1, line 11.

19

The regressions include a constant, as do the regressions mentioned in the subsequent two paragraphs.

20

Net domestic investment is equal to gross investment minus depreciation of the capital stock, and is taken from the National Income and Product Accounts, Table 5.1, line 31.

21

The current account, as defined by the “net lending” series published by the Bureau of Economic
Analysis, ran a small surplus in 1991, in part because of capital account transactions and in part because of a large statistical discrepancy. The U.S. has gone from being a creditor nation in 1980, with a net international investment position (NIIP) of 10 percent of GDP, to a debtor nation, with a NIIP of about -25 percent of GDP in 2001.

9

as a share of GDP five years ahead.22 Figure 9 shows similar observations for forward long-term rates and projected publicly held debt. Both figures show a clear association between projected fiscal policy outcomes and forward long-term real interest rates. For example, a regression of the forward rate on the 5-year ahead projected ratio of the unified deficit to GDP implies that a one percent of GDP increase in the projected deficit is associated with an increase of the forward rate of about 27 basis points (t=5).
Figures 6-9 suggest a very simple story: Increases in current Federal budget deficits reduce net national saving, which reduces net domestic investment. Increases in projected future federal deficits raise long-term interest rates, which explains how reductions in national saving serve to reduce domestic investment. These patterns are consistent with the conventional view, but not with the Ricardian or small open economy view. A primary goal of the paper is to see robust these simple relationships are to more formal analysis.
B. Magnitude of conventional effects in two simplified models
To generate some intuition about the potential magnitudes involved in the conventional approach, we first follow Shapiro (2004) and examine the effects of sustained budget deficits in the context of the Solow growth model. Based on Mankiw
(2000, page 123), we assume that the economy’s growth rate (n+g) is equal to 3 percent per year, the depreciation rate (δ) is 4 percent per year, and the capital share of output is
30 percent. We also assume that the initial saving rate is 17.5 percent.23 This saving rate, for example, could reflect a private gross saving rate of 20 percent of output and a unified budget deficit of 2.5 percent, which are the values we assume for illustrative purposes.
These assumptions generate an initial steady-state with a capital-output ratio of 2.5 and a gross marginal product of 12 percent, which are reasonable values for the United States
(Table 1).
Now assume that the unified budget deficit rises by 1 percent of output on a sustained basis.24 Suppose that one-quarter of the decline in public saving is offset by an increase in private saving; this response is somewhat more than might be expected based on the data patterns in Figure 6, but somewhat less than the typical estimate we provide below. With this private sector saving response, the budget deficit rises to 3.5 percent of output, private saving rises to 20.25 percent of output, and the national saving rate declines to 16.75 percent.25 Given the reduction in national saving, output per capita in the new steady-state is reduced by 1.9 percent. The marginal product of capital is 54 basis points higher. If we assume that the change in the government borrowing rate is equal to the change in the marginal product of capital, the implication is that the increase
22

The data employed in the figure are described in more detail in section VI and Appendix Table 4.

23

Mankiw assumes a capital-output ratio of 2.5, and then solves for the saving rate. The implied saving rate is 17.5 percent.

24

Note that this simplified model does not impose a government budget constraint.

25

The example assumes a closed economy, so we do not take into account net foreign investment changes.

10

in the unified budget deficit raises the interest rate by 54 basis points.
These results provide one way of calibrating the traditional effects of changes in the budget deficit. Under our base case assumptions, holding other factors constant, a sustained increase in the unified deficit of 1 percent of GDP reduces output by about 2 percent, and raises interest rates by about 50 basis points. If, instead, half of the decline in public saving is offset by an increase in private saving, output per capita falls by 1.2 percent and interest rates rise by 35 basis points. If there is no private saving response, output per capita is reduced by 2.5 percent and the marginal product of capital rises by 73 basis points (Table 1).
The analysis can also be undertaken with regard to the stock variable (government debt) rather than the flow variable (the deficit). In a steady state, the debt-GDP ratio is equal to the unified deficit-GDP ratio divided by the GDP growth rate.26 Assuming a 3 percent growth rate as in the Solow model exercise above, an increase in the unified deficit-GDP ratio of 1 percent of GDP would thus raise the steady-state debt-GDP ratio by approximately 33 percentage points.
To map this increase in the debt-GDP ratio into a change in income and interest rates, we follow the basic contours of the “debt fairy” calculation in Ball and Mankiw
(1995). First, as in the Solow model above, we assume the initial steady-state for the economy involves a capital-output ratio of 2.5. The change in the capital-output ratio depends on how much of the debt increase is offset by increased private capital accumulation; as in the base case above, we assume a 25 percent offset. The reduction in capital is thus equal to 25 percent (=33*0.75) of initial GDP. Assuming a marginal product of capital equal to 12 percent, the reduction in the capital stock causes income to decline by about 3 percent. Second, to map the change in the capital-output ratio into a change in the marginal product of capital, a specific form of the aggregate production function is necessary. With a Cobb-Douglas production function, the percentage increase in the marginal product of capital is equal to the percentage decline in the capital-output ratio. The capital-output ratio falls by 7 percent, from 2.50 to 2.32. The marginal product of capital would thus rise by 7 percent, from 12.0 to 12.8. Finally, we again assume that the change in the long-term government borrowing rate is equal to the change in the marginal product of capital. The debt perspective thus suggests that a sustained increase in the unified deficit equal to 1 percent of GDP would reduce income by 3 percent and raise steady-state long-term interest rates by about 80 basis points.
Thus, the deficit exercise and the debt exercise are basically consistent: A sustained increase in the unified deficit equal to one percent of GDP would reduce income by 2 to 3 percent and raise long-term interest rates by roughly 50 to 80 basis points under the base-case assumptions.

26

If the unified deficit is a constant share of GDP, then (rD+p)/Y=k, where r is the interest rate, D is government debt, p is the primary budget balance, and Y is GDP. A constant debt-GDP ratio requires that
D grow at rate g, or that (rD+p)/D=g, where g is the growth rate of Y. Therefore, in a steady state with a constant debt-GDP ratio, D/Y=k/g.

11

To be sure, it is challenging to move from these simplified models to real-world results. The models, for example, effectively assume a closed economy. The U.S. economy, however, is usually considered large and open. One would therefore expect capital inflows to mitigate the interest rate and domestic production effects to some degree, even though the effect on national income should be largely unaffected by the assumption of a closed economy.
Another key consideration is that the results above consider only the effects of increased budget deficits or debt per se. A full analysis of the effects of public policies on economic growth should take into account not only the effects of increased deficits and debt, but also the direct effects of the spending programs or tax reductions that cause them. The effects of fiscal policies on both economic performance and interest rates depend not only on the deficit but also on the specific elements of the policies generating that deficit. For example, spending $1 on public investment projects would increase the unified budget deficit by $1, but the net effect on future income would depend on whether the return on the public investment project exceeded the return on the private capital that would have instead been financed by the national saving crowded out by the deficit. Similarly, a deficit of one percent of GDP caused by reducing marginal tax rates will generally have different implications for both national income and interest rates than a deficit of one percent of GDP caused by increasing government purchases of goods and services. We return to this issue in the conclusion.
V. Deficits and Consumption
Our goal in measuring the effects of fiscal policy on consumption is to distinguish the Ricardian view from the other two views. A wide variety of research tends to reject various indirect implications of Ricardian Equivalence. For example, previous studies have generally found that: motives for bequests are neither universal nor purely altruistic; consumer spending responds to temporary tax cuts; anticipated changes in income do not affect consumption until the changes actually occur (although there is mixed evidence on this point); and aggregate consumption is sensitive to the age distribution of the population.27 We focus on a different set of tests: those using aggregate time-series data to examine the impact of tax revenues on consumption, holding other factors constant.
Despite the numerous rejections of Ricardian Equivalence in the indirect tests noted above, the time has come to revisit the aggregate time-series effects of fiscal policy on consumption for several reasons. First, these analyses provide a direct test of whether the timing of tax collections affects the economy, controlling for other factors. Second, the aggregate time series tests provide a direct measure of the magnitude of the effects in question. This is particularly important because virtually no one claims that Ricardian
Equivalence is literally true. Rather, the controversy is over the extent to which
Ricardian Equivalence is a good approximation of the aggregate impact of fiscal policies.
The indirect tests noted above can be helpful in distinguishing whether the literal
27

See, for example, the discussion in Bernheim (1987), Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999) and Seater (1993).

12

implications of Ricardian Equivalence hold, but they are often uninformative about the quantitative importance of any particular rejection of the theory. Third, there has been little work on these issues using data beyond the early 1990s. The past 10 years, however, have witnessed dramatic fiscal policy shifts in both directions. These shifts have raised the prominence of policy concerns about budget deficits, and should provide useful variation from an econometric perspective. Fourth, despite the rejection of many of the indirect implications of Ricardian Equivalence noted above, at least some lines of previous research using aggregate time series data has proven somewhat more favorable to the Ricardian view. This may be due to problems that are unique to time-series analysis, but it may also be that Ricardian Equivalence is more robust -- in particular as a working approximation -- than the indirect tests suggest.
A. Previous Research
Authors of earlier literature surveys note the wide variety of research findings from studies of aggregate consumption and fiscal policy, and emphasize the daunting econometric problems inherent in such studies, but come to different conclusions about what the literature shows. Barro (1989) and Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999) conclude the literature is inconclusive. Seater (1993) concludes that once the studies are corrected for econometric problems, Ricardian Equivalence is corroborated -- or at least that it is not possible to reject Ricardian Equivalence. Bernheim (1989) concludes that once the studies are normalized appropriately, Ricardian Equivalence should be rejected.
Previous studies of the effects of fiscal policy on consumption have taken three general approaches. A variety of studies provide reduced form analysis of consumption and saving patterns in United States and other countries.28 Like figures 6 and 7 above, these studies generally appear to support non-Ricardian interpretations of the data.
A second strand of the literature, and by far the largest segment, specifies consumption functions and then tests for the effects of fiscal policy given the consumption function (Feldstein 1982, Seater and Marianno 1985, Kormendi, 1983).
Perhaps the best-known study in this area is Kormendi (1983), who finds no evidence of non-Ricardian effects. This work has spawned significant research, including three sets of exchanges in the American Economic Review. At the risk of oversimplifying, the work of Kormendi (1983) and Kormendi and MeGuire (1986, 1990, 1995) has survived the challenges well enough to continue to serve as the bulwark of empirical evidence for the
Ricardian view of the world (as in, for example, the survey by Seater 1993).29
28

See, for example, Summers (1985), Carroll and Summers (1987), Poterba and Summers (1986, 1987), and Serres and Pelgrin (2003).

29

A comprehensive review of the literature following Kormendi (1983) is beyond the scope of this paper, but some highlights include the following. Barth, Iden, and Russek (1986) update the data, correct some data problems, and obtain results broadly similar to Kormendi (1983). Modigliani and Sterling (1986) argue that Kormendi's results are flawed because of data problems, a failure to distinguish temporary and permanent taxes, and inappropriate first-differencing of the data. They develop an aggregate consumption function derived from the life-cycle model that contains Ricardian Equivalence as a special case. Their empirical results show strongly non-Ricardian results. Kormendi and MeGuire (1986) note significant

13

A third strand of the literature focuses on Euler equation tests. There have been very few Euler equation tests of Ricardian Equivalence. Aschauer (1985) examines the effects of fiscal policy assuming utility maximization and rational expectations, but his model does not nest a non-Ricardian specification (Bernheim 1987, Graham and
Himarios 1991). Graham and Himarios (1991) nest Ricardian and non-Ricardian views in a model that builds off of Hayashi (1982) and find non-Ricardian results using a nonlinear instrumental variables procedure. A substrand of the literature aims to test the
Blanchard (1985) model, which nests Ricardian and non-Ricardian alternatives. Evans
(1988, 1993) and Evans and Hasan (1994) obtain results that are generally consistent with
Ricardian Equivalence, while Graham and Himarios (1996) correct several data and econometric issues in Evans’ work and find strong non-Ricardian effects.
The relative value of consumption function versus Euler equation approaches is a recurring theme in the literature. The advantage of using the Euler equation approach is that Ricardian equivalence requires a combination of utility maximization and rational expectations that can be explicitly incorporated in the Euler equation. The disadvantage is that Euler equation models can (and do) fail for reasons unrelated to Ricardian
Equivalence, and Ricardian Equivalence can fail in ways that do not affect the Euler equation (Bernheim 1987).
Flavin (1987) argues that the consumption function approach is fundamentally inconsistent with Ricardian Equivalence and therefore can not be used to test the theory. On the other hand, the strongest evidence in favor of Ricardian
Equivalence comes from the consumption function studies by Kormendi (1983) and
Kormendi and MeGuire (1986, 1990), which Seater (1993) claims is the best available evidence on the issue. Rather than attempting to resolve this debate, we estimate both consumption function and Euler equation models. We also show that the two specifications are closely related, so that the difference between them in practice may not be large, even though the conceptual frameworks are quite different.

problems with how Modigliani and Sterling have defined temporary taxes. They show that imposing the condition that taxes and transfers have effects of equal magnitude and opposite sign (as Modigliani and
Sterling do) is not supported by the data, and that when the restriction is released, taxes and government debt continue to have Ricardian effects. Feldstein and Elmendorf (1990) work within the Kormendi framework and evaluate the effects of removing war years, extending the sample, other specification changes, and instrumenting for endogenous explanatory variables. After reproducing Kormendi's estimates, they find that their extensions fundamentally alter the findings, and obtain very strong nonRicardian results. Kormendi and MeGuire (1990), however, show that Feldstein and Elmendorf's results only obtain as the joint consequence of using what they view as the wrong deflators and failing to incorporate the improved definitions of variables that came out of the 1986 exchanges. Graham (1995) makes two adjustments to the Kormendi and MeGuire framework, extended to 1991. He allows state and local variables to have different effects than federal variables. He also claims that theory suggests that labor and capital income should have distinct effects and proposes a decomposition of aggregate income and taxes into those due to labor and those due to capital. His re-estimates suggest some non-Ricardian results, but not for tax revenues. Kormendi and MeGuire (1995) challenge the decomposition of income into labor and capital and show that an alternative definition generates Ricardian results.

14

B. Consumption Function Specification
Our consumption function specification replicates, updates and extends the work by Kormendi and MeGuire and their critics. Kormendi (1983) specifies an aggregate consumption function of the form:
(1)

Ct = α0 + α11Yt + α12Yt-1 + α2GSt + α3Wt + α4TRt + α5TXt + α6REt + α7GINTt + α8GBt + εt,

where t indexes time periods; C is a measure of consumption; Y is net national product;
W is a measure of private net worth, not including government debt; GS is government purchases of goods and services; TR is government transfer payments; TX is tax revenue;
RE is corporate retained earnings; GINT is government interest payments; and GB is outstanding value of government debt.
Ricardian and Non-Ricardian Hypotheses Although the equation is not specified in a structural manner, Kormendi (1983) argues that this framework nests both Ricardian and non-Ricardian hypotheses. The Ricardian view is that consumption depends on current wealth, expected future income, and the burdens imposed by government purchases. If current and lagged NNP serve as proxies for future income, then the expected coefficients on NNP and lagged NNP should be between zero and one.
Likewise, in this formulation, the coefficient on wealth represents the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth.
Current government purchases is intended to be a proxy for expected future government purchases. The key point, however, is that even if current purchases are an accurate proxy for expected future purchases, the coefficient does not provide a test of
Ricardian Equivalence. Ricardian Equivalence is a statement about how variations in the timing of taxation affect consumption, holding expected purchases constant. It has no necessary implications for the effects of purchases on consumption, since the items the government purchases could be substitutes or complements for private consumption.30
Thus, while it is important to control for expected government purchases, the coefficient on the purchases variable does not provide information that can test the theory.
Instead, the central tests between Ricardian and non-Ricardian views have to do with the coefficients on current taxes and current transfers. Ricardian equivalence implies that α4 = α5 = 0; that is, that transfers and taxes should not affect consumption, given the path of government purchases. The values of these coefficients, if they are not

30

Kormendi (1983) obtains a negative coefficient on government purchases and interprets this finding as evidence in favor of Ricardian Equivalence. Kormendi and MeGuire (1990), however, acknowledge that the coefficient on government spending is essentially uninformative in testing Ricardian and non-Ricardian views. 15

zero, provide a quantitative measure of the extent to which Ricardian equivalence fails as a description of reality.31
Of course, Ricardian equivalence also implies that α8 = 0; that is, that government bonds are not treated as net wealth by consumers.32 Although this channel for nonRicardian effects has attracted an enormous amount of attention over the past several decades, it is unlikely to be the major channel through which non-Ricardian effects occur.
For example, Poterba and Summers (1987) and Evans (1991) show that, if Ricardian
Equivalence is violated solely because forward-looking, life-cycle consumers treat government bonds completely as net worth, the effects of fiscal policy on short-run consumption are likely to be small. In addition, as discussed further below, there are both data and conceptual problems with interpreting the government bonds (and wealth) variables. As a result, we do not emphasize this channel for testing between the different models. Data Details on the data construction are provided in Appendix Table 1. All of the variables are first transformed into real, per capita levels. To deal with stationarity issues, Kormendi and MeGuire (1990) and Feldstein and Elmendorf (1990) estimate regressions in first differences of the levels and in first differences of the ratios of each term divided by NNP per capita. Following Campbell and Mankiw (1990), we also adjust for stationarity a third way, dividing the first differences in the levels by lagged
NNP per capita.33
We use two measures of consumption. The first is the one developed by
Kormendi (1983): expenditures on non-durables and services, plus 10 percent of current durable expenditures plus 30 percent of the existing stock of durable goods. The second measure is the more common nondurables plus services used in many studies of aggregate consumption.
The wealth variable used in Kormendi (1983), Kormendi and MeGuire (1990) and other papers in this literature is an amalgam of different series with several extrapolations. Instead, we use data on household wealth from the Federal Reserve
Board's Flow of Funds. We use household net worth rather than private net worth, because the household measure contains the market value of corporate equities held by
31

Note, however, that there is an inconsistency in the specification in that current levels of government purchases are intended to proxy for permanent levels, but current levels of taxes and transfers are not intended to proxy for permanent levels of those items.

32

The coefficients on government interest payments and retained earnings should be zero under Ricardian equivalence, but this test is not particularly interesting, because the coefficients should also be zero under other hypotheses. For example, the view that households pierce the corporate veil suggests that retained earnings should not affect consumption. Likewise, if government interest payments accrue mainly to highincome households who tend to save the funds, they will not affect consumption.

33

Campbell and Mankiw (1990) divide by lagged disposable income, rather than NNP, but the difference is unimportant empirically. We divide by NNP in order to maintain consistency with the first difference in ratio specification.

16

households, whereas the private sector measure removes those values and replaces them with book values of corporate equity. Since we want to capture the influence of wealth on consumption, we believe that the market value of equities is the more appropriate measure to include. Likewise, for data on the market value of government bonds, we use updated and unified data from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. For state data, we use the same methodology as Seater (1981), but we obtain more recently available data.
Generally, the data under the new definitions track the data under the old definitions very closely for the years in which values of both are present.34
With these specifications, we have almost exactly the specification employed by
Kormendi (1983) and Kormendi and MeGuire (1986, 1990, 1995). In earlier work (Gale and Orszag 2003c), we almost exactly replicate their results for earlier time periods dating from as far back as 1931 up to 1992.
Extending the Kormendi-MeGuire Approach Our analysis here focuses on three extensions of this framework. First, we extend the sample period to 2002. The added 10 years of data provide valuable variation in fiscal policy and national saving.
Second, we alter the treatment of government taxes and transfers. In the
Kormendi specification, all government variables (taxes, transfers, purchases, interest payments, and debt) represent the combined values of federal, state, and local governments. But Federal and state variables are likely to have different effects on aggregate consumption. First, states face balanced budget rules, which implies that the cyclical dynamics of changes in state taxes or spending may be different than for federal taxes or spending, which implies in turn that the behavioral response to such changes might be different. Second, to the extent that state and local taxes are capitalized into local real estate prices, they are likely to have different effects than federal taxes.
Perhaps most importantly, the states collect a significant share of their revenue through consumption taxes, which would be expected to vary positively with consumption, whereas other taxes would be expected, at least in non-Ricardian theory, to vary negatively.35 At the very least, tests of the robustness of the results to specifications that allow for independent effects of federal and state variables are a reasonable specification check. Third, in some specifications, we include a marginal tax rate as a control variable.

34

The data from the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas appears to follow the same procedures as those developed in Cox (1985). The market value of state debt is calculated by multiplying the outstanding par value of state and local bonds (taken from the Statistical Abstract of the United States) by the ratio of market to par value for municipal bonds (taken from Standard and Poors 2003).

35

Likewise, state and federal governments typically allocate their purchases of goods and services differently, with a large share of federal purchases going to defense, while state purchases are dedicated more to education, police and health care.
The balanced budget rules also imply that state debt may be paid off at a different rate than federal debt, which again could influence behavior. Finally, mobility across states is much higher than emigration out of the United States; the basic Ricardian story does not hold when individuals (and their offspring) can escape the future burden of taxation by moving.

17

Not controlling for marginal tax rates probably biases the tax coefficient toward a
Ricardian outcome. For example, holding government spending constant, lump sum taxes are cut. The conventional view is that consumption rises (saving rises by less than the full amount of the tax cut). The Ricardian view is that consumption is not affected
(saving rises by the full amount of the tax cut). Both views, though, allow that a cut in marginal tax rates could raise labor income or saving. Thus, the same tax cut, enacted through cuts in marginal tax rates rather than lump sum taxes, would raise saving by more than would a lump sum tax cut, in either model. (It will also raise labor supply, but recall that the equations control for net national product.) Thus, the coefficient on the revenue variable will be biased in a pro-Ricardian direction if the marginal tax rate is not controlled for.
Almost all previous studies of Ricardian Equivalence omit marginal tax rates except for Seater and Mariano (1981) and even they omit corporate tax rates. Seater
(1993) suggests that any bias arising from the omission of marginal tax rates is not important. Barro (1989,), Bernheim (1989), Plosser (1987) and others believe that controlling for marginal tax rates is essential. This view is buttressed by the work of
Judd (1985, 1987a, 1987b) and Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) who show that the shortterm dynamics of tax cuts are strongly affected by private responses to marginal tax incentives. Notably, a number of these papers emphasize the importance of including a broad-based measure of taxation. Accordingly, we include a measure of the average economy-wide marginal effective tax rate on new capital investment, as determined in
Gravelle (1994) and updated through 2002 in Gravelle (2004).36
C. Consumption Function Results
Table 2 shows ordinary least squares results for the specification above. We estimate regressions for three time periods, two measures of consumption, three transformations of the dependent variable, and three specifications of the explanatory variables. The first panel follows the Kormendi and MeGuire (1990) specification of explanatory variables. In the first part of the panel (with estimates in first-difference form), the second column shows that when the sample is restricted to 1954-1992, consumption does not respond to changes in taxes in a statistically significant fashion.
This finding replicates and confirms the basic Kormendi and MeGuire (1990) estimates.
The first column, however, shows that merely updating the data through 2002 alters the conclusion, even with no further changes in specification. When the data are updated through 2002, the coefficient on the tax variable implies that controlling for other factors, between 27 and 39 percent of a tax cut is spent in the year it occurs, whereas the
Ricardian benchmark would be zero and the pure Keynesian benchmark would be close to 100 percent. These conclusions are not particularly sensitive to the starting point for the data (not shown), but they are sensitive to the ending date. In particular, the third column shows that the statistical significance of the tax coefficient is dependent on
36

We thank Jane Gravelle for updating the series on a timely basis.

18

including 2001 and 2002. This sensitivity to excluding 2001 and 2002 is not present when the specification is improved, as shown below. The other specifications in the first panel (with different transformations of the dependent variable) yield similar though slightly weaker results.
The second panel splits federal and state tax variables, for reasons noted above.
This has several effects on the results. First, the absolute value of the coefficients and tstatistics on Federal taxes is larger than were the corresponding items for all taxes in the first panel. The estimates suggest that between 25 and 46 cents of every dollar in federal tax cuts is consumed in the first year, controlling for other factors. Second, the statistical significance of the results are no longer sensitive to whether the last two years are included. Third, although not shown for the regressions in the second panel, the coefficients on the state tax variables are positive, large and precisely estimated. This buttresses the view that federal and state taxes can have different effects on the economy, and it points out an important source of aggregation bias (between federal and state tax revenues) in previous work on this subject.37
The third panel shows the results when the tax variables are split between Federal and state components and when the marginal tax rate on capital income is included. The regressions are now strongly non-Ricardian, regardless of the time period employed, the consumption measure, or the transformation employed. The estimates suggest that between 32 and 53 cents of every dollar of tax cuts is spent in the year of the tax cut.
These coefficients are statistically different from the Ricardian value of zero.
Table 3 reports coefficient estimates for the six regressions in the third panel of table 2 that include the marginal tax rate on capital and cover the full sample period
(1954-2002). Several results are worth highlighting. The coefficients on NNP and lagged NNP are similar to those reported by Kormendi and MeGuire (1990).
Government purchases enter with a small, positive, statistically insignificant coefficient.38
The contrast between the effects of federal and state taxes is stark. State taxes enter with a positive, precisely estimated coefficient that hovers around 1.0. Government transfers always have a positive effect that is usually significant.39 The marginal tax rate on capital generally enters with a positive, statistically significant, but economically small, effect.
The coefficient on government bonds is negative and insignificant in each of the specifications. It is difficult to interpret this result, however, in light of the fact that the private wealth coefficient is also small and usually insignificant.
One possible issue in all of these equations is that Ricardian consumers should care about expected future government purchases. The specification in (1) assumes that
37

The results are similar when all the fiscal variables, not just taxes, are split into Federal and state components (not shown).
38

In Gale and Orszag (2003c), we show that in earlier time periods, the coefficient on the purchases variable is larger and precisely estimated, consistent with other results in the literature.

39

In the regressions that exclude the marginal tax rate on capital, the transfer coefficient is always large and statistically significant.

19

the current change in government purchases is a good proxy for the future change in government purchases. We have run regressions with future government purchases entered instead of current values, and with CBO projections of five-year-ahead government spending. In both cases, the added variables had very small, imprecisely estimated coefficients and had trivial effects on the other coefficients in the model.
In summary, the results above demonstrate that, within the framework that has been viewed by supporters of Ricardian Equivalence as providing the most credible evidence in their favor, updated data and an improved specification reveal robust nonRicardian effects. The evidence using these updated and improved specifications suggests that about 40 to 50 cents of every dollar in Federal tax cuts in spent in the same year. Nevertheless, there are significant concerns with this specification. Most notably, the equations are not derived from a well-defined economic model, and many of the key explanatory variables are likely to be endogenous. While it is possible to use instrumental variable techniques to remove endogeneity, such an effort raises special problems in the consumption function approach (see Flavin 1987) and there are a very large number of potentially endogenous variables in the consumption function specification above. For these reasons, we turn to Euler equations, which we estimate in both ordinary least squares and instrumental variable forms.
D. Euler Equation Specification
This section develops an Euler equation specification that nests Ricardian and non-Ricardian alternatives. In the standard specification, permanent-income consumers adjust their consumption in each period so that the marginal utility of consumption follows a random walk (Hall 1978). With a few simplifying assumptions, consumption itself follows a random walk, which implies that the change in consumption is unpredictable, or that
(2)

∆Ct = α + εt,

where εt is a forecast error that is uncorrelated with all information in periods t-1 and before but may be correlated with current-period information.
Our goal is to expand on the model in (2) to account explicitly for Ricardian consumers, and consumers who exhibit any of a variety of types of non-Ricardian behavior. Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990) specify a model in which a share (λ) of all disposable income (YD) goes to rule-of-thumb consumers who immediately consume the resources. The remainder of income accrues to “far-sighted” consumers, who behave according to (2). This generates a consumption equation of the form:
(3)

∆Ct = α + λ*∆YDt + (1- λ)*εt.

20

Blanchard (1985) develops a model of far-sighted, life-cycle consumers that also contains Ricardian Equivalence as a special case (where consumers have an infinite horizon). Based on Blanchard (1985), Evans (1988), and Graham and Himarios (1996), the model implies that aggregate consumption can be written as:
(4)

∆Ct = α + β1*∆Wt-1 + β2*∆Bt-1 + v1t,

where W is private net worth and B is the real outstanding stock of government bonds.
As shown in Evans (1988), life-cycle consumers will generate negative values for β1 and β2. In the limiting case of Ricardian equivalence, β1 and β2 are zero and the equation collapses to (2). This, if a proportion µ1 (µ2) of private wealth (government bonds) is held by life-cycle consumers and the remaining share is held by Ricardian consumers, equations (3) and (4) can be combined to allow for both rule-of-thumb and life-cycle consumers: (5)

∆Ct = α + λ*∆YDt + γ1*∆Wt-1 + γ2*∆Bt-1 + v2t,

where γi = β1 µi.
Finally, Ricardian consumers should not be influenced by changes in disposable income or past changes in wealth, but they may be affected by changes in expectations regarding future government purchases (although as noted above, the sign of the effect is not clear). Moreover, for all groups, with the possible exception of strict rule-of-thumb consumers, changes in the marginal tax rate may affect consumption choices. These considerations generate an Euler specification of the following form:
(6)

∆Ct = α + λ*∆YDt + γ1*∆Wt-1 + γ2*∆Bt-1 + φ1*∆GS + φ2*∆MTR + ut,

where ut is uncorrelated with all variables in earlier time periods.
The Euler equation (6) has a number of interesting properties. First, it allows for the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers and life-cycle consumers, and contains
Ricardian equivalence as the special case, where λ = γ1 = γ2 = 0. These restrictions derive directly from the Blanchard (1985) and Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990) models.
Thus, the equation allows for testing of Ricardian equivalence in a utility-maximizing framework that nests both Ricardian and several non-Ricardian hypotheses and also shows the quantitative importance of any deviations from Ricardian Equivalence.
Second, with a little transformation, the equation is not that different from the consumption function specification developed by Kormendi (1983) and reported in equation (1). In the notation of section B above, disposable income can be written as YD
= NNP – TX – RE + TR + GINT. When that expression is substituted into (5) and the coefficients on each component of disposable income are allowed to vary, the resulting equation differs from equation (1) only in that (1) contains a lagged NNP term.

21

To isolate the effects of federal taxes on consumption, we decompose the disposable income term in (6) into pre-tax income (YP), federal taxes, and state and local taxes. This yields equation (7), which is estimated by OLS and instrumental variables in the next section:
(7) ∆Ct = α + λ1*∆YPt + λ2*∆TXFt + λ3*∆TXSLt + γ1*∆Wt-1 + γ2*∆Bt-1 + φ1*∆GS + φ2*∆MTR + ut.
E. Euler Equation Results
Table 4 presents estimates of (7). The first panel presents ordinary least squares regressions, for comparison with Table 2. The results using first differences and first differences scaled by lagged income are somewhat smaller than those in Table 2, and suggest that between 22 and 44 cents of each dollar in federal tax cuts is consumed in the year the tax cuts occur. The results using the first difference in ratios are substantially larger, suggesting that between 65 and 80 cents per dollar of tax cuts are consumed in the first year. Thus, the results show no obvious bias relative to the findings in Table 2.
These results, of course, still suffer from endogeneity problems. The direction of the bias created from endogenous explanatory variables is unclear on a priori basis.
Barro (1989) claims it biases findings against Ricardian Equivalence. Bernheim (1987) claims it biases findings in favor of Ricardian Equivalence. Cardia (1997) shows that removing the endogeneity of income has a crucial impact on the ability of regressions to isolate an effect of taxes or bonds on consumption.
As Campbell and Mankiw (1989) note, any lagged stationary variable is a valid instrument, provided it predicts the right-hand-side variable well. We follow Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990) in using lagged values of the right-hand-side variables as instruments for their current value, and lagged values of consumption itself as an instrument for current income. In models where agents are forward-looking, lagged consumption will help to predict current income, but is not correlated with the stochastic component of current consumption. For reasons discussed in Hall (1988), Campbell and
Mankiw (1989) and elsewhere, we avoid using once-lagged variables as instruments, and instead use variables that are lagged twice and three times.
Table 4 reports the instrumental variable estimates. In the equations that exclude the marginal tax rate on capital, we instrument for current gross income, federal taxes, state taxes, and government purchases. In the equations that include the marginal tax rate, the lagged values are used as instruments and the current value is instrumented.
The results are shown in the bottom panel of Table 4. and provide strong support for non-Ricardian views. Of the 12 regressions, 10 report large and precisely estimated negative effects of current taxes on aggregate consumption, controlling for other factors.
All six regressions that do not control for the marginal tax rate on capital find large negative effects, ranging from 50 to 81 percent of the tax cut being consumed in the first year. In the regressions that control for the tax rate, the specifications that use first

22

differences, or first differences scaled for lagged income report results in roughly the same range – 44 to 82 percent. The only exception is that the equations using first differences of ratios generate estimates of about 31 to 36 cents, which are not statistically significant. F. Summary
The OLS regressions demonstrate robust non-Ricardian effects even within the basic specification that has previously suggested the strongest support for Ricardian
Equivalence. When the sample period is extended, Federal and state tax variables are split, and a marginal tax rate variable is included, the results suggest that about 40 to 50 cents of every dollar in tax cuts in spent in the same year.
The OLS regressions likely suffer from severe simultaneity problems, however.
When IV regressions are used in the Euler specification, with twice- and three-times lagged variables as instruments, the results are generally more strongly non-Ricardian.
The coefficients from this specification, which is our preferred one, suggest that a range of about 50 to 80 cents of every dollar in tax cuts is spent in the first year. This range is consistent with some previous assessments,40 but it is inconsistent with the Ricardian prediction of a full offset from private saving and the difference, as discussed further in the conclusion, is economically important.
VI. Deficits and Interest Rates
A. Previous Research
For a number of well-known reasons, the effects of fiscal policy on interest rates have proven difficult to pin down statistically. The issues include the appropriate definition of deficits and debt, whether deficits or debt should be the variable of interest, the difficulty of distinguishing expected and unexpected changes, and the potential endogeneity of many of the key explanatory variables. We discuss many of these issues below; Bernheim (1987), Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999), and Seater (1993) provide comprehensive analyses. In part because of these statistical issues, the evidence from the empirical literature as a whole is mixed.41
40

For example, Bernheim (1987) and the Congressional Budget Office (1998) conclude that private saving would rise by between 20 and 50 percent of an increase in the deficit (i.e., consumption would rise by between 50 and 80 percent of the increase in the deficit). Elmendorf and Liebman (2000) conclude that that private saving would offset 25 percent of the increase in the deficit. Gale and Potter (2002) estimate that private saving will offset 31 percent of the decline in public saving caused by the 2001 tax cut.
41

Previous analyses reach widely varying conclusions about the effects of deficits on interest rates. For example, Barth et. al (1991) surveys 42 studies through 1989, of which 17 found a “predominately significant, positive” effect of deficits on interest rates (that is, larger deficits raised interest rates); 6 found mixed effects; and 19 found “predominately insignificant or negative” effects. Barth et al (1991) conclude that “Since the available evidence on the effects of deficits is mixed, one cannot say with complete confidence that budget deficits raise interest rates…But, equally important, one cannot say that they do not have these effects. Other reviewers of the literature have reached similar conclusions. Elmendorf and
Mankiw (1999) note that “Our view is that this literature...is not very informative.” Bernheim (1989)

23

Projected deficits and interest rates Our contribution to interpreting the literature has been to highlight the key role of using expected deficits rather than current deficits
(Gale and Orszag 2002, Gale and Orszag 2003a).42 As Feldstein (1986a) has written, “it is wrong to relate the rate of interest to the concurrent budget deficit without taking into account the anticipated future deficits. It is significant that almost none of the past empirical analyses of the effect of deficits on interest rates makes any attempt to include a measure of expected future deficits.” Since financial markets are forward-looking, excluding deficit expectations could bias the analysis toward finding no relationship between interest rates and deficits.43
Studies that incorporate more accurate information on expectations of future sustained deficits tend to find economically and statistically significant connections between anticipated deficits and current interest rates. Gale and Orszag (2003a) combine the papers reviewed in Barth et. al. (1991) with more recent papers. Appendix Table 3 shows that of the 19 papers incorporating timely information on projected deficits, 13 find predominantly positive, significant effects between anticipated deficits and current interest rates, 5 find mixed effects, and only one finds no effects. The studies that find no significant effect are disproportionately those that do not take expectations into account at all or do so only indirectly through a vector auto-regression. Thus, while the literature as a whole, taken at face value, generates mixed results, the literature that focuses on the effects of anticipated deficits tends to find a positive and significant impact on interest rates. The challenge in incorporating market expectations about future deficits is that such expectations are not directly observable. Researchers have used different strategies in the face of this challenge. One approach is to use published forecasts of the deficit as a proxy for market expectations. To the extent this proxy is imperfect, the coefficient on the projected deficit will tend to be biased toward zero because of classical measurement error. This bias would reduce the estimated impact of deficits on interest rates.
As some examples of this approach, Elmendorf (1993) uses deficit forecasts from
Data Resources, Inc., and finds that an increase in the projected deficit of one percent of
GNP raises five-year bond yields by 43 basis points. Canzoneri, Cumby, and Diba
(2002) use CBO projected surpluses and find that an increase in projected future deficits writes that “it is easy to cite a large number of studies that support any conceivable position.” Appendix
Table 3 updates the Barth et. al (1991) survey and shows that of more than 60 studies, roughly half found a predominately significant, positive effect and the other half found either no effect or mixed effects.
42

One recent study expands the literature along a different dimension: Kiley (2003) examines the relationship between current government debt and the return to capital in the nonfinancial corporate sector.
Kiley finds that a one percentage point increase in the debt-GDP ratio is associated with a 10 basis point increase in the return to capital.
43

Bernheim (1987) notes that if households perfectly anticipated future deficits, one may well find no empirical relationship between the current deficits and interest rates, even though the path of interest rates and economic activity would be substantially different in the absence of the deficits.

24

averaging one percent of current GDP is associated with an increase in the long-term interest rate relative to the short-term interest rate of 53 to 60 basis points.
Laubach (2003) uses CBO and OMB projections and finds that a one percentage point increase in the projected deficit-to-GDP ratio raises forward long-term interest rates by between 24 and 40 basis points and that a one percentage point in the projected debtto-GDP ratio raises long-term rates by 3.5-5.5 basis points. Laubach’s work is important because it proposes a novel and sensible solution to one concern about several of the previous studies: that the business cycle could be affecting both projected deficits and yield spreads.44 To mitigate such problems, Laubach examines the relationship between projected deficits (or debt) and the level of real forward (5-year ahead) long-term interest rates. Following Laubach, Engen and Hubbard (2004) use CBO projections and find that an increase in the projected deficit equal to one percent of GDP raises long-term rates (either the current long-term rate or the forward long-term rate) by between 18 and
24 basis points. They also find that an increase in the projected debt equal to one percent of GDP raises long-term rates by between 2.8 and 3.3 basis points. The debt-based result is not too dissimilar from the deficit-based results. Consider, for example, an increase in the budget deficit equal to one percent of GDP in each year over the next 10 years. After
10 years, that would raise government debt by roughly 10 percent of GDP. The deficitbased results from Engen-Hubbard would suggest an increase in long-term rates of roughly 20 basis points. The debt-based results would suggest an increase of roughly 30 basis points (ten times the effect for an increase of one percent of GDP).
A second approach to incorporating expected deficits involves “event analysis” of news reports about deficit reduction legislation or budget projections. This approach examines the change in interest rates (or other variables) on the day in which deficit news is released. For example, Elmendorf (1996) examines financial market reactions to events surrounding passage of the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings legislation in 1985 and the
Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 and concludes “higher expected government spending and budget deficits raised real interest rates…while lower expected spending and deficits reduced real rates.”45 Unfortunately, given the inability to measure market expectations, this approach does not yield a mapping between the size of the unanticipated deficit and the interest rate effect.46
44

For example, in a recession, the projected unified deficit could increase merely because of the lingering effects from the rise in debt during the downturn; at the same time, the yield curve could steepen as shortterm interest rates are depressed by Federal Reserve policy. This could potentially introduce an artificial relationship, actually driven by the business cycle and monetary policy, between the yield spread and the projected unified deficit.
45

The Council of Economic Advisers (1994) studies the events surrounding passage of the Omnibus
Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993. Its concludes that event analysis “linking the announcement and enactment of credible budget reduction to changes in the long-term interest rate provides support for the view that the interest rate declines were largely due to budget policy.”

46

Several other recent papers examine interest rate changes surrounding the release of new budget projections. Thorbecke (1993) uses OMB and CBO projections and finds that a $100 billion increase in the

25

Notably, most of the studies using either of the two approaches to incorporating anticipated deficits are consistent with the range of 20 to 60 basis points for an increase in projected deficits equal to 1 percent of GDP over 10 years mentioned by Gale and Orszag
(2003a), and the range of 30 to 60 basis points proposed by Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai
(2004).47 This range is also consistent with the results from macroeconometric models.48
The simplified Solow model and debt calculation discussed above generate somewhat larger numbers, but those calculations assume a closed economy. In a large open economy like the United States, the effect of deficits on interest rates would be expected to be somewhat smaller, which is consistent with the empirical evidence summarized above. Vector auto-regressions Some of the most heavily cited papers finding no effect of deficits on interest rates, including Evans (1987a, b) and Plosser (1982, 1987a), employ vector autoregressions (VARs) that use past variables to predict current or future deficits.49 The VARs are typically based on a very limited number of variables, ignore deficit (relative to the previously projected level) is associated with an immediate increase in 10-year interest rates of 14 to 26 basis points. Quigley and Porter-Hudak (1994) use CBO and OMB projections and find that a one-percent increase in the deficit itself (not as a percentage of GDP) raises short-term interest rates by 0.37 to 0.87 basis points. Assuming a baseline deficit of 2 percent of GDP, their result implies that an increase in the deficit of one percent of GDP (a 50 percent increase in the deficit) would raise short-term interest rates by 18.5 to 43.5 basis points. Kitchen (1996) uses changes in OMB forecasts and finds a statistically significant but quite modest effect -- an increase in the deficit projection of one percent of GDP raises 10-year bond yields by 3.4 basis points for one-year budget projections. He finds even smaller effects for multi-year budget projections on long-term interest rates. Calomiris, Engen,
Hassett, and Hubbard (2004) examine announcement effects about previous deficits, rather than announcement effects about future deficits or future legislation. They find no effects on current interest rates of the announcement of the previous month’s deficit. Their deficit measure, however, is based on the monthly budget updates provided by the CBO and Department of Treasury. These monthly updates are quite noisy, and depend on factors such as the timing of defense contract payments. The variation in the monthly data is thus unlikely to provide significant information about the budget outlook.
47

Brook (2003) similarly concludes that “most empirical work conducted in the past ten years estimates the impact on US real long-term interest rates of a sustained 1 percentage point decrease in the US fiscal position to be in the range of 20-40 basis points, and the impact on the slope of the yield curve to be in the range of 10-60 basis points.”

48

Almost all major macroeconometric models imply an economically significant connection between changes in budget deficits and in long-term interest rates. The precise effects depend on a wide variety of factors, including whether the change in the deficit is caused by a change in taxes or a change in spending, how monetary policy reacts, and how foreign governments react. The results vary widely, in part because different policies are simulated and standardization is difficult, but the findings suggest that a sustained increase in the primary (non-interest) deficit of 1 percent of GDP would raise interest rates by 40-50 basis points after 1 year and 50-100 basis points after 10 years (See Gale and Orszag 2002).

49

These are also some of the most heavily criticized studies, along the grounds that: the results are not robust to changes in sample period or specification; the models contain a variety of strong and unusual maintained assumptions; the equations explain only a small portion of the variance, which suggests either measurement error or that missing variables explain much of the residual and are being proxied by the variables in the regression. Perhaps most importantly, the tests have very little power, and in some cases are even unable to reject the hypothesis that expected inflation has no effect on nominal interest rates. For

26

information that is not reflected in such variables but may be widely known to market participants, and assume that the relationships among the variables do not change over time. Bernheim (1987), Cohen and Garnier (1991), and Elmendorf (1993) show that
VAR-based projections are inferior to those produced by OMB or DRI. The implication is that VAR-based projections are more likely to suffer from measurement error and thus to be biased toward showing no effects of deficits on interest rates.
Despite these limitations, several recent papers have applied the VAR methodology to examine the connection between deficits and interest rates. For example,
Canzoneri, Cumby, and Diba (2002) include both the Federal funds rate and the 10-year bond rate in a structural VAR; they find that the ten-year yield rises by 45 basis points immediately, and by roughly 40 basis point in the long run, in response to a spending shock equal to one percent of GDP. Engen and Hubbard (2004) use a VAR framework that includes anticipated deficits to estimate that an increase in the federal deficit equal to one percent of GDP causes the real interest rate to rise by 12 basis points. Dai and
Philippon (2004) estimate a structural VAR that uses information provided by noarbitrage restrictions on the yield curve. They conclude that a one percent of GDP increase in the unified deficit raises 10-year bond yields by 41 basis points.
B. Specification
To examine these issues, we follow Laubach (2003) and Engen and Hubbard
(2004) and undertake reduced-form regressions of the generic form: it = α + β f t + Γ Z + ε t

where i is a measure of the interest rate, f is a measure of fiscal policy (e.g., the deficit), and Z is a vector of control variables. Our primary interest is in the coefficient β, which provides an estimate of the effect of fiscal policy variables on interest rates.
We examine the role of four fiscal variables (as a share of GDP) at different time periods: federal publicly held debt; the unified deficit; the primary deficit (excluding interest payments); and primary outlays and revenue. Appendix Table 4 provides full details on these and the other variable definitions used in the interest rate regressions.
We do not take a firm a priori view on whether the “stock” view of an interest rate effect (through government debt) or the “flow” view of such an effect (through government deficits) on the level of interest rates is the analytically correct one. The model in Ball and Mankiw (1995) and Engen and Hubbard (2004) underscores the role of debt in affecting the level of interest rates. The Solow model and simple IS-LM models underscore the role of the deficit in affecting the level of interest rates. Indeed, since it is conceivable that both stocks and flows matter, we include both debt and deficits in some of the regressions. The regressions that separate primary outlays and revenue are insightful to the extent that, as noted in the discussion of Ricardian Equivalence above, further discussion, see Bernheim (1987) and Elmendorf and Mankiw (1999).

27

changes in outlays could have different effects on national saving and thus on interest rates than changes in revenue.50 We undertake several different version of our generic regression, for the years 1976 to 2004:
Effects of projected fiscal policy on forward interest rates Our preferred specifications examine the relationship between forward long-term interest rates and projected fiscal policies. This specification comes closest to eliminating the conflating effect between interest rates and deficits from current macroeconomic conditions: Most projections assume that the economy will be operating at full employment within a relatively short projection period into the future. In these specifications, it reflects the simple average of one-year forward interest rates from 5 to 14 years ahead, calculated from the zero-coupon yield curve.51 This provides a forward 10-year interest rate. The fiscal policy measures, ft, are measured five years ahead, as a share of projected GDP in that year, taken from the CBO baseline projections. The months in which the CBO projections were issued are listed in Appendix Table 5.
Effects of projected fiscal policy on current interest rates In these regressions, it is the current 10-year constant maturity Treasury yield, rather than the forward yield. The fiscal measures ft are the same as above.
Effects of current fiscal policy on current interest rates In these regressions, we examine current long-term rates and current fiscal policy outcomes (rather than projected fiscal policy outcomes, as above). The fiscal measures, ft, are all measured for the current year.
We run (but do not always report) each regression in both real and nominal terms.
We compute the real rate by adjusting the nominal rate for the long-term inflationary expectations series incorporated in the Federal Reserve Board’s FRB/US model.52 In the regressions explaining the nominal interest rate, the inflationary expectations series is included as an explanatory variable.
All regressions include a constant term and an estimate of the GDP growth rate.
The equations using projected fiscal policy use the growth rate projected by CBO five years ahead. The equations using current fiscal policy measures use the current growth rate. 50

Ricardian equivalence is a statement about the effects of variations in the timing of lump-sum tax payments, holding constant both the path of transfers and government purchases. Our regressions separate tax revenues from purchases and transfers.

51

These variables and some of the other data used in this study come from Thomas Laubach and Eric
Engen. We are grateful to them for sharing their data. The forward interest rate is computed from the zerocoupon yield curve as the last trading day for the month of the CBO projection.

52

Since 1991 Q3, this series is based on the Survey of Professional Forecasters published by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Laubach (2003, appendix) describes this series before 1991 Q3.

28

We include several additional control variables, since macroeconomic conditions can affect the level of interest rates associated with any given fiscal policy outcome. We include a dummy for an NBER-defined recession, which is entered on its own and also interacted with the fiscal measures. The purpose of this dummy and interaction term is to examine whether, even controlling for projected GDP growth, future fiscal policy outcomes have a different effect on interest rates during a recessionary period than during a recovery period; such a possibility was raised in Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai (2004).
Following Laubach (2003) and Engen and Hubbard (2004), we include a measure of the equity premium, which is intended to control for changes in risk aversion, which in turn could affect interest rates. The measure is defined as dividend income from the
National Income and Product Accounts divided by the market value of corporate equities held by households from the Federal Reserve’s Flow of Fund Accounts, plus the trend growth rate in real GDP, minus the real 10-year Treasury yield (Laubach 2003).
We follow Engen and Hubbard (2004) in controlling for Federal Reserve holdings
(in the debt equations) and purchases (in the deficit equations) of Treasury securities as a share of GDP, as a way of controlling for monetary policy.
Engen and Hubbard (2004) include an oil price variable, citing the evidence in
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991) and Barro (1991) that real oil prices affect real interest rates. We include the spot price for West Texas Intermediate crude oil, adjusted by the
GDP deflator.53
Lastly, Engen and Hubbard (2004) include a dummy variable for changes in defense spending, defined as the Ramey and Shapiro (1998) defense dummy variable augmented to include the military buildup in 2002.
We are skeptical that this is capturing significant shifts in defense spending, however. Defense spending over the sample period is shown in Figure 10. The Engen-Hubbard indicator variable is set equal to one only in 1980 and 2002. Yet the increases in defense spending as a share of GDP were larger in 1981, 1982, 1983, and 2003 than in 1980. A sustained defense build-up should have lasting effects on interest rates, not a one-year effect. In addition, the decline in defense spending following the collapse of the Soviet Union might rightfully also be considered a noteworthy event in trends in defense spending.54 For these reasons, we use actual defense spending as a share of GDP as a control variable, rather than the dummy variable.
Because some of the regression results suggested evidence of first-order autocorrelation in the error term, we use robust standard errors when estimation is undertaken
53

The oil price series we use, which is commonly used in various empirical studies, is slightly different from that in Engen and Hubbard (2004). The empirical results are unaffected by this difference.

54

In addition, Ramey and Shapiro (1998, Figure 6d) show that the expected effect on interest rates of a defense spending shock in their model dies out after 5 years, so there ought not be an impact on the 5-year ahead, 10-year interest rate in the first place.

29

using ordinary least squares (OLS) and also present the results using maximum likelihood to estimate an AR(1) model.55
C. Results
Projected Fiscal Policy and Forward Interest Rates Table 6 shows OLS regressions with the real forward long-term rate as the dependent variable and leaves two broad impressions. First, the table shows a robust, economically and statistically significant relationship between forward long-term real interest rates and projected fiscal imbalances. Second, the R-squared statistics show that there is more information in the projected deficit variables than in the projected debt variables.
In the simplest formulation, including only projected fiscal policy and projected
GDP growth rate as control variables, an increase in the projected debt after 5 years of 1 percent of GDP raises the real forward long-term rate by 4.9 basis points; the coefficient is significantly above zero. An increase in the projected unified deficit equal to 1 percent of GDP raises the forward long-term real interest rate by 29 basis points. An increase in the projected primary deficit of 1 percent of GDP is associated with a larger impact on the forward long-term rate: 40 basis points. When revenue and primary outlays are entered separately, a projected reduction in revenue after 5 years of 1 percent of GDP is estimated to raise the forward long-term rate by 42 basis points, and a projected increase in outlays of the same magnitude raises the forward long-term rate by 37 basis points.
Adding a recession dummy and interacting the recession dummy with the fiscal policy variable slightly raises the estimated coefficients on the fiscal variable: The coefficient on the projected primary deficit, for example, rises from 40 to 45 basis points.
The interactions between the recession dummy and the projected fiscal measures suggest that a given fiscal projection has a smaller (in absolute value) effect on interest rates during a recession than during a period of full-employment. Four of the five interaction terms have p-values below .12 and one of those is significant at the 1 percent level. This suggests that the effect of a projected deficit on forward long-term rates may be smaller if the economy is currently in recession than if it is not. This presents a puzzle, since it is unclear why a current recession should affect the relationship between the two future variables.56 Adding the other control variables (monetary policy, defense, oil, and equity premium) reduces the estimated coefficients on the fiscal variables slightly: The coefficient on the projected primary imbalance, for example, declines to 39 basis points.
The interaction between the recession dummy and projected unified or primary deficits
55

Estimation is undertaken using the “arima” command in STATA.

56

Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai (2004) hypothesize, based mostly on Rubin’s experience with real-world financial markets, that “it is possible during economic downturns that financial markets do not focus on long-term fiscal issues; if this is the case, the effect of the fiscal deterioration on long-term interest rates will manifest itself only as the economy recovers.” We have not evaluated whether arbitrage based on this evidence would generate expected profits after taking into account trading costs and other factors.

30

remains statistically and economically significant. Many of the additional control variables enter with the expected sign, but few are statistically significant, other than the equity premium, which enters negatively, as in Laubach (2003) and Engen and Hubbard
(2004). The coefficient on real oil prices is positive and significant in the debt equation, but not statistically significant in the others. The coefficient on Federal Reserve openmarket purchases is negative, but not statistically significant. Defense spending enters with a negative coefficient, which may be considered a surprise, but it is not statistically significant. Moreover, because the regressions already control for expected future deficits or future outlays, the informational value of the defense variable is unclear.
Running the same regressions using the nominal forward long-term rate as the dependent variable and including inflationary expectations as a right-hand-side variable
(in Table 7) generates slightly smaller fiscal effects. The coefficient on the projected primary deficit, for example, ranges between 33 and 46 basis points. The results in
Tables 6 and 7 underscore a robust, statistically significant connection between forward long rates and projected fiscal policy outcomes.
Table 8 includes both projected debt and projected primary deficit variables in the same regressions. To avoid double-counting, we use projected debt as a share of GDP at the end of year t+4 and primary budget measures in year t+5.57 In this “horse race” between stocks and flows, the deficit variables dominate. Indeed, the coefficient on the projected debt variable becomes statistically insignificant (and slightly negative) and the estimated effect of the projected deficit increases: Relative to the results in Table 5 that show an effect of 29 to 45 basis points per percent of GDP in projected primary variables
(primary deficit, primary outlays, or revenue), Table 8 shows an effect of 40 to 67 basis points once the analysis controls for projected debt-GDP ratios.
The recession interaction is statistically significant in one of the regressions, but insignificant in others.
Of the other variables, only the equity premium remains statistically significant. All the results in Table 7 are similar when using the nominal forward interest rate as the dependent variable and including inflationary expectations on the right-hand-side (not shown). Table 9 shows the same specification as Table 8 but uses an AR(1) model for estimation, because some of the results (in particular, when the additional control variables are included) suggest autocorrelated errors. In Table 9, the coefficient on the projections of primary deficit, primary outlays, and revenues ranges between 44 and 67 basis points. Again, the coefficients on the debt variables are generally small, negative, and statistically insignificant, and some of the recession interaction terms are significant.
The Appendix text and Appendix Table 6 discuss additional sensitivity analysis for regressions that examine the impact of projected future fiscal policy on forward, longterm interest rates.

57

Using projected debt at the end of t+5 and the deficit in t+5 would double count the deficit in t+5.
Likewise, using debt at the end of t+4 and the unified deficit in t+5 would effectively double count interest payments in t+5, since they are already implied by the debt level at the end of t+4.

31

Projected Fiscal Policy and Current Long-Term Rates Table 10 shows regressions of the current 10-year interest rate on projected future fiscal variables. With only fiscal variables entered or only fiscal and recession variables entered, the coefficients on the fiscal variables tend to be somewhat smaller than when the forward long-term rate is used (in Table 6) but are still statistically significant. For example, the coefficient on the projected primary deficit is between 30 and 36 basis points. The coefficients become smaller and statistically insignificant when the additional control variables are included. The coefficient on primary deficits falls to 17 basis points.
Notably, the Federal Reserve holdings or purchases of Treasury securities, which did not affect long-term forward rates, has an economically significant and statistically precise effect on current rates. Federal reserve purchases of Treasury securities are a statistically significant factor in all of the regressions in Tables 10-13 in which the variable enters, suggesting that different factors may affect current and forward long-term rates. When nominal long-term rates are used as the dependent variable (Table 11), the regressions that include all of the control variables, unified deficits and primary deficits enter with a statistically significant coefficient of about 20 basis points (specifications 10 and 11).
When real current rates are used and both the projected debt and primary deficit variables are included (Table 12), the estimated coefficient on the primary deficit variables increases to over 50 basis points in the specifications that include only fiscal variables or only fiscal and recession variables, but disappears when all control variables are included. The results are similar when nominal rates are used, and when an AR(1) model is estimated.
Current Fiscal Policy on Current Long-Term Rates Table 13 presents regressions of the real current long rate on current fiscal variables. The fiscal variables are generally not statistically significant in these specifications, and remain insignificant when the nominal rate is used, when an AR(1) model is estimated, and when both debt and deficit variables are entered simultaneously.
D. Summary
In the preferred specifications (Tables 8 and 9), which allow both debt and deficits to affect interest rates, the estimated effect on forward long-term rates from a 1percent-of-GDP shift in projected primary budget variables ranges between 40 and 67 basis points, depending on the specification and whether the fiscal variable is the primary deficit or revenue and primary outlays separately. Our effects are larger than those found in Laubach (2003) and Engen and Hubbard (2004) because we estimate regressions containing projected debt and deficits and because we include measures of whether the economy is currently in recession. The results show that the effects of projected deficits are larger when projected debt is included, and that the effect of a given future deficit also tends to be larger if the economy is currently not in a recession than if it is.

32

In sharp contrast, the projected debt-to-GDP ratio never exerts a positive and significant effect on future interest rates when it is entered in a regression that also includes projected deficits. The projected deficit thus seems a more informative measure than projected debt. This is reflected in table 6, where the deficit equations had significantly higher R-squared than the debt equations, and most strikingly in tables 8 and
9, where, when both variables are entered, deficits have large effects and the debt has none. Our estimates for an increase in the projected unified budget deficit of one percent of GDP are somewhat smaller -- 25 to 35 basis points per percent of GDP – than the effect of a primary deficit of one percent of GDP. This should be expected, since a shift of one percent of GDP in the primary deficit is more substantial than a shift of one percent of GDP in the unified deficit. Finally, our results when debt is entered by itself suggests that each percent-of-GDP increase in projected debt raises long-term rates by between 3 and 6 basis points. We find smaller and less significant effects of projected fiscal policy or current fiscal policy on current interest rates.
All of the estimates above may understate the true effects for at least two reasons.
First, as Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai (2004) note, the effects would be larger if sustained deficits cause investors to lose confidence in the ability of policy-makers to avoid a fiscal crisis. Second, because the projected fiscal policy variables are only approximations of investors' expectations, rather than investors’ true expectations, the regressions suffer from classical measurement error, which biases the coefficient toward zero.
VII. Conclusion
According to Suskind (2004), Vice President Cheney has declared that “Reagan proved that deficits don’t matter.” The evidence presented in this paper firmly indicates the opposite, at least as an economic matter. The empirical evidence shows that deficits reduce national saving, reduce future national income, and raise long-term interest rates.
Reasonable rules of thumb based on our estimates are that each percent-of-GDP in current deficits reduces national saving by 0.5 to 0.8 percent of GDP, that each percentof-GDP in anticipated future unified deficits raises forward long-term interest rates by 25 to 35 basis points, and that each percent-of-GDP in projected future primary deficits raises interest rates by 40 to 70 basis points.
These findings carry substantial implications. First, both the consumption and the interest rate results reject the Ricardian view of the world. It may be argued that the consumption results apply only to the short-term effects of changes in the timing of taxes and that it is still possible, conceptually, that in the long run, changes in the timing of taxes do not affect the level of national saving. (See, for example, Smetters 1999). The consumption results, however, rule out this criticism when taken in conjunction with the interest rate results. In particular, if tax-cut induced deficits did not affect long-term national saving, they should have no effect on forward, long-term interest rates. The presence of strong and systematic positive effects of projected revenues on forward, long-

33

term interest rates only makes sense if the effects of deficits on consumption and national saving are persistent and negative. Second, the results reject the small open economy view, at least as it applies to the U.S. economy. The key distinguishing test between the small open economy view and the conventional view is the impact of interest rates, which is shown to be positive in the analysis above.
Third, the results suggest that the sustained deficits facing the nation will impose significant economic costs. Under the assumptions described in Section II, the unified budget deficit over the next decade is projected to average about 3.5 percent of GDP.
First, our results suggest that these deficits will reduce annual national saving by 2 to 3 percent of GDP. As a result, by the end of the decade, the assets owned by Americans will be lessened by roughly 20 to 30 percent of GDP compared to their level if we balanced the unified budget over the next decade. Those missing assets will reduce national income by 1 to 2 percent in 2015. The increase in unified deficits will raise interest rates by 80 to 120 basis points.
Fourth, our results suggest that making the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts permanent would raise the cost of capital for new investments, reduce long-term investment, and reduce long-term economic growth. Tax cuts have offsetting effects on the cost of new investments, with marginal tax rate cuts reducing, and higher interest rates from deficits increasing, the cost of capital. Gale and Potter (2002) show that if the 2001 tax cut were to raise interest rates by 50 basis points, the cost of capital would rise for corporate equipment and structures, non-corporate equipment and structures, and owner-occupied housing. By 2014, EGTRRA, if extended, would increase the public debt by just over
$3.4 trillion, or about 19 percent of GDP in 2014. This implies an interest rate increase of 57 basis points using the Engen and Hubbard (2004) estimates noted above, and even larger amounts using our estimates. Alternatively, making EGTRRA permanent would reduce revenues by about 1.7 percent of GDP on a permanent basis (assuming the tax cuts are not overrun by the AMT). Using our estimates for primary deficits, this implies that interest rate will rise by 70 and 120 basis points. Both sets of estimates imply that the 2001 tax cut will end up reducing long-term investment. It might be thought that the
2003 tax cut would have more beneficial effects on investment, since it focused on dividend and capital gains tax cuts. In recent work, however, Gale and Orszag (2004b) show that the net effect of making EGTRRA and JGTRRA permanent would be to raise the cost of capital once the interest rate effects are taken into account (even using the
Engen-Hubbard (2004) estimates). These findings imply that making the tax cuts permanent would reduce the long-term level of investment, which is consistent with a negative effect on national saving.
Finally, after 2014, the budget outlook grows steadily worse as costs associated with retirement and health programs mount. Under reasonable projections and in the absence of policy changes, the nation thus faces a long period of sustained high budget deficits. In this context, the negative long-term effects of deficits presented in this paper, substantial though they are, may provide an unduly auspicious perspective on the adverse consequences of fiscal deficits.

34

References
Aschauer, DA. 1985. “Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand.” American Economic Review 75:
117-127.
Auerbach, Alan J. 1994. “The U.S. Fiscal Problem: Where We Are, How We Got Here, and
Where We’re Going.” In Stanley Fischer and Julio Rotemberg, eds., NBER Macroeconomics
Annual. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Auerbach, Alan J., William G. Gale, and Peter R. Orszag. 2004. "Sources of the Fiscal Gap.”
Tax Notes 103(8): 1049-59. May 24.
Auerbach, Alan J., William G. Gale, Peter R. Orszag, and Samara R. Potter. 2003. “Budget
Blues: The Fiscal Outlook and Options for Reform.” In Agenda for the Nation. Henry Aaron,
James Lindsey, and Pietro Nivola, eds. Brookings. 109-145
Auerbach, Alan J. and Laurence Kotlikoff. 1987. “Evaluating Fiscal Policy with a Dynamic
Simulation Model.” American Economic Review, May, 49-55.
Ball, Laurence and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1995. “What Do Budget Deficits Do?” Budget Deficits and Debt: Issues and Options, 95-119. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Barro, Robert J. 1974. “Are Government Bonds Net Worth?” Journal of Political Economy Vol.
82 No. 6 (Nov/Dec): 1095-1117.
Barro, Robert J. 1989. “The Ricardian Approach to Budget Deficits.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives. 3 (2) (Spring), 37-54.
Barro, Robert J. 1991. “World Interest Rates and Investment.” NBER Working Paper 3849.
September.
Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1990. “World Real Interest Rates.” NBER Working
Paper 3317. April.
Barth, James R. and Michael D. Bradley. 1989. “Evidence on Real Interest Rate Effects of
Money, Debt, and Government Spending.” Quarterly Review of Economics and Business Vol.
29 No. 1 (Spring): 49-57.
Barth, James R., George Iden, and Frank S. Russek. 1985. "Federal borrowing and short term interest rates: Comment." Southern Economic Journal Vol. 52 No.2 (October): 554-559.
Barth, James R., George Iden, Frank S. Russek. 1986. “Government Debt, Government
Spending, and Private Sector Behavior: Comment.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 76,
Issue 5 (Dec.) 1158-1167.

Barth James R., George Iden, Frank S. Russek, and Mark Wohar. 1991. “The Effects of Federal
Budget Deficits on Interest Rates and the Composition of Domestic Output.” In The Great Fiscal
Experiment, edited by Rudolph G. Penner. Washington: Urban Institute Press, pp. 71-141.
Bernheim, B. Douglas. 1987. “Ricardian Equivalence: An Evaluation of Theory and Evidence.”
NBER Working Paper 2330, July.
Bernheim, B. Douglas. 1989. “A Neoclassical Perspective on Budget Deficits.” Journal of
Economic Perspectives Vol. 3 No. 2 (Spring): 55-72.
Blanchard, Olivier J. 1985. “Debt, Deficits, and Finite Horizons.” The Journal of Political
Economy 93 (2): (Apr.): 223-247.
Bovenberg, A. Lans. 1988. “Long-term Interest Rates in the United States.” IMF Staff Papers 35,
No. 2 (June): 382-390.
Bradley, Michael D. 1986. “Government Spending or Deficit Financing: Which Causes
Crowding Out?” Journal of Economics and Business Vol. 38 No. 3 (August): 203-214.
Brook, Anne-Marie. 2003. “Recent and Prospective Trends in Real Long-Term Interest Rates:
Fiscal Policy and Other Drivers.” OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 367.
September 29.
Burman, Leonard E., William G. Gale and Jeffrey Rohaly. 2003. “The Expanding Role of the
Alternative Minimum Tax”. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 17:2. Spring. 173-86.
Calomiris, Charles W., Eric Engen, Kevin A. Hassett, and R. Glenn Hubbard. 2003. “Do Budget
Deficit Announcements Move Interest Rates?” December.
Campbell, John Y. and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1989. “Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates:
Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence.” In NBER Macroconomics Annual, edited by O.
Blanchard and S. Fischer. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 185-216.
Campbell, John Y. and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1990. “Permanent Income, Current Income and
Consumption.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 8(3): 265-79. July.
Canto, Victor A. and Donald Rapp. 1982. “The ‘Crowding Out’ Controversy: Arguments and
Evidence.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Economic Review (August): 33-37.
Canzoneri, Matthew B., Robert E. Cumby, and Behzad T. Diba. 2002. “Should the European
Central Bank and the Federal Reserve Be Concerned About Fiscal Policy?”
Presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s symposium on “Rethinking Stabilization
Policy,” Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 2002.
Cardia, Emanuela. 1997. “Replicating Ricardian Equivalence Tests with Simulated Series.” The
American Economic Review 87 (1) March: 65-79.

Carlson, Jack. 1983. “The Relationship Between Federal Deficits and Interest Rates.” Statement before the Joint Economic Committee, October 21.
Carroll, Chris and Lawrence H. Summers. 1987. “Why Have Private Savings Rates In the United
States and Canada Diverged?” Journal of Monetary Economics 20: 249-279.
Cebula, Richard J. 1987. The Deficit Problem in Perspective. Lexington, Massachusetts: D.C.
Health & Co.
Cebula, Richard J. 1988. “Federal Government Budget Deficits and Interest Rates: A Brief
Note.” Southern Economic Journal Vol. 55 no.1 (July): 206-210.
Cebula, Richard J. and James V. Koch. 1989. “An Empirical Note on Deficits, Interest Rates, and International Capital Flows.” Quarterly Review of Economics and Business Vol. 29 No. 3
(Autumn): 121-127.
Cebula, Richard J. and James V. Koch. 1994. “Federal Budget Deficits, Interest Rates, and
International Capital Flows: A Further Note. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance
Vol. 34 No. 1 (Spring): 117-120.
Cebula, Richard J. 1998. “Impact of Budget Deficits on Ex Post Real Long-Term Interest Rates.”
Applied Economics Letters 7: 177-179. March.
Cohen, Darrel and Olivier Garnier. 1991. “The Impact of Forecasts of Budget Deficits on
Interest Rates in the United States and other G-7 Countries,” Division of Research and Statistics,
Federal Reserve Board.
Congressional Budget Office. 1998. “Description of Economic Models.” November.
Congressional Budget Office. 2003. “The Long-Term Budget Outlook.” December.
Congressional Budget Office. 2004a. “Economic and Budget Outlook.” January.
Congressional Budget Office. 2004b. “The Cyclically Adjusted and Standardized-Budget
Measures.” May.
Congressional Budget Office. 2004c. “The Outlook for Social Security.” June.
Coorey, Sharmini. 1992. “The Determinants of U.S. Real Interest Rates in the Long Run.” In
The United States Economy: Performance and Issues by a staff team headed by Yusuke
Horiguchi. Washington: International Monetary Fund, 314-353.
Council of Economic Advisers. 1994. Economic Report of the President. Washington: United
States Government Printing Office, February.

Council of Economic Advisers. 2003. Economic Report of the President. Washington: United
States Government Printing Office, February.
Cox, W. Michael. 1985. “The Behavior of Treasury Securities Monthly, 1942-1984.” Journal of
Monetary Economics 16: 227-240.
Dai, Qiang and Thomas Philippon. 2004. “Government Deficits and Interest Rates: a NoArbitrage Structural VAR Approach.” New York University. March 14.
De Leeuw, Frank and Thomas M. Holloway. 1985. “The Measurement and Significance of the
Cyclically Adjusted Federal Budget and Debt.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking Vol. 17
No.2 (May): 232-242.
Dennis, Robert et al. 2004. “Macroeconomic Analysis of a 10 Percent Cut in Income Tax Rates.”
Congressional Budget Office. May.
Dewald, William G. 1983. “Federal Deficits and Interest Rates: Theory and Evidence.” Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Economic Review (January): 20-29.
Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1991. “National Saving and International Investment: Comment.” In
National Saving and Economic Performance, edited by B. Douglas Bernheim and John B.
Shoven, 220-26. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Echols, Michael E. and Jan Walter Elliot. 1976. “Rational Expectations in a Disequilibrium
Model of the Term Structure.” American Economic Review Vol. 66 No.1 (March): 28-44.
Elmendorf, Douglas W. 1993. “Actual Budget Deficits and Interest Rates,” Mimeo, Department of Economics, Harvard University, March.
Elmendorf, Douglas W. 1996. “The Effects of Deficit Reduction Laws on Real Interest Rates,”
Finance and Economics Discussion Series 1996-44, Federal Reserve Board, October.
Elmendorf, Douglas W. and Jeffrey B. Liebman. 2000. “Social Security Reform and National
Saving in an Era of Budget Surpluses.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2): 1-71.
Elmendorf, Douglas W. and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1999. “Government Debt.” In Handbook of
Macroeconomics Volume 1C, edited by John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, 1615-1669.
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.
Engen, Eric M. and R. Glenn Hubbard. 2004. “Federal Government Debt and Interest Rates.”
Forthcoming, NBER Macroeconomic Annual.
Evans, Paul. 1985. “Do Large Deficits Produce High Interest Rates?” American Economic
Review Vol. 75 No. 1 (March): 68-87.

Evans, Paul. 1987a. “Interest Rates and Expected Future Budget Deficits in the United States.”
Journal of Political Economy Vol. 95 No. 11 (February): 34-58.
Evans, Paul. 1987b. “Do Budget Deficits Raise Nominal Interest Rates? Evidence From Six
Countries.” Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 20: 281-300.
Evans, Paul. 1988. “Are Consumers Ricardian?” Journal of Political Economy. 96:5 (October),
983-1004.
Evans, Paul. 1989. “A Test of Steady-State Government-Debt Neutrality.” Economic Inquiry
Vol. 27 (January): 39-55.
Evans, Paul. 1991. “Is Ricardian Equivalence a Good Approximation?” Economic Inquiry 29(4):
626-44. October.
Evans, Paul. 1993. “Consumers Are Not Ricardian: Evidence from Nineteen Countries.”
Economic Inquiry 31(October): 534-548.
Evans, Paul and Iftekhar Hasan.1994. “Are Consumers Ricardian? Evidence for Canada.” The
Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 34(1): 25-40. Spring.
Feldstein, Martin S. 1982. “Government Deficits and Aggregate Demand.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 9: 1-20.
Feldstein, Martin S. 1986. “Budget Deficits, Tax Rules, and Real Interest Rates. ” NBER
Working Paper 1970, July.
Feldstein, Martin S. and Gary Chamberlain. 1973. “Multimarket Expectations and the Rate of
Interest.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking Vol. 4 No. 4 (November): 873-902.
Feldstein, Martin S. and Otto Eckstein. 1970. “The Fundamental Determinants of the Interest
Rate.” Review of Economics and Statistics Vol. 52 no. 4 (November): 363-375.
Feldstein, Martin and Douglas W. Elmendorf. 1990. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and Private Sector Behavior Revisited: Comment.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 80,
No. 3 (Jun.) 589-599.
Feldstein, Martin S. and Charles Horioka. 1980. "Domestic Savings and International Capital
Flows." Economic Journal June Vol. 90 No. 358 (June): 314-329.
Flavin, Marjorie. 1987. “Comment.” In Macroeconomics Annual: 304-315. Cambridge, MA:
NBER and MIT Press.
Frankel, Jeffrey A. 1983. “A Test of Portfolio Crowding-Out and Related Issues of Finance.”
NBER Working Paper 1205, September.

Friedman, Benjamin. 1988. Day of Reckoning: The Consequences of American Economic
Policy Under Reagan and After. New York: Random House.
Gale, William G. and Peter R. Orszag. 2002. “The Economic Effects of Long-Term Fiscal
Discipline.” Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Discussion Paper. December 17.
Gale, William G. and Peter R. Orszag. 2003a. “Economic Effects of Sustained Budget Deficits.”
National Tax Journal 56: 463-85. September.
Gale, William G. and Peter R. Orszag. 2003b. “Sunsets in the Tax Code.” Tax Notes 99(10):
1553-61. June 9.
Gale, William G. and Peter R. Orszag. 2003c. “Effects of Fiscal Policy on Aggregate
Consumption and Saving: A Re-Evaluation of Ricardian Equivalence.” Paper presented at the
American Economic Association Meeting. December.
Gale, William G. and Peter R. Orszag. 2004a. “Economic Effects of Making the 2001 and 2003
Tax Cuts Permanent.” International Tax and Public Finance, forthcoming.
Gale, William G. and Peter R. Orszag. 2004b. “Tax Cuts, Interest Rates, and the User Cost of
Capital.” Brookings. In Progress.
Gale, William G. and Samara R. Potter. 2002. “An Economic Evaluation of the Economic
Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001.” National Tax Journal 55(1): 133-186.
Giannaros, Demetrios S. and Bharat R. Kolluri. 1985. “Deficit Spending, Money, and Inflation:
Some International Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Macroeconomics Vol. 7 no. 3 (Summer):
401-417.
Gokhale, Jagadeesh and Kent Smetters. 2003. Fiscal and Generational Imbalances: New Budget
Measures for New Budget Priorities. Washington: AEI Press.
Graham, Fred C. 1995. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and Private-Sector Behavior:
Comment.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 85, No. 5, (Dec.), 1348-1356.
Graham, Fred C. and Daniel Himarios. 1991. “Fiscal Policy and Private Consumption:
Instrumental Variables Tests of the ‘Consolidated Approach.’” Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking 23(1): 53-67. February.
Graham, Fred C. and Daniel Himarios. 1996. “Consumption, Wealth, and Finite Horizons: Tests of Ricardian Equivalence.” Economic Inquiry Vol. 34, 527-544.
Gravelle, Jane G. 1994. The Economic Effects of Taxing Capital Income. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.

Gravelle, Jane G. 2004. “Historical Effective Marginal Tax Rates on Capital Income.”
Congressional Research Service Report for Congress. January 12.
Hall, Robert E. 1978. “Stochaistic Implications of the Life Cycle-Permanent Income
Hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy 86: 971-987.
Hall, Robert E. 1988. “Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption.” Journal of Political
Economy 96: 339-357.
Hayashi, Fumio. 1982. “The Permanent Income Hypothesis: Estimation and Testing By
Instrumental Variables.” Journal of Political Economy 90: 895-916.
Hoelscher, Gregory P. 1983. “Federal Borrowing and Short Term Interest Rates.” Southern
Economic Journal Vol. 50 (October): 319-333.
Hoelscher, Gregory P. 1986. “New Evidence on Deficits and Interest Rates.” Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking Vol. 18 No.1 (February): 1-17.
Hutchison, Michael and David H. Pyle. 1984. “The Real Interest Rate/Budget Deficit Link:
International Evidence, 1973-1982.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Review
(Fall): 26-35.
Judd, Kenneth L. 1985. “Short Run Analysis of Fiscal Policy in a Simple Perfect Foresight
Model.” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93, No. 2. (April), pp. 298-319.
Judd, Kenneth L. 1987a. “The Welfare Cost of Factor Taxation in a Perfect Foresight Model.”
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 95, No. 4. (August), pp. 675-709.
Judd, Kenneth L. 1987b. “Debt and Distortionary Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight
Model.” Journal of Monetary Economics 20(5): 1-72. July.
Kiley, Michael T. 2003. “The Effect of Government Debt on the Return to Capital.” December.
Kim, Sun-Young and Raymond E. Lombra. 1989. “Why the Empirical Relationship Between
Deficits and Interest Rates Appears so Fragile.” Journal of Economics and Business Vol. 41 No.
3 (August): 241-251.
Kitchen, John. 1996. “Domestic and International Financial Market Responses to Federal
Deficit Announcements.” Journal of International Money and Finance Vol. 15 No. 2: 239-254.
Kitchen, John. 2002. “A Note on Interest Rates and Structural Federal Budget Deficits,” unpublished manuscript, October.
Kolluri, Bharat R. and Demetrios S. Giannaros. 1987. “Budget Deficits and Short-term Real
Interest Rate Forecasting.” Journal of Macroeconomics Vol. 9 No. 1 (Winter): 109-125.

Kormendi, Roger. 1983. "Government Debt, Government Spending, and Private Sector
Behavior." The American Economic Review. Vol. 73 Issue 5 (Dec.) 994-1010.
Kormendi, Roger C. and Philip Meguire. 1986. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and
Private Sector Behavior: Reply.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, Issue 5 (Dec.),
1180-1187.
Kormendi, Roger C. and Philip Meguire. 1990. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and
Private Sector Behavior: Reply and Update.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 80, Issue 3
(Jun.), 604-617.
Kormendi, Roger C. and Philip Meguire. 1995. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and
Private Sector Behavior: Reply.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 85, No. 5 (Dec.): 13571361.
Kudlow, Lawrence. 1981. Statement before the Senate Budget Committee (Statistical Appendix),
October 20.
Laubach, Thomas. 2003. “New Evidence on the Interest Rate Effects of Budget Deficits and
Debt.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. May.
Lee, Ronald and Ryan Edwards. 2001. “The Fiscal Impact of Population Change.” In Seismic
Shifts: The Economic Impact of Demographic Change, edited by Jane Sneddon Little and Robert
K. Triest, 220-237. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series No. 46.
Makin, John H. 1983. “Real Interest, Money Surprises, Anticipated Inflation and Fiscal
Deficits.” Review of Economics and Statistics Vol. 65 No.3 (August): 374-384.
Makin, John H. and Vito Tanzi. 1984. “Level and Volatility of U.S. Interest Rates: Roles of
Expected Inflation, Real Rates and Taxes.” In Taxation, Inflation, and Interest Rates, edited by
Vito Tanzi, 110-142. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2000a. Macroeconomics. New York: Worth Publishers.
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2000b. “The Savers-Spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy.” American
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 90(2): 120-125.
Mascaro, Angelo and Allen H. Melzer. 1983. “Long- and Short-term Interest Rates in a Risky
World.” Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 12 No.4 (November): 485-518.
Miller, Stephen M. and Frank S. Russek. 1991. “The Temporal Causality Between Fiscal
Deficits and Interest Rates,” Contemporary Policy Issues, Vol. IX, July: 12-23.
Miller, Stephen M. and Frank S. Russek. 1996. “Do Federal Deficits Affect Interest Rates?
Evidence from Three Econometric Methods.” Journal of Macroeconomics Vol. 18 No. 3
(Summer): 403-428.

Modigliani, Franco and Arlie G. Sterling. 1986. “Government Debt, Government Spending, and
Private Sector Behavior: Comment.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 5 (Dec.)
1168-1179.
Motley, Brian. 1983. “Real Interest Rates, Money and Government Deficits.” Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, Economic Review (Summer): 31-45.
Mountford, Andrew and Harald Uhlig. 2000. “What are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks.”
Centre for Economic Policy Research, October.
Muller, Patrice and Robert Price. 1984. “Public Sector Indebtedness and Long-term Interest
Rates.” Paper presented at the World Bank/Brookings Institution Workshop on the International
Consequences of Budgetary Deficits in the OECD. Washington, September.
Perotti, Roberto. 2002. “Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in OECD countries,” ISOM conference, Frankfurt, June.
Plosser, Charles I. 1982. “Government Financing Decisions and Asset Returns.” Journal of
Monetary Economics Vol. 9, No. 3 (May): 325-352.
Plosser, Charles I. 1987a. “Fiscal Policy and the Term Structure.” Journal of Monetary
Economics Vol. 20 No. 6 (September): 343-367.
Plosser, Charles I. 1987b. “Comment.” On Douglas Bernheim. "Ricardian Equivalence: An
Evaluation of Theory and Evidence," NBER Macroeconomics Annual: 263-303.
Poterba, James M. and Lawrence H. Summers. 1986. “Finite Lifetimes and the Crowding Out
Effects of Budget Deficits.” NBER Working Paper No. 1955. June 1986.
Poterba, James M. and Lawrence H. Summers. 1987. “Recent US Evidence on Budget Deficits and National Savings.” NBER Working Paper No. 2144. February.
Quigley, Michael Regan and Susan Porter-Hudak. 1994. “A New Approach in Analyzing the
Effect of Deficit Announcements on Interest Rates.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking Vol.
26 No. 4 (November): 894-902.
Ramey, Valerie A. and Matthew D. Shapiro. 1998. “Costly Capital Reallocation and the Effects of Government Spending.” Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy vol. 48
(June), pp. 145-94.
Rubin, Robert E., Peter R. Orszag, and Allen Sinai. 2004. “Sustained Budget Deficits: LongerRun U.S. Economic Performance and the Risk of Financial and Fiscal Disarray.” Paper presented at the AEA-NAEFA Joint Session, Allied Social Science Associations Annual Meetings, The
Andrew Brimmer Policy Forum, “National Economic and Financial Policies for Growth and
Stability,” January 4.

Seater, John J. 1981. “The Market Value of Outstanding Government Debt, 1919-1975.”
Journal of Monetary Economics 8 (July): 85-101.
Seater, John J. 1993. “Ricardian Equivalence.” Journal of Economic Literature 31 Issue 1
(March): 142-190.
Seater, John J. and Roberto S. Mariano. 1985. "New Tests of the Life-Cycle and TaxDiscounting Hypotheses." Journal of Monetary Economics. (March): 195-215.
Serres, Alain de and Florian Pelgrin. 2003. “The Decline in Private Saving Rates in the 1990s in
OECD Countries: How Much Can Be Explained by Non-Wealth Determinants?” OECD
Economics Department Working paper No. 344.
Shapiro, Matthew. 2004. Comment. on “Federal Government Debt and Interest Rates.”
Forthcoming, NBER Macroeconomic Annual.
Shoven, John B. 2002. “The Impact of Major Life Expectancy Improvements on the Financing of Social Security, Medicare and Medicaid.” In Creating Methuselah: Molecular Medicine and the Problems of an Aging Society edited by Henry J. Aaron and William B. Schwartz.
Washington.: Brookings Institution Press.
Sinai, Allen and Peter Rathjens. 1983. “Deficits, Interest Rates, and the Economy.” Data
Resources U.S. Review (June): 1.27-1.41.
Smetters, Kent. 1999. “Ricardian Equivalence: Long-Run Leviathan.” Journal of Public
Economics 73(3): 395-421. September.
Standard and Poor’s Statistical Service. 2003. Municipal Bond Price Indexes.
Summers, Lawrence H. 1985. “Issues in National Savings Policy.” NBER Working Paper No.
1710.
Suskind, Ron. 2004. The Price of Loyalty: George W. Bush, the White House, and the Education of Paul O’Neill. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Swamy, P.A.V.B., Bharat R. Kolluri and Rao N. Singamsetti. 1988. “What Do Regressions of
Interest Rates on Deficits Imply?” Division of Research and Statistics, Federal Reserve Board of
Governors. Finance and Economics Discussion Series no. 3, January.
Tanzi, Vito. 1985. “Fiscal Deficits and Interest Rates in the United States, An Empirical
Analysis, 1960-1984.” IMF Staff Paper 32, no. 4 (December): 551-576.
Tatom, John A. 1984. “A Perspective on the Federal Deficit Problem.” Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review Vol. 66 No.6 (June/July): 5-17.

Tavares, Jose and Rossen Valkanov. 2001. “The Neglected Effect of Fiscal Policy on Stock and
Bond Returns,” Anderson School, UCLA, October.
Thomas, Lloyd B. Jr., and Ali Abderrezak. 1988a. "Anticipated Future Budget Deficits and the
Term Structure of Interest Rates," Southern Economic Journal Vol. 55 no. 1 (July): 150-161.
Thomas, Lloyd B. Jr., and Ali Abderrezak.1988b. “Long-term Interest Rates: The Role of
Expected Budget Deficits.” Public Finance Quarterly Vol. 16 No. 3 (July): 341-356.
Thorbecke, Willem. 1993. “Why Deficit News Affects Interest Rates.” Journal of Policy
Modeling Vol. 15 No. 1: 1-11.
Truman, Edwin M. 2001. “The International Implications Of Paying Down The Debt.” Institute for International Economics. Policy Brief Number 01-7.
United States Treasury Department. 1984. The Effects of Deficits on Prices of Financial Assets:
Theory and Evidence. Washington, D.C., March.
Wachtel, Paul and John Young. 1987. “Deficit Announcements and Interest Rates.” American
Economic Review Vol. 77 no. 5 (December): 1007-1012.
Zahid, Khan H. 1988. “Government Budget Deficits and Interest Rates: The Evidence Since
1971, Using Alternative Deficit Measures.” Southern Economic Journal Vol. 54 No. 3 (January):
725-731.

Appendix
Sensitivity Analysis for Effects of Projected Fiscal Policy on Forward Long-Term Rates
In addition to the regressions reported in the text, we have undertaken a variety of additional sensitivity analysis of the relation between projected fiscal policy outcomes and forward long-term rates. First, controlling for the actual current or lagged budget surplus (as a share of GDP) or the current or lagged standardized surplus had important effects in specifications 1-4 (in Tables 6-9), which control only for projected future fiscal variables and projected growth rates, and specifications 5-8, which control for those variables and recession indicators. The coefficients on the current and lagged actual and standardized surplus was positive and large, and the coefficients on future fiscal variables rose. When all control variables were entered, however, (specifications 9-12), the coefficients on the current or lagged actual or standardized budget went to zero and the coefficients on the other variables were almost identical to those in Tables 6-9.
Estimates of the regressions in tables 6-9 in first-difference form yield similar coefficients but large standard errors. We also experimented with using the Federal funds interest rate or the 3-month Treasury rate as an alternative to Federal Reserve purchases or holdings of Treasury securities, but the results are not materially affected.
The remainder of our sensitivity analysis focuses on two variables: the equity premium and the recession dummy.
The equity premium variable is potentially problematic in a number of ways.
First, it is not clear whether changes in the ratio of current dividend yield to market value should be taken to represent a change in the return of all assets, or a shift in preferences for stocks versus bonds. Second, the equity premium variable includes a measure of current long-term interest rates, which affect interpretation of the results. For example, the results in tables 5-8, taken literally, represent the effect on fiscal policy on 5-year ahead long-term rates after already controlling for current long-term rates (through the equity premium). To examine sensitivity of the results to these issues, we enter the dividend/market value ratio in lieu of the equity premium variable or leave all of the risk variables out of the equation.
As a measure of current economic activity, the recession variable may also raise concerns, since it is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 only in 1980, 1981, 1982, and 1991. (Although there was a recession in 2001, it started after the January 2001 CBO forecast and ended before the January 2002 CBO forecast.) To explore other options, we alternatively include the GDP gap, the lagged GDP gap, or no control for the current state of the economy. It is important to note, however, that our goal in including the recession variable was not just to control for the state of the economy, but also to explore whether the effects of future projected fiscal policy outcomes were systematically different in a recession, perhaps because participants in financial markets have shorter horizons during such periods. Controlling for the GDP gap instead of using the recession dummy may

not provide as clean a test of that hypothesis. Also, note that the GDP gap is measured in fiscal years, so the lagged GDP gap is for the fiscal year that ends approximately 4 months before the CBO projection.
Appendix Table 6 reports the results from using 12 alternative specifications to the regression shown in Table 9, specification 11, which is replicated in the first column of Appendix Table 6. In all 12 specifications, projected primary deficits in year t+5 have positive, precise and substantial impacts on forward long-term rates. In contrast, projected ratios of public debt to GDP never show a positive significant effect on forward long-term rates.
The first set of robustness checks examines the recession dummy. The second column replaces the recession dummy and interaction with the GDP gap, which is entered by itself and also interacted with the fiscal variables. The estimated coefficient on the primary deficit is largely unaffected by this change (52 basis points versus 53). The interaction term on the projected primary deficit remains negative and statistically significant. The coefficient suggests that for every 1 percentage point increase in the current GDP gap, the effect of the projected deficit on the forward long-term rate is reduced by 11 basis points. The third column replaces the recession dummy and interaction with the lagged GDP gap. In this specification, the coefficient on the projected primary deficit declines somewhat, to 35 basis points, and the interaction term on the lagged GDP gap and the projected primary deficit is also somewhat smaller (7 basis points).
The fourth column leaves out the recession indicator and interactions altogether and shows an effect of only 22 basis points. However, given that the previous three columns show that the interaction between the economic activity indicator and projected primary deficits is statistically significant, and the previous two regressions show that the economic activity indicator itself is statistically significant, the fourth column shows the importance of controlling for the level of economic activity. Studies that do not (e.g.,
Engen and Hubbard 2004) are likely to obtain smaller effects of deficits on projected fiscal policy.
The second set of robustness checks involves the equity premium variable.
Specifications 5-8 replace the equity premium with the ratio of dividends to the market value of stocks held by households. Specifications 9-12 leave out all variables associated with risk. The results in these specifications are very similar to those in 1-4 and the coefficients on the ratio of dividends to market value are small and insignificant.

Table 1
Steady-State Effects of Deficits in the Solow Model
Initial

New steady state with private saving offset of:
25%
0%
50%

Capital share
Depreciation rate
Growth rate

0.3
0.04
0.03

0.3
0.04
0.03

0.3
0.04
0.03

0.3
0.04
0.03

Saving rate
Private saving rate
Budget deficit

0.175
0.200
0.025

0.1675
0.2025
0.035

0.165
0.200
0.035

0.17
0.205
0.035

Income per capita
Capital-output ratio
Marginal product of capital

1.48
2.5
0.120

1.45
2.39
0.125

1.44
2.36
0.127

1.46
2.43
0.124

Table 2
Effects of Taxes on Aggregate Consumption
(Consumption Function Estimates, Ordinary Least Squares)
First Difference of Levels
1954-02 1954-92 1954-00

First Difference of Ratios
1954-02 1954-92 1954-00

First Difference of Levels, Scaled
1954-02 1954-92 1954-00

A. Kormendi-Meguire RHS Specification (Effects of all taxes)
PC*

-0.39
-0.14

-0.14
0.16

-0.23
0.17

-0.22
0.13

-0.09
0.15

-0.19
0.14

-0.24
0.12

-0.14
0.14

-0.23
0.13

NDS**

-0.27
0.12

-0.15
0.16

-0.23
0.16

-0.18
0.13

-0.10
0.15

-0.18
0.14

-0.21
0.12

-0.15
0.14

-0.22
0.13

B. With Federal and State/Local Taxes Split (Effects of Federal Taxes)
PC

-0.46
0.13

-0.21
0.16

-0.30
0.16

-0.28
0.12

-0.17
0.15

-0.26
0.13

-0.31
0.11

-0.25
0.12

-0.31
0.12

NDS

-0.34
0.11

-0.23
0.16

-0.29
0.14

-0.25
0.11

-0.20
0.14

-0.26
0.12

-0.27
0.11

-0.27
0.12

-0.31
0.12

C. And with Marginal Tax Rate on Capital included (Effects of federal taxes)
PC

-0.53
0.14

-0.32
0.17

-0.40
0.17

-0.38
0.13

-0.30
0.15

-0.37
0.14

-0.40
0.12

-0.35
0.13

-0.43
0.13

NDS

-0.41
0.12

-0.34
0.16

-0.40
0.15

-0.35
0.12

-0.32
0.15

-0.37
0.14

-0.38
0.12

-0.37
0.14

-0.42
0.13

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.
*PC is real per-capita consumption of nondurables and services, plus 10 percent of expenditures on durable goods plus
30 percent of the stock of durable goods.
**NDS is real per-capita expenditures on nondurables and services multiplied by the sample period mean ratio of total consumption expenditures to nondurable and services expenditures.

Table 3
Coefficient Estimates
(Consumption Function Estimates, Ordinary Least Squares --- 1954-2002)
First Difference of Levels

First Difference of Ratios

First Difference of Levels, Scaled

PC*

NDS**

PC

NDS

PC

NDS

NNP(t)

0.35
0.08

0.32
0.07

0.39
0.10

0.36
0.09

0.26
0.06

0.30
0.06

NNP(t-1)

0.13
0.05

0.09
0.04

0.08
0.04

0.07
0.04

0.04
0.04

0.03
0.04

Government
Purchases

0.09
0.14

0.04
0.12

0.02
0.10

-0.02
0.10

0.01
0.10

-0.01
0.10

Federal Taxes

-0.53
0.14

-0.41
0.12

-0.38
0.13

-0.35
0.12

-0.40
0.12

-0.38
0.12

State/Local Taxes

0.90
0.50

1.02
0.44

0.90
0.39

1.05
0.38

0.98
0.39

1.04
0.38

Government
Transfers

0.67
0.29

0.43
0.25

0.55
0.19

0.53
0.19

0.18
0.27

0.16
0.26

Government
Interest Paid

0.02
0.29

0.12
0.25

-0.08
0.26

0.10
0.25

-0.16
0.26

0.01
0.25

Government
Debt(t-1)

-0.03
0.02

-0.02
0.02

-0.03
0.02

-0.02
0.02

-0.02
0.02

-0.01
0.02

Wealth(t-1)

0.02
0.01

0.02
0.01

0.01
0.01

0.01
0.01

0.01
0.01

0.01
0.01

Retained Earnings

0.17
0.16

0.13
0.14

0.17
0.15

0.16
0.15

0.01
0.00

0.00
0.00

Marginal Tax Rate on Capital***

0.69
0.56

0.72
0.48

0.04
0.04

0.04
0.02

0.04
0.02

0.04
0.02

Constant

0.07
0.05

0.07
0.04

0.01
0.00

0.00
0.00

0.00
0.00

0.01
0.00

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.
*PC is real per-capita consumption of nondurables and services, plus 10 percent of expenditures on durable goods plus
30 percent of the stock of durable goods.
**NDS is real per-capita expenditures on nondurables and services multiplied by the sample period mean ratio of total consumption expenditures to nondurable and services expenditures.
*** Coefficient and standard error multiplied by 100.

Table 4
Effects of Taxes on Aggregate Consumption
(Euler Equation Specification)
First Difference of Levels
Marginal Tax
Rate Included?

First Difference of Ratios

First Difference of Levels, Scaled

No

Yes

No

Yes

No

Yes

PC

-0.38
0.14

-0.44
0.15

-0.70
0.16

-0.79
0.18

-0.25
0.13

-0.33
0.13

NDS

-0.27
0.12

-0.31
0.13

-0.65
0.15

-0.71
0.17

-0.22
0.12

-0.27
0.12

PC

-0.81
0.26

-0.82
0.24

-0.54
0.25

-0.36
0.34

-0.56
0.25

-0.56
0.23

NDS

-0.66
0.22

-0.65
0.22

-0.51
0.23

-0.31
0.32

-0.55
0.25

-0.44
0.23

A. OLS (1954-2002)

B. IV (1957-2002)

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

Table 5
Coefficient Estimates
(Euler Equation Specification, Instrumental Variable Estimates, 1957-2002)
First Difference of Levels

First Difference of Ratios

First Difference of Levels, Scaled

PC

NDS

PC

NDS

PC

NDS

Pre-Tax Income

0.47
0.22

0.39
0.21

0.98
0.32

0.90
0.29

0.34
0.19

0.31
0.20

Government
Purchases

0.30
0.37

0.24
0.33

0.30
0.37

0.23
0.35

0.23
0.26

0.25
0.27

Federal Taxes

-0.82
0.24

-0.65
0.22

-0.36
0.34

-0.31
0.32

-0.56
0.23

-0.44
0.23

State/Local Taxes

0.97
1.13

1.47
1.06

0.57
1.49

0.64
1.45

1.31
0.92

1.70
0.99

Government
Debt(t-1)

0.01
0.03

0.01
0.03

0.06
0.04

0.06
0.04

0.01
0.03

0.01
0.03

Wealth(t-1)

0.03
0.01

0.03
0.01

-0.01
0.01

-0.01
0.01

0.02
0.01

0.02
0.01

Marginal Tax
Rate on Capital*

1.97
1.77

1.15
1.57

-0.09
0.12

-0.10
0.11

0.06
0.07

0.02
0.07

Constant

0.09
0.07

0.05
0.06

0.00
0.00

0.00
0.00

0.01
0.00

0.00
0.00

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.
* Coefficient and standard error multiplied by 100.

Table 6
Regression Results for Real 5-Year-Ahead 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t+5)/GDP

1

2

3

4

0.049
0.016

Deficit(t+5)/GDP

5

6

7

8

0.056
0.018
0.293
0.068

Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

0.395
0.100

Recession

2.913
0.554
-0.043
0.025

Rec*Debt(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Deficit(t+5)/GDP

1.615
0.396

0.388
0.099

-0.531
0.130
0.391
0.141
1.128 -6.731
0.484 4.350

-0.292
0.133
0.430
0.219
0.719 6.555
0.334 6.634

0.870
1.031
-0.012
0.023

0.897
0.344

-0.099
0.053
-0.258
0.147

Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP

-0.152
0.075
0.380
0.127
0.057
0.173

Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Holdings
Treasury Purchases

Adjusted R-squared

12

0.282
0.072

-0.178
0.109

Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

Constant

11

0.445
0.091
-0.424
0.203
0.370
0.113

Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP

10

0.038
0.012
0.315
0.070

Revenues(t+5)/GDP

GDP growth rate(t+5)

9

0.555
0.438
1.335
1.593

0.278
0.300
3.666
0.806

0.185
0.289
4.809
0.799

0.204
0.264
5.767
4.878

0.296
0.406
1.629
1.687

0.034 -0.053 -0.001
0.233 0.205 0.208
4.168 5.377 7.880
0.689 0.494 3.684

0.213

0.436

0.408

0.386

0.463

0.642

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

0.641

0.636

0.030
0.157
-0.356
0.229
0.023
0.022
-0.377
0.175
-0.028
0.195

0.048 0.023 0.015
0.017 0.019 0.020
-0.283 -0.293 -0.338
0.161 0.134 0.143
-0.041 -0.079 0.012
0.179 0.141 0.148
-0.208
0.345
-0.743 -0.690 -0.602
0.755 0.741 0.821
0.152 0.346 0.363 0.311
0.585 0.521 0.526 0.554
3.522 4.261 4.999 2.586
2.276 0.924 0.880 5.275
0.679

0.779

0.773

0.758

Table 7
Regression Results for Nominal 5-Year-Ahead 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t+5)/GDP

1

2

3

4

0.035
0.019

Deficit(t+5)/GDP

5

6

7

8

0.056
0.020
0.250
0.096

Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

0.329
0.127

Recession

2.874
0.691
-0.042
0.026

Rec*Debt(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Deficit(t+5)/GDP

1.850
0.491

0.384
0.098

-0.527
0.126
0.398
0.256
1.201 -6.515
0.512 6.437

-0.229
0.123
0.458
0.238
0.750 9.254
0.347 7.462

0.988
0.432

-0.271
0.160

-0.149
0.074
0.375
0.130
0.050
0.254

Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Holdings
Treasury Purchases

Adjusted R-squared

1.243
1.168
-0.021
0.030

-0.105
0.057

Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP

Constant

-0.169 -0.078 -0.248 -0.265
0.598 0.443 0.385 0.378
1.327 1.184 1.236 1.275
0.172 0.194 0.179 0.165
2.740 4.057 5.088 7.874
1.907 0.875 0.722 3.774
0.813

0.854

0.853

12

0.281
0.073

-0.206
0.122

Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

Expected Inflation

11

0.464
0.112
-0.400
0.180
0.245
0.147

Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP

10

0.038
0.011
0.351
0.085

Revenues(t+5)/GDP

GDP growth rate(t+5)

9

0.851

0.273
0.525
1.012
0.151
1.678
1.851

0.274
0.370
0.858
0.153
3.939
0.739

0.042
0.333
0.940
0.149
5.340
0.506

0.011
0.378
0.989
0.225
7.671
5.871

0.854

0.906

0.903

0.900

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

-0.037
0.159
-0.430
0.263
0.031
0.021
-0.370
0.168
0.056
0.259

0.052 0.027 0.017
0.018 0.020 0.020
-0.244 -0.275 -0.330
0.136 0.134 0.142
0.055 0.011 0.051
0.275 0.230 0.235
-0.367
0.412
-0.786 -0.707 -0.615
0.702 0.733 0.804
0.228 0.393 0.372 0.335
0.635 0.551 0.552 0.594
0.809 0.878 0.949 0.847
0.278 0.209 0.203 0.228
4.103 3.989 4.883 0.668
2.050 1.157 1.123 6.100
0.914

0.941

0.938

0.935

Table 8
Regression Results for Real 5-Year-Ahead 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t+4)/GDP
Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
Revenues(t+5)/GDP
Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Recession
Rec*Debt(t+4)/GDP
Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Purchases
GDP growth rate(t+5)
Constant

Adjusted R-squared

1

2

3

4

5

6

-0.034 -0.038 -0.042 -0.046 -0.016 -0.017
0.028 0.033 0.028 0.030 0.027 0.043
0.541
0.648
0.475
0.176
0.156
0.177
-0.528
-0.661
-0.400
0.212
0.179
0.275
0.582
0.665
0.559
0.233
0.224
0.386
1.036 -5.343 1.315 4.925
1.366 4.138 0.825 7.757
-0.005 -0.008 -0.016 -0.013
0.028 0.022 0.019 0.020
-0.349
-0.163
0.195
0.156
0.397
0.083
0.179
0.268
-0.026
-0.280
0.208
0.279
0.003 0.005
0.020 0.034
-0.354 -0.380
0.152 0.187
0.077 0.015
0.143 0.167
-0.628 -0.561
0.749 0.844
-0.133 -0.186 -0.446 -0.501 0.307 0.305
0.440 0.426 0.277 0.315 0.601 0.620
7.235 6.547 8.429 8.676 5.947 3.337
2.347 4.848 1.852 3.994 2.127 5.651
0.416

0.393

0.662

0.664

0.761

0.738

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

Table 9
Regression Results for Real 5-Year-Ahead 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, ARMA
(1976-2004)

Variable

1

2

3

4

5

6

Debt(t+4)/GDP

-0.029 -0.038 -0.047 -0.047 -0.013 -0.010
0.031 0.034 0.026 0.026 0.017 0.019
Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
0.455
0.673
0.534
0.225
0.169
0.113
Revenues(t+5)/GDP
-0.442
-0.672
-0.508
0.219
0.171
0.154
Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
0.564
0.669
0.489
0.227
0.201
0.213
Recession
0.770 -5.549 0.512 1.688
1.511 3.597 0.854 4.807
Rec*Debt(t+4)/GDP
0.003 -0.003 0.013 0.015
0.033 0.029 0.021 0.022
Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
-0.385
-0.330
0.231
0.159
Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP
0.423
0.295
0.213
0.180
Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
-0.051
-0.368
0.243
0.245
Oil Price
-0.010 -0.003
0.020 0.029
Equity Premium
-0.447 -0.448
0.118 0.118
Defense Spending/GDP
0.029 0.032
0.063 0.085
Fed. Reserve Treasury Purchases
-0.330 -0.297
0.545 0.585
GDP growth rate(t+5)
-0.150 -0.250 -0.484 -0.506 0.775 0.734
0.429 0.407 0.213 0.259 0.560 0.565
Constant
6.941 5.388 8.748 8.871 5.365 5.448
2.346 4.761 1.701 3.375 1.332 3.147
ARMA
L.ar
Wald Chi-squared

0.331 0.346 -0.100 -0.061 -0.587 -0.588
0.308 0.280 0.210 0.214 0.239 0.232
52.409 56.816 419.01 71263 2751.6 39604

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

Table 10
Regression Results for Current Real 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t+5)/GDP

1

2

3

4

0.035
0.019

Deficit(t+5)/GDP

5

6

7

8

0.045
0.020
0.255
0.097

Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

0.319
0.152

Recession

4.393
0.826
-0.063
0.040

Rec*Debt(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Deficit(t+5)/GDP

2.579
0.746

0.169
0.155

-0.378
0.279
0.346
0.208
2.141 -9.671
0.907 9.527

-0.006
0.246
0.280
0.228
1.195 10.028
0.658 8.171

1.680
1.133
-0.027
0.031

1.211
0.786

-0.029
0.086
-0.224
0.282

Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP

0.038
0.132
0.329
0.276
0.344
0.320

Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Federal Holdings
Federal Purchases

Adjusted R-squared

12

0.175
0.100

-0.192
0.210

Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

Constant

11

0.360
0.109
-0.331
0.326
0.308
0.158

Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP

10

0.017
0.020
0.274
0.076

Revenues(t+5)/GDP

GDP growth rate(t+5)

9

0.783
0.508
0.510
1.817

0.662
0.410
1.887
1.123

0.558
0.408
2.914
1.143

0.566
0.400
3.321
7.498

0.386
0.410
0.973
1.792

0.267
0.279
2.714
0.897

0.177
0.277
3.770
0.769

0.167
0.356
4.396
7.498

0.028

0.181

0.135

0.100

0.410

0.498

0.464

0.478

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

-0.234
0.262
-0.250
0.248
0.047
0.042
-0.567
0.185
0.076
0.222

0.046 0.034 0.039
0.026 0.033 0.034
-0.437 -0.494 -0.506
0.163 0.177 0.178
-0.139 0.075 0.170
0.301 0.218 0.212
-0.985
0.344
-2.008 -1.941 -1.809
0.538 0.566 0.724
0.462 0.697 0.514 0.473
0.664 0.658 0.659 0.730
7.418 2.654 3.059 -1.652
2.573 0.911 0.945 5.919
0.755

0.781

0.763

0.751

Table 11
Regression Results for Current Nominal 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t+5)/GDP

1

2

3

4

0.002
0.022

Deficit(t+5)/GDP

5

6

7

8

0.025
0.024
0.108
0.120

Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

0.133
0.157

Recession

3.115
1.122
-0.041
0.038

Rec*Debt(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Deficit(t+5)/GDP

2.122
0.831

0.217
0.117

-0.587
0.222
-0.105
0.341
1.727 -22.057
0.897 9.284

-0.272
0.254
0.161
0.214
0.817 -1.307
0.328 9.465

0.778
0.432

-0.150
0.271

0.010
0.093
0.569
0.215
0.706
0.332

Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Holdings
Treasury Purchases

Adjusted R-squared

0.649
0.850
-0.002
0.022

0.001
0.064

Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP

Constant

-0.883 -0.569 -0.660 -0.693 -0.388 -0.200 -0.364 -0.526
0.646 0.586 0.520 0.480 0.669 0.573 0.516 0.498
1.753 1.637 1.666 1.739 1.398 1.277 1.340 1.623
0.227 0.268 0.250 0.229 0.249 0.268 0.253 0.300
3.741 3.240 3.700 8.984 2.573 3.161 3.980 16.428
2.033 1.159 0.948 5.489 2.151 1.066 0.783 8.615
0.809

0.818

0.817

12

0.178
0.082

-0.138
0.208

Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP

Expected Inflation

11

0.251
0.142
-0.268
0.255
-0.025
0.188

Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP

10

0.019
0.017
0.203
0.111

Revenues(t+5)/GDP

GDP growth rate(t+5)

9

0.819

0.843

0.858

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

0.854

0.874

0.046
0.271
0.063
0.281
0.011
0.034
-0.595
0.195
-0.275
0.203

0.035 0.014 0.012
0.021 0.025 0.027
-0.545 -0.578 -0.606
0.169 0.161 0.171
-0.404 -0.351 -0.295
0.293 0.181 0.189
-0.544
0.500
-1.804 -1.739 -1.758
0.794 0.804 0.794
0.252 0.475 0.397 0.373
0.670 0.610 0.610 0.658
1.527 1.579 1.608 1.642
0.249 0.200 0.196 0.256
5.814 3.948 4.454 6.400
3.048 1.002 0.930 7.141
0.940

0.957

0.954

0.949

Table 12
Regression Results for Current Real 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t+4)/GDP
Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
Revenues(t+5)/GDP
Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Recession
Rec*Debt(t+4)/GDP
Rec*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Revenues(t+5)/GDP
Rec*Primary Outlays(t+5)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Purchases
GDP growth rate(t+5)
Constant

Adjusted R-squared

1

2

3

4

5

6

-0.052 -0.062 -0.037 -0.050 0.019 0.017
0.039 0.041 0.033 0.031 0.028 0.037
0.541
0.527
0.085
0.276
0.194
0.198
-0.504
-0.479
0.026
0.344
0.344
0.348
0.660
0.655
0.209
0.312
0.281
0.304
3.677 -6.378 4.129 9.496
2.272 9.464 1.102 9.220
-0.050 -0.056 -0.076 -0.072
0.047 0.026 0.022 0.024
-0.162
0.304
0.309
0.174
0.180
-0.422
0.352
0.335
0.419
0.128
0.248
0.248
0.024 0.026
0.033 0.049
-0.547 -0.585
0.200 0.207
0.238 0.147
0.228 0.242
-2.199 -2.100
0.656 0.787
0.073 -0.081 -0.251 -0.493 0.745 0.741
0.559 0.495 0.342 0.474 0.837 0.903
6.611 4.615 6.654 4.636 1.868 -1.993
3.199 7.500 2.347 8.649 2.297 7.340
0.146

0.119

0.488

0.537

0.785

0.767

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

Table 13
Regression Results for Current Real 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Current-Period Fiscal Variables, OLS
(1976-2004)

Variable
Debt(t)/GDP

1

2

3

4

-0.029
0.031

Deficit(t)/GDP

5

6

7

8

0.034
0.023
0.165
0.115

Primary Deficit(t)/GDP

0.086
0.111

Recession

8.161
1.590
-0.161
0.040

Rec*Debt(t)/GDP
Rec*Deficit(t)/GDP

4.968
2.306

0.667
0.287
0.583
0.334
2.834 -23.329
1.374 11.876

2.411
2.231

0.205
0.288
0.269
0.460
0.336 -14.988
1.177 14.676

-0.515
0.535

Rec*Revenues(t)/GDP

0.249
0.929
-0.440
0.859
1.667
1.106

Rec*Primary Outlays(t)/GDP
Oil Price
Equity Premium
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Holdings
Treasury Purchases

Adjusted R-squared

3.776
1.874
-0.088
0.039

-0.050
2.052

-0.283 -0.293 -0.294 -0.086
0.179 0.171 0.180 0.139
6.100 4.617 5.045 -29.049
1.450 0.685 0.636 5.000
0.090

0.123

0.081

0.453

12

-0.062
0.137

-0.748
0.791

Rec*Primary Deficit(t)/GDP

Constant

11

0.020
0.145
-0.005
0.108

0.940
0.114
0.878
0.173

Primary Outlays(t)/GDP

10

-0.010
0.027
0.113
0.114

Revenues(t)/GDP

GDP growth rate(t)

9

0.086 -0.009
0.173 0.187
2.108 3.499
1.091 0.689

0.071 0.048
0.203 0.223
3.484 -19.215
0.754 10.761

0.351

0.245

0.287

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.

0.422

-0.118
0.949
0.909
1.044
0.041
0.032
-0.459
0.162
0.244
0.292

0.041 0.057 0.066
0.023 0.020 0.020
-0.410 -0.478 -0.432
0.111 0.124 0.130
-0.022 0.316 0.338
0.271 0.297 0.249
-1.087
0.301
-1.612 -1.523 -1.620
0.629 0.709 0.736
0.014 -0.059 -0.028 0.007
0.109 0.128 0.138 0.140
9.752 3.096 2.476 -5.023
2.598 1.126 1.318 11.283
0.771

0.739

0.731

0.726

Figure 1
Standardized and Actual Federal Budget Surplus, 1962-2004
(as a share of Potential GDP)

3
2

Percent of Potential GDP

1
0
-1
Standardized

-2
-3
-4

Actual

-5
-6
-7
1962

1967

Source: CBO (2004a, 2004b).

1972

1977

1982

Year

1987

1992

1997

2002

Figure 2
Unified and Adjusted Federal Budget Projections, 2004-2014
(as a share of GDP)
0
Unified Budget
-1

Surplus (% GDP)

-2
Adjust for Discretionary Spending,
Expiring Provisions, Index AMT
-3

Adjust for 2001 and 2003 Tax
Cuts and AMT Adjustment

-4

Adjust for Retirement
Trust Fund Surpluses

-5

-6
2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Source: Authors' calculations using CBO (2004a), imputed debt service using the CBO interest matrix, and the TPC Microsimulation Model.

2013

2014

Figure 3
Public Debt, 1950-2014
(as a share of GDP)
80

70

60

Percent of GDP

Adjusted Baseline
Adjusted, No Tax Cut

50

40
Unified Baseline
30

20

10

0
1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

Year
Source: Authors' calculations using CBO (2004a), imputed debt service using the CBO interest matrix, U.S. Budget (2004), and the TPC Microsimulation Model.

Figure 4
Entitlement Expenditures under Current Law, 2003-2080
(as a share of GDP)
14

12

10
Percent of GDP

Medicare

8
Social Security

6

4
Medicaid

2

0
2003

2008

2013

2018

Source: Auebach, Gale, and Orszag (2004).

2023

2028

2033

2038

2043

Year

2048

2053

2058

2063

2068

2073

2078

Figure 5
DEFICIT RISES

Private saving rises by 100% of the change in the deficit

Private saving rises by less than 100% of the change in the deficit

National saving constant

National saving falls

Future national income (GNP) constant

Future national income (GNP) falls

No capital inflow

Capital inflow
= 100 percent of fall in national saving Capital inflow
< 100 percent of fall in national saving GDP constant

GDP falls

Interest rates constant

Interest rates may rise or stay constant Interest rates rise

Exchange rate constant

Exchange rate appreciates Ricardian equivalence

Small open economy GDP constant

Exchange rate may appreciate or stay constant Conventional view Figure 6
Net Federal and National Saving, 1950-2003
(as a share of NNP)

Net national saving as percent of NNP

15

10

Net National saving

5

0

-5
Net Federal saving

-10
1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

Year

Source: National Income and Product Accounts Tables, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Figure 7
Net Domestic Investment and National Saving, 1950-2003
(as a share of NNP)
16

14

12

Percent of NNP

Net domestic investment
10

8

6

4
Net national saving
2

0
1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

Year
Source: National Income and Product Accounts Tables, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Figure 8
Forward 10-Year Interest Rates and Projected Deficits, 1976-2004
8.0
1985
1982

7.0

1983
6.0

1984

Forward 10-year real interest rate

1981

1980

1992
1991

5.0
2000
2001

4.0

1989
1986

2002
2003
1998

2004

1990

1993

1995
1996

1997
1988
1999 1994
1987

1976
3.0

1978

1977
1979

2.0

1.0

0.0
-5

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

Projected deficit in 5 years as a share of projected GDP

5

6

7

Figure 9
Forward 10-Year Interest Rates and Projected Debt, 1976-2004
8.0
1985
1982

7.0

1983
6.0

1984

Forward 10-year real interest rate

1981

1980

1992
1990

5.0
2000

1989 1988

2002

2001

4.0

1999

2003

1986
1998

2004

1993

1995
1996

1991
1997

1994

1987

1976
3.0

1978

1977
1979

2.0

1.0

0.0
0

10

20

30

40

50

Projected debt in 5 years as a share of projected GDP

60

70

Figure 10
Defense Spending, 1976-2003
(as a share of GDP)

7

6

Percent of GDP

5

4

3

2

1

0
1976

1981

1986

1991

Year

1996

2001

Appendix Table 1
Data sources for the Consumption Regressions
POP

– Total Population in millions
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 2.1, line 38]

NNPN

– Net National Product in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.7.5, line 14]

NNPR

– Net National Product in billions of 2000 dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.7.6, line 10]

CDN

– Personal Consumption Expenditure on Durable Goods in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.5, line 3]

CNDN

– Personal Consumption Expenditure on Non-durables in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.5, line 4]

CSN

– Personal Consumption Expenditure on Services in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.5, line 5]

DURN

– Net Stock of Consumer Durable Goods in billions of current dollars, year-end values
1929-01 [BEA Fixed Assets Tables Sep 2002 issue, Table 1.1, line 13]

PCD

– Implicit Price Deflator for Personal Consumption Expenditure on Durable Goods,
2000=1
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.9, line 3]

PCND

– Implicit Price Deflator for Personal Consumption Expenditure on Non-durables,
2000=1
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.9, line 4]

PCS

– Implicit Price Deflator for Personal Consumption Expenditure on Services, 2000=1
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.9, line 5]

TCR

– Total Personal Consumption Expenditure in billions of 2000 dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.6, line 2]

GSR

– Government Purchases of Goods and Services in billions of 2000 dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.6, line 20]

GSFN

– Federal Government Purchases in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.5, line 21]

PGSF

– Implicit Price Deflator for Federal Government Purchases, 2000=1
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 1.1.9, line 21]

TXN

– Total Government Receipts in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 1 minus Table 3.1 line 6 minus Table
3.1 line 10 minus Table 3.1 line 14 minus Table 3.2 line 13 minus Table 3.3 line 13]

TXFN

– Federal Government Receipts in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.2, line 1 minus line 10 minus line 13 minus line 18]

TRN

– Total Government Transfer Payments to Persons in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 19]

TRFN

– Federal Government Transfer Payments to Domestic Persons in billions of current dollars 1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.2, line 23]

GINTN

– Net interest paid by Government in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 22 minus Table 3.2 line 13 minus
Table 3.3 line 13]

GINTFN

– Net interest paid by Federal Government in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.2, line 28 minus line 13]

REN

– Undistributed Corporate Profits (Retained Earnings) with Inventory Valuation and
Capital Consumption Adjustments in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 5.1, line 5]

FRPROFN

– Federal Reserve Bank Profits paid to the US Treasury in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.2, line 8]

GDIV

– Corporate Dividends received by Government in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 10]

GINTFORN

– Government Interest paid to Foreigners in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 24]

NSUBN

– Government Subsidies to Businesses Net of Current Surplus of Government
Enterprises in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 25 minus line 14]

NSUBFN

– Federal Government Subsidies to Businesses Net of Current Surplus of Government
Enterprises in billions of current dollars
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.2, line 31 minus line 18]

TRFORN

– Government Transfer Payments to Foreigners
1929-02 [NIPA July 2004 issue, Table 3.1, line 20]

GBFN

– Market Value of Privately Held Gross Federal Debt in billions of dollars, Dec values
1942-01 [Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
]

GBSLN

– Aggregate Par Value of State and Local Debt Outstanding in billions of dollars, endof-June values
1940-02 [various issues of Statistical Abstract of the United States, Table
“Indebtedness and Debt Transactions of State and Local Governments”]

MBP

– Municipal Bond Price Index, Dec values
1930-01 [Standard and Poor’s Statistical Service 2001, P. 328, Dec column]

NWO

– Net Worth in billions of current dollars, year-end values
1945-01 [Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States (Z.1) Table B100 line43]

NBAS

– United States Non-Budget-Agency Government Securities Outstanding in billions of current dollars, year-end values
1945-01 [Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States (Z.1) Table B100 line16 minus line20] BAS

– Budget Agency Securities Outstanding in billions of current dollars, beginning of period, year-end values
1945-01 [Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States (Z.1) Table L210 line1]

SLS

– State and Local Government Securities Outstanding in billions of current dollars, year-end values
1945-01 [Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States (Z.1) Table L211 line2]

MTRK

– Marginal Effective Tax Rates on Capital Income
1953-03

PCt

= [ CNDNt / PCNDt + CSNt / PCSt + 0.3 X DURNt -1 / (0.5 X PCDt-1 + 0.5 X PCDt ) +
0.1 X CDNt / PCDt ] / POPt

PNNPt

= NNPN t / NNPR t

Ct

= (CNDNt / PCNDt + CSNt / PCSt) X TCCratio / POPt where TCCratio

= Average of [TCR / (CNDNt / PCNDt + CSNt / PCSt)] in sample period

Yt

= NNPRt / POPt

GSt

= [GSRt / POPt ] + [(TRFORN t + GINTFORN t ) / (PNNP t X POPt )]

GSFt

= [GSFNt / (PGSFt X POPt )] + [(TRFORN t + GINTFORN t ) / (PNNP t X POPt )]

TRt

= (TRNt + NSUBN t) / (PNNPt X POPt )

TRFt

= (TRFNt + NSUBFN t) / (PNNPt X POPt )

TXt

= (TXNt - FRPROFNt) / (PNNPt X POPt )

TXFt

= (TXFNt - FRPROFNt) / (PNNPt X POPt )

REt

= RENt / (PNNPt X POPt )

GBSLt-1 where MVSLt-1

= MVSLt-1 / (0.5 X PNNPt-1 X POPt-1 + 0.5 X PNNPt X POPt)
= (0.5 X GBSLNt-1 + 0.5 X GBSLNt ) X (MBPt-1 /100)

GBFt-1

= GBFNt-1 / (0.5 X PNNPt-1 X POPt-1+ 0.5 X PNNPt X POPt )

GBt-1

= GBFNt-1 + GBSLt-1

RGINTt where PIt
DRB t

= (GINTNt – GINTFORNt – FRPROFNt – DRBt – GDIVt) / (PNNPt X POPt )
= In [(PNNP t+1 + PNNPt) / (PNNPt + PNNP t-1)]
= PI t X [GBFN t-1 + (0.5 X GBSLNt-1 + 0.5 X GBSLNt ) X (MBPt-1 /100)]
= (GINTFNt – GINTFORNt – FRPROFNt – DRBFt ) / (PNNPt X POPt )

RGINTFt where DRBF t

= PI t X GBFN t-1

YDt

= Yt + TR t + TX t – RE t + RGINT t

YGt

= YDt + TX t

Wt-1

= WNt-1 / (0.5 X PNNPt-1 X POPt-1 + 0.5 X PNNPt X POPt ) where WNt-1

= NWOt-1 – NBASt-1 – BASt-1 – SLSt-1

Appendix Table 2
Coefficient Estimates
(Euler Equation Specification, Instrumental Variable Estimates, 1957-2002)
First Difference of Levels

First Difference of Ratios

First Difference of Levels, Scaled

PC

NDS

PC

NDS

PC

NDS

Pre-Tax

0.38
0.09

0.35
0.08

0.58
0.16

0.57
0.15

0.35
0.08

0.35
0.07

Government
Expenditure

0.15
0.16

0.09
0.13

0.15
0.15

0.12
0.14

-0.04
0.10

-0.05
0.10

Federal Taxes

-0.44
0.15

-0.31
0.13

-0.79
-0.79

-0.71
0.17

-0.33
0.13

-0.27
0.12

State/Local Taxes

0.86
0.60

1.00
0.51

1.06
0.62

1.22
0.58

0.75
0.44

0.94
0.41

Government
Debt(t-1)

-0.03
0.02

-0.02
0.02

-0.01
0.03

0.00
0.03

-0.01
0.02

-0.01
0.02

Wealth(t-1)

0.01
0.01

0.01
0.01

0.02
0.01

0.01
0.01

0.01
0.01

0.01
0.01

Marginal Tax Rate on Capital*

0.71
0.58

0.54
0.49

0.03
0.04

0.03
0.03

0.04
0.02

0.03
0.02

Constant

0.14
0.03

0.11
0.03

0.00
0.00

0.00
0.00

0.01
0.00

0.01
0.00

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; robust standard errors in regular font. N=29.
* Coefficient and standard error multiplied by 100.

Appendix Table 3
Empirical studies of deficits and interest rates
Predominately positive significant effect
Expected or unanticipated deficit
1. Makin and Tanzi (1984)
2. Feldstein (1986)
3. Wachtel and Young (1987)
4. Bovenberg (1988)
5. Thomas and Abderrezak (1988a)
6. Thomas and Abderrezak (1988b)
7. Barth and Bradley (1989)
8. Thorbecke (1993)
9. Elmendorf (1993)
10. Elmendorf (1996)
11. Kitchen (1996)
12. Canzoneri, Cumby, and Diba (2002)
13. Laubach (2003)

Mixed effect

Predominately insignificant effect

1. Sinai and Rathjens
(1983)
2. Kim and Lombra
(1989)
3. Cohen and Garnier
(1991)
4. Quigley and
Porter-Hudak
(1994)
5. Engen and
Hubbard (2004)

1. Bradley (1986)

1. Mountford and
Uhlig (2000)
2. Perotti (2002)
3. Engen and
Hubbard (2004)

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.

1. Echols and Elliott
(1976)
2. Dewald (1983)
3. Tanzi (1985)
4. Zahid (1988)
5. Coorey (1992)

1. Feldstein and Chamberlain
(1973)
2. Canto and Rapp (1982)
3. Frankel (1983)
4. Hoelscher (1983)
5. Makin (1983)
6. Mascaro and Meltzer (1983)
7. Motley (1983)
8. Tatom (1984)
9. U.S. Treasury (1984)
10. Giannaros and Kolluri (1985)
11. Kolluri and Giannaros (1987)
12. Swamy et al (1988)
13. Calomiris, Engen, Hassett, and
Hubbard (2004)

VAR-based dynamics
1. Miller and Russek (1991)
2. Tavares and Valkanov (2001)
3. Dai and Phillipon (2004)

Current deficit or debt
1. Feldstein and Eckstein (1970)
2. Kudlow (1981)
3. Carlson (1983)
4. Hutchison and Pyle (1984)
5. Muller and Price (1984)
6. Barth, Iden, and Russek (1985)
7. de Leew and Hollaway (1985)
8. Hoelscher (1986)
9. Cebula (1987)
10. Cebula (1988)
11. Cebula and Koch (1989)
12. Cebula and Koch (1994)
13. Miller and Russek (1996)
14. Kitchen (2002)
15. Kiley (2003)
16. Cebula (2000)

Plosser (1982)
Evans (1985)
Evans (1987a)
Evans (1987b)
Plosser (1987)
Evans (1989)

Appendix Table 4
Data sources for the Consumption Regressions

CBO projections (provided by Laubach)1
Debt(t+5)/GDP

CBO's projected 5-year-ahead debt held by the public as percent of GDP.

Debt(t+4)/GDP

CBO's projected 4-year-ahead debt held by the public as percent of GDP.

Deficit(t+5)/GDP

CBO's projected 5-year-ahead deficit (+) or surplus (-) as percent of GDP.

Primary
Deficit(t+5)/GDP

CBO's projected 5-year-ahead deficit (+) or surplus (-) as percent of GDP less projected 5-year-ahead net interest payments as percent of GDP.

Revenues(t+5)/GDP CBO’s projected 5-year-ahead total revenues.
GDP Growth
Rate(t+5)

CBO's projected 5-year-ahead real GDP growth.

Primary
Outlays(t+5)/GDP

CBO's projected 5-year-ahead total outlays as percent of GDP less projected 5year-ahead net interest payments as percent of GDP.

Interest rate and inflation series (provided by Laubach)
Expected Inflation

We use the expected inflation series constructed by Laubach (2003). The series consists of three different pieces. Until 1981:Q1, the series is an estimated step function based on the changepoint model developed in Kozicki and Tinsley
(2001). From 1981:Q2 until 1991:Q2, the series is based on the Hoey survey of decision makers which polled participants for their expectations of CPI inflation ten years ahead. Since 1991:Q3 the series is based on the Survey of Professional
Forecasters conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, in which participants are asked for their expectations of CIP inflation over the next ten years. The series is extrapolated to monthly frequency, and is sampled in the months corresponding to the yield data. (Laubach, 2003)

Nominal 10-year constant maturity
Treasury yield

Conventional definition; sampled on the last trading day of the month of the CBO release. (provided by Laubach).

Real 10-year constant maturity

Nominal 10-year constant maturity Treasury yield – Expected Inflation.

1 The CBO projections data, compiled by Laubach, are based on CBO’s annual publication “The Budget and Economic Outlook”. For the early years, the CBO did not publish projections for federal debt held by the public; those projections are computed by adding the CBO’s deficit projections for the current and next five fiscal years to the stock of debt held by the public at the end of the previous year. For the years 19761982 estimates are based on the assumption of no policy change. The January 1991 projections are based on the already legislated discretionary spending caps, which were the CBO’s baseline for the remainder of the 1990s. (Laubach, 2003)

Treasury yield fw59_c Average of one-year forward rates 5-9 years ahead, calculated from the zerocoupon yield curve, sampled on the last trading day of the month of the CBO release. fw1014_c

Average of one-year forward rates 10-14 years ahead, calculated from the zerocoupon yield curve, sampled on the last trading day of the month of the CBO release. Nominal 5-Year
Ahead 10-Year
Treasury Rate

The average of fw59_c and fw1014_c. [ (fw59_c+fw1014_c)/2 ]

Real 5-Year Ahead
10-Year Treasury
Rate

Nominal 5-Year Ahead 10-Year Treasury Rate – Expected Inflation.

Equity Premium

Calculated as the dividend component of national income, expressed as percent of the market value of corporate equity held (directly or indirectly) by households, minus the real 10-year Treasury yield, plus CBO's projected 5-year-ahead real
GDP growth The value of the premium in the quarter prior to the release of the projections is used. (Laubach, 2003)

Dividend/Market
Value

Equity Premium - GDP growth rate(t+5) + Real 10-year constant maturity
Treasury yield.

Realized fiscal and economic variables
Debt(t)/GDP

Actual debt held by the public as percent of GDP, end of year. Data for 1976-2003 provided by Laubach. Source for 2004 projection: Budget of the U.S. Government,
Fiscal Year 2005, Mid-Session Review.

Deficit(t)/GDP

Actual deficit (+) or surplus (-) as percent of actual GDP. Data for 1976-2003 provided by Laubach. Source for 2004 projection: Budget of the U.S. Government,
Fiscal Year 2005, Mid-Session Review.

Primary
Deficit(t)/GDP

Actual deficit less net interest payments as percent of GDP. Source for net interest series, 1976-2003: The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2005-2014,
Appendix F, Historical Budget Data, Table 6. Source for 2004 projection: Budget of the U.S. Government, Fiscal Year 2005, Mid-Session Review.

Revenues(t)/GDP

Actual revenues as percent of GDP. Source for 1976-2003 data: The Budget and
Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2005-2014, Appendix F, Historical Budget Data,
Table 2. Source for 2004 projection: Budget of the U.S. Government, Fiscal Year
2005, Mid-Session Review.

Primary
Outlays(t)/GDP

Total outlays less net interest payments as percent of GDP. Source for 1976-2003 data: The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2005-2014, Appendix F,
Historical Budget Data, Table 5. Source for 2004 projection: Budget of the U.S.

Government, Fiscal Year 2005, Mid-Session Review.
GDP Growth
Rate(t)

Real GDP growth rate in current year. Source for 1976-2003 data: NIPA Table
1.1.1. (Percent Change From Preceding Period in Real Gross Domestic Product, line 1.) Source for 2004 projection: Budget of the U.S. Government, Fiscal Year
2005, Mid-Session Review.

Control Variables
Oil Price

Crude Oil Spot Price, dollars per barrel: West Texas Intermediate, average annual price (based on monthly data) for previous year. Source: The Financial Forecast
Center, reprinted from Dow Jones Energy Service. Current dollars converted to
2000 dollars using implicit price deflator for GDP (NIPA table 1.1.9, line 1).

Recession

Dummy variable equal to 1 if the economy was in recession in the month of CBO release. Source for data on business cycle: National Bureau of Economic Research, available at http://www.nber.org/cycles.html/.

Defense
Spending/GDP

Defense spending as percent of GDP, in current year. Source: The Budget and
Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2005-2014, Appendix F, Historical Budget Data,
Table 8.

Treasury Holdings

Monetary Authority holdings of U.S. Treasury Securities as percent of nominal
GDP, end of previous year. Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States,
Historical Data. Table L.108 Monetary Authority, line 10 (Treasury Securities).
Available at: http://federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/data.htm
Source for nominal GDP series: NIPA table 1.1.5 (Gross Domestic Product, line 1)

Treasury Purchases

Monetary Authority net acquisition of U.S. Treasury Securities as percent of nominal GDP, end of previous year. Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the
United States, Historical Data. Table F.108 Monetary Authority, line 12 (Treasury
Securities). Available at: http://federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/data.htm
Source for nominal GDP series: NIPA table 1.1.5 (Gross Domestic Product, line 1)

GDP Gap

The difference between Actual and Potential GDP as percent of Potential GDP.
Source of Actual and Potential GDP series for 1976-2003 fiscal years: The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2005-2014, Appendix F, Historical Budget
Data, Table 11. Forecast for 2004 Actual GDP is taken from The Budget and
Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2005-2014, Appendix E, Table E-2. Projected
Potential GDP for fiscal year 2004 estimated from CBO’s report “The Cyclically
Adjusted and Standardized-Budget Measures”, Table 1, by averaging the implicit
Potential GDP amounts from lines 1, 3, and 5.

Appendix Table 5
Date of Release of CBO Budget Projections
Month

Year

January
December
January
January
February
July
February
February
February
February
February
January
February
January
January
January
January
January
January
January
May
January
January
January
January
January
January
January
January

1976
1976
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004

Appendix Table 6
Regression Results for Real 5-Year-Ahead 10-Year Treasury Rate
Using Projected Fiscal Variables, (1976-2004), ARMA
Sensitivity Analysis Using Alternative Measures of Economic Activity and Risk Adjustments

Variable
Debt(t+4)/GDP
Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
Recession
Recession*Debt(t+4)/GDP
Recession*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
GDP Gap
GDP Gap*Debt(t+4)/GDP
GDP Gap*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
GDP Gap(t-1)
GDP Gap(t-1)*Debt(t+4)/GDP
GDP Gap(t-1)*Primary Deficit(t+5)/GDP
Equity Premium
Dividend/Market Value
Oil Price
Defense Spending/GDP
Treasury Purchases
GDP growth rate(t+5)
Constant

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

-0.013 -0.051 -0.008 0.009 -0.018 -0.069 -0.015 0.000 -0.019 -0.067
0.017 0.020 0.025 0.023 0.021 0.017 0.022 0.018 0.023 0.020
0.534 0.520 0.353 0.224 0.438 0.573 0.332 0.238 0.428 0.572
0.113 0.123 0.139 0.110 0.169 0.173 0.157 0.099 0.156 0.174
0.512
0.275
0.127
0.854
1.125
1.204
0.013
0.005
0.007
0.021
0.023
0.025
-0.330
-0.215
-0.217
0.159
0.183
0.183
-0.809
-0.912
-0.911
0.209
0.305
0.302
0.021
0.023
0.023
0.005
0.006
0.006
-0.112
-0.120
-0.120
0.022
0.033
0.033
-0.636
-0.620
0.218
0.269
0.015
0.015
0.006
0.007
-0.069
-0.062
0.030
0.034
-0.447 -0.271 -0.310 -0.283
0.118 0.086 0.116 0.144
-0.043 0.022 -0.037 0.080
0.129 0.085 0.143 0.120
-0.010 0.057 0.047 0.052 0.042 0.075 0.069 0.065 0.043 0.076
0.020 0.008 0.012 0.013 0.013 0.012 0.008 0.010 0.013 0.009
0.029 -0.005 0.041 -0.007 -0.070 -0.073 -0.024 -0.121 -0.084 -0.069
0.063 0.068 0.096 0.103 0.089 0.086 0.116 0.102 0.095 0.088
-0.330 -1.200 -1.337 -0.879 -0.846 -1.217 -1.555 -0.903 -0.766 -1.273
0.545 0.347 0.856 0.596 0.596 0.485 1.071 0.680 0.542 0.398
0.775 -0.424 0.141 0.008 -0.603 -1.267 -0.694 -0.767 -0.647 -1.243
0.560 0.327 0.517 0.575 0.270 0.212 0.400 0.298 0.231 0.190
5.365 8.281 5.042 4.445 7.284 10.287 6.564 5.905 7.254 10.234
1.332 1.334 1.882 1.827 1.485 1.075 1.737 1.323 1.529 1.166

11
-0.016
0.023
0.324
0.143

12
0.001
0.018
0.241
0.103

-0.596
0.215
0.015
0.006
-0.060
0.031

0.067 0.069
0.008 0.009
-0.034 -0.094
0.108 0.105
-1.457 -1.040
0.760 0.596
-0.724 -0.736
0.376 0.280
6.542 5.949
1.753 1.239

ARMA
L.ar
Wald Chi-squared

-0.587 -0.530 -0.333 -0.218 -0.183 -0.423 -0.221 -0.050 -0.155 -0.432 -0.190 -0.105
0.239 0.213 0.261 0.261 0.253 0.227 0.299 0.197 0.212 0.204 0.254 0.183
2751.6 889.6 679.8 259.5 703.1 499.8 416.3 247.1 588.3 505.3 320.6 219.6

Note: Estimation coefficients in bold; semi-robust standard errors in regular font. N = 29.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

The Clinton Administration

...Greenspan used in convincing Clinton that deficit reduction was an essential policy goal, it still remains a fact that deficits were reduced and (briefly) turned into surpluses over the eight years of the Clinton Presidency. In January of 2001, the Council of Economic Advisers made the following argument: The Omnibus Budget and Reconciliation Act of 1993 was the right policy package at the right time … long-term interest rates remained stubbornly high. … Bond yields were being predictably affected by the forces of supply and demand: the Federal Government was set to run a deficit of almost $300 billion … With an oversupply of government bonds and the prospect of even more to come, bond and stock prices were depressed, and yields were correspondingly high… In 1992, the new Administration was elected on a promise to turn the deficits around. After a tough political battle in 1993, the Administration was able to deliver on that promise … The markets responded quickly to this serious effort to address the deficit by lowering expectations of future inflation, and long-term interest rates accordingly fell…. As economic growth and further restraints on spending … turned the huge deficits into surpluses, a new fiscal environment emerged. The 10-year Treasury rate fell below 6 percent in 1998 and 1999… that rate stood at only 5.7 percent in November 2000. … Ultimately, the combination of falling prices for investment goods and reduced interest costs stimulated dramatic growth in...

Words: 4161 - Pages: 17

Free Essay

Balanced Budget

...Balanced Budget Todd Driscoll ECO 203 Principles of Macroeconomics Instructor: Jason Friedline October 23, 2012 Balanced Budget Economists generally agree that high budget deficits today will reduce the growth rate of the economy of the future. The difference between what a government spends and what it collects in taxes in a given period is known as a budget deficit. There are many reasons why this might happen. One might be that if our government keeps spending money that does not exist obviously the more debt will accumulate. The government cannot keep this up without creating more debt. It the same as budgeting you personal accounts. If you get a new credit card or loan to consolidate old debt and then re-use your old cards, it rather defeats the purpose of getting out of debt. Another reason might be that due to the enormous loss of jobs there are less taxes being paid to pay our nations bills or to re-invest back into the economy. There is no point to list these reason in number order there are so many. If the deficit is growing it affects the nation savings, in turn, reduces national income. This may become possible if interest rates go up or domestic investments fall. Economists agree these a few things on when it comes to a high deficit. Deficits over a short period do not really have much affect, because the United States can borrow to cover these gaps due to the dollar’s value as the leading currency. If the deficit is sustained over a long period...

Words: 1940 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Eco 372 Week 4 Reflection

...how deficits, surpluses, and debt in relation to the macroeconomic health of the United States. A government deficit is when federal spending is greater that the tax revenue received for that year.  Each year the deficit is added to the current debt, the Treasury must sell bonds to raise the money to cover deficit.  At first, the deficit spending does boost economic growth.  As we have read in the previous weeks, government spending does have a positive effect on the economy; it lowers interest rates, increasing the money supply available, and creates jobs, which lowers the unemployment rate.  However, if the deficit is added to the national debt this is very damaging to the economy because the government can let the value of the U.S. dollar fall, this would make the debt repayment cheaper and less expensive.  This will have a negative effect on foreign government and how investors view the strength of our Treasury bonds, and they will be reluctant to purchase Treasury bonds, this will cause an increase in the interest rates.  When creditors become concerned about a country's ability to repay its debt, they demand a higher interest rate to provide a greater return on this higher risk investment.   Treasury bills, notes and bonds are used to finance budget deficits, if foreign government and investors do not purchase them, the U.S. will have difficulty raising money to continue to finance the deficit On the other hand, a budget surplus is the opposite of a budget deficit. A...

Words: 403 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Fiscal Deficit on Economic Activity Last 4 Years in Australia

...large a fiscal deficit during the past 4 years particularly in light of their projections for the Australian economy which were made when the first stimulus package was announced in 2008". Discuss this assertion and the consequences of this fiscal deficit on economic activity during the past 4 years. What are the implications of your analysis for Australia's fiscal policy during the next 3 years? EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Global Financial Crisis (GFC) evolved from its origin in subprime mortgage crisis of United States and affected almost every country in the world. Australia entered into GFC with a strong position, as compared to the other OECD countries. Australian government implemented stimulus packages in order to deal with the situation. This reports looks at the consequences of the fiscal deficit on economic activity and its implications for Australia’s fiscal policy. Its direct impact on Australia was small – mostly increases in bank borrowing costs The case for fiscal stimulus was based on Keynesian model, which proposes a short term government spending to stimulate the economy during the recessionary period. However, Basic Keynesian model assumes that the exchange rate is fixed. The analysis shows that significant contributor for GDP (expenditure) was net exports over that period, not the consumption. This increase in demand was due to the depreciated Australian dollar and the strong demand for resources from China. Further, recent Australian National University (ANU)...

Words: 4684 - Pages: 19

Premium Essay

Sandwich Blitz Unit 6 Essay

...1) The companies allow many workers to hold large amounts of stock at work because of the reason that they want the productivity of the workers to increase. Since the workers are getting a higher payment from the company they are encouraged to put more effort. The people might not want to hold stock in the company where he works because he might not want to have a higher payment in the company. The worker might not want to get joined to the performance of the company. 2) a. It is strenuous to decrease taxes on private saving and reduce government shortage at the same time because a reduction in taxes expands budget debt which is just opposite of the second measure. b. If sufficient connection were to be found between decrease in tax rates...

Words: 502 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Gdp Signature Assignment

...scarce resources? Is it about inflation, unemployment, and government budget deficits? Is it about eliminating poverty? All of the above are important topics in the study of economics. The main objective of economic research is its ability to explain how we can most optimally achieve the highest standard of living. Thus: Economics is the study of how we can best increase a nation's wealth with the resources that we have available to us. In our country and other relatively free-market economies, the decision as to what and how much to produce is made primarily by the buyers and sellers of the products. The government exerts relatively little control over prices of products. Some say that this is the nation’s wealth, but is it? Wealth by definition includes tangible products, such as cars and houses, as well as intangible products, such as more leisure time and cleaner air. The biggest question associated with wealth, is how to increase it. Some economists support government involvement, price controls, and government rules and regulations. Others believe that government involvement should be minimal and limited to tasks including the provision of a legal system, military, police and fire protection, and providing certain public goods. Many believe that a combination of moderate government involvement and private initiative works best. There is a lot of controversy about the role of profits, consumer spending, savings,...

Words: 2035 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Deficit Financing Theory and Practice in Bangladesh

...Assignment DEFICIT FINANCING: TEORY AND PRACTICE IN BANGLADESH Submitted By Zahirul Islam [pic] DEFICIT FINANCING: TEORY AND PRACTICE IN BANGLADESH INTRODUCTION In the past as today, the deficit budget policy is famous instrument of fiscal policy used to increase the rate of economic growth of the country. That way of financing was establish after the two world wars, oil crises and current financial and economic crises. The objective in seeking deficit financing is to finance the shortfall between government expenditures and tax receipts. Tax increases are not politically palatable. Governments often resort to deficit financing when other components of GDP such as private consumption decline during recessionary periods. Such deficits, if undertaken for a short period with an action plan to create equivalent surplus in near future, could reverse decline in real GDP and stimulate growth in real GDP for the benefit of citizens of the nation. Structural deficits are indicative of inability to reduce entrenched government expenses. The sustainable level of accumulated deficits can also be determined with reference to both the deficit servicing requirements and deficit servicing sources. This analysis will entail identification of cause and effect relationships that determine the factors influencing each of these two areas. As shown by other researchers, the explanatory variables leading to deficits include domestic budgetary receipts;...

Words: 5493 - Pages: 22

Free Essay

Balanced National Budget

...When national revenues total equals to or exceed total expense in a fiscal year denotes a balanced budget. Emphasis needs mentioning that a balanced budget refers to either a situation where there is neither a budget deficit nor a budget surplus. Put simply, revenues equal expenses or exceed costs, but not where expenses exceed revenues. Proponents of a balanced national budget uphold it will condense interest rates, increase savings and investments and further economic growth with favorable balance of trade deficits. Rather, Keynesian arguments against a balanced national budget appeal to the reasoning given that public sector operations usually have multiple and conflicting objectives with no standard measure of the returns of innumerable programs (Mikesell, 2014). However, adherence to a rigid balanced national budget might jeopardize the most potent of means to an efficient economy, opening risks of slower growth, increased unemployment, poverty, and inequality. Further, a balanced budget might limit government's ability to use countercyclical fiscal policy forcing spending cuts when a stimulus is most needed. Recessions would be longer and more severe, and long-term growth prospects worsen. A balanced national budget would be a national security disaster, as wars and other national security initiatives cost money, and a balanced budget will result in significant tax increases in case of emergencies. Most economists agree that the federal government needs to spend more...

Words: 598 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Fiscal Policy

...Topic 4 – Fiscal Policy Refers to the governments choices regarding the overall level of government purchases or taxes * Government spending – on health sector, education, infrastructure, defence. * Taxation policy – income tax, sales tax (VAT), corporate tax, capital gains tax. Fiscal policy and aggregate demand * Government spending – increase in G spending → AD shifting right * e.g. Gov places £10 billion order for new school buildings → building contractor has increased demand for output → hires more staff and increases production. * Taxation – * Income tax cut → consumption increases → AD shifting right * Corporate tax cut → investment increases → AD shifting right * If tax cuts are seen as temp then AD shift may be smaller Multiplier Effect The additional shifts in aggregate demand that result when expansionary fiscal policy increases income and thereby increases consumer spending. * Example continued… * Positive impact - The Gov buys £10 billion of buildings from Bob and Co, → demand from gov raises employment and profits at Bob and Co → as workers see higher earnings and firm owners see higher profits → increase own spending on consumer goods and so on… This is the multiplier effect. * Negative impact could be that spending on foreign goods may increase → neg impact on AD as imports increase. * Size of multiplier depends on marginal propensity to consume and import. * SHOW IMPACT OF MULTIPLIER...

Words: 894 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

National Debt in Usa

...National Debt in the U.S.A Name Professor Institution Course Date ABSTRACT The fast increase in the National government debt is becoming of interest to decision makers and the citizens of the USA. This paper examines the implications of the increasing debt financing to the economy of the United States. The proportion of the U.S.A National debt is rising in comparison to the National GDP. In the past decade, the USA Treasury has been borrowing trillions of dollars from both foreign investors and its citizens to help fund wars save the financial system as well as promote the economic development of the country. Does the increasing debt have any impact on economy? This paper will explain that an appropriate analysis on the United States debt is important to cope up with this worrying trend. INTRODUCTION In general, debt can be viewed as something specific in nature which the creditor and debtor can’t control at will. The United States National debt has been increasing at an average rate of about $1.64 billion each day since September, 2004 (Lucas, 2005). Manuel estimates that every human being in the United States currently owes $56,651 for their share of the U.S.A public debt. As at 27th October 2013, the total National debt of the United States was $ 17,211,829,040,346.01 (Manuel, 2013). This is an indication of how the national debt in the United States of America has been rising in the recent years. Recently...

Words: 1380 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Economic

...Chapter 36 Five Debates over Macroeconomic Policy 1. Stabilization policy is useful because a. there is no reason for society to suffer through the booms and busts of the business cycle. b. the economy would stabilize itself too quickly without government intervention. c. there are significant lags due to the nature of the political process. d. All of the above are correct. ANSWER: a there is no reason for society to suffer through the booms and busts of the business cycle. SECTION: 1 OBJECTIVE: 1 2. The Federal Reserve will tend to tighten monetary policy when a. interest rates are rising too rapidly. b. it thinks the unemployment rate is too high. c. the growth rate of real GDP is quite sluggish. d. it thinks inflation is too high today, or will become too high in the future. ANSWER: d it thinks inflation is too high today, or will become too high in the future. SECTION: 1 OBJECTIVE: 1 3. If the Federal Reserve loosened monetary policy today because it believed a recession was going to hit the economy in about one year, this is an indication that the Fed a. is undertaking an inappropriate monetary policy. b. recognizes the problem of lags. c. recognizes the fact that money is neutral. d. is conducting a procyclical monetary policy. ANSWER: b recognizes the problem of lags. SECTION: 1 OBJECTIVE: 1 4. When economists say that there is a time lag in the effect of monetary...

Words: 1782 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Income Tax India

...Lawrence Summers for comments on an earlier draft. Elmendorf was formerly Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Treasury in the Office of Economic Policy, and prior to that Senior Economist at the Council of Economic Advisers; Liebman was formerly Special Assistant to the President for Economic Policy at the National Economic Council; and Wilcox was formerly Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy. Table of Contents Page 1. Introduction 2. Budget Outcomes and Projections Improved Budget Picture Sources of Improvement 3. Budget Deficit Reduction: 1990 through 1997 OBRA90 OBRA93 What Did Deficit Reduction Ultimately Accomplish? The Republican-Controlled Congress BBA97 4. Entitlement Reform and Saving Social Security First Entitlement Commissions Social Security Saving Social Security First 5. Social Security Reform Options Using Projected Budget Surpluses as Part of Social Security Reform Investments in Private Financial Assets Potential Compromise Reform Proposals The 1999 State of the Union Social Security Proposal 6. Budget Surpluses: 1998 through 2000 The 1999 State of the Union Budget Framework Balancing the Budget Excluding Social Security Fiscal Policy in 2000 A National Asset 7. Conclusion References Tables Figures 1 3 9 24 40 63 78 80 84...

Words: 25267 - Pages: 102

Free Essay

Economic Terms

...there is more money going out of the economy than coming in thus resulting to lower GDP figures. B. Demographic Transition Model Birth and death rates are both low, leading to a total population which is high and stable. Death rates are low for a number of reasons, primarily lower rates of diseases and higher production of food. The birth rate is low because people have more opportunities to choose if they want children; this is made possible by improvements in contraception or women gaining more independence and work opportunities. C. Trade Account The trade balance/ trade account is the amount a country receives for the export of goods and services minus the amount it pays for its imports of goods and services. Current Account The difference between a nation’s savings and its investment. The current account is an important indicator about an economy's health. It is defined as the sum of the balance of trade (goods and services exports less imports), net income from abroad and net current transfers. A positive current account balance indicates that the nation is a net lender to the rest of the world, while a negative current account balance indicates that it is a net borrower from the rest of the world. A current account surplus increases a nation’s net foreign assets by the amount of the surplus, and a current account deficit decreases it by that amount. The current account...

Words: 1855 - Pages: 8

Free Essay

The Do-Com Bubble

...This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: G7 Current Account Imbalances: Sustainability and Adjustment Volume Author/Editor: Richard H. Clarida, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-10726-4 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/clar06-2 Conference Date: June 1-2, 2005 Publication Date: May 2007 Title: The Dot-Com Bubble, the Bush Deficits, and the U.S. Current Account Author: Aart Kraay, Jaume Ventura URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c0124 11 The Dot-Com Bubble, the Bush Deficits, and the U.S. Current Account Aart Kraay and Jaume Ventura 11.1 Introduction Since the early 1990s, the United States has experienced steadily widening current account deficits, reaching 5.7 percent of gross national product (GNP) in 2004 (see top panel of figure 11.1). These deficits are large relative to the postwar U.S. historical experience. With the exception of a brief period in the mid-1980s where current account deficits reached 3.3 percent of GNP, the U.S. current account has typically registered small surpluses or deficits averaging around 1 percent of GNP. As a consequence of the recent deficits, the U.S. net foreign asset position has declined sharply from –5 percent of GNP in 1995 to about –26 percent by the end of 2004 (see bottom panel of figure 11.5). The goal of this paper is to provide an account of this decline that relates it to other major macroeconomic events and helps us to...

Words: 17727 - Pages: 71

Premium Essay

Economics

...or transfers should be changed. 3. Explain why an equal increase (decrease) in government purchases and net taxes (taxes minus transfers) has an expansionary (contractionary) effect. 4. What is the balanced budget multiplier? 5. Explain why discretionary fiscal policy has not been very effective in reducing recessions in the United States. 6. What are the “time lags”? 7. What is meant by "automatic stabilization"? What are the main automatic stabilizers? 8. What is meant by "official budget deficit"? by "structural deficit"? Why is the structural budget deficit a better measure of the intent of fiscal policy? 9. What does it mean that "fiscal policy is expansionary (or contractionary)"? How does one determine whether fiscal policy is expansionary or contractionary? 10. In what ways might budget deficits be bad for an economy? In what ways might they be good for an economy? 11. What is meant by “crowding-out”? 12. Explain the relation between the budget deficits and the trade deficits. 13. What is meant by the "national debt"? What is the difference between "budget deficit" and "national debt"? What is the difference between "gross national debt" and "net national debt"? 14. What is the difference between a Treasury bill, a Treasury note, and a...

Words: 9913 - Pages: 40