Free Essay

Dynamics

In:

Submitted By DUXIN
Words 11290
Pages 46
Q U A N T I T A T I V E F I N A N C E V O L U M E 2 (2002) 45–60 INSTITUTE O F PHYSICS PUBLISHING

RE S E A R C H PA P E R quant.iop.org Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces
Rama Cont1,3 and Jos´ da Fonseca2 e
Centre de Math´ matiques Appliqu´ es, Ecole Polytechnique, F-91128 e e Palaiseau, France 2 Ecole Superieure d’Ingenierie Leonard de Vinci, F-92916 Paris La D´ fense, e France E-mail: Rama.Cont@polytechnique.fr and jose.da fonseca@devinci.fr Received 20 September 2001
Published 4 February 2002 Online at stacks.iop.org/Quant/2/45
1

Abstract
The prices of index options at a given date are usually represented via the corresponding implied volatility surface, presenting skew/smile features and term structure which several models have attempted to reproduce. However, the implied volatility surface also changes dynamically over time in a way that is not taken into account by current modelling approaches, giving rise to ‘Vega’ risk in option portfolios. Using time series of option prices on the SP500 and FTSE indices, we study the deformation of this surface and show that it may be represented as a randomly fluctuating surface driven by a small number of orthogonal random factors. We identify and interpret the shape of each of these factors, study their dynamics and their correlation with the underlying index. Our approach is based on a Karhunen–Lo` ve e decomposition of the daily variations of implied volatilities obtained from market data. A simple factor model compatible with the empirical observations is proposed. We illustrate how this approach models and improves the well known ‘sticky moneyness’ rule used by option traders for updating implied volatilities. Our approach gives a justification for use of ‘Vega’s for measuring volatility risk and provides a decomposition of volatility risk as a sum of contributions from empirically identifiable factors.

1. Introduction
Although the Black–Scholes formula is very popular among market practitioners, when applied to (‘vanilla’) call and put options it is very often reduced to a means of quoting option prices in terms of another parameter, the implied volatility. The implied volatility σtBS (K, T ) of a call option with strike level K and maturity date T actually depends on K and T , in contradiction with the Black–Scholes model. The function σtBS : (K, T ) → σtBS (K, T ) which represents this dependence is called the implied volatility surface at date t. Specifying the implied volatility surface at a given date is therefore
3

http://www.cmap.polytechnique.fr/˜rama/

synonymous with specifying prices of all (vanilla) calls and puts at that date. Two features of this surface have captured the attention of researchers in financial modelling. First, the non-flat instantaneous profile of the surface, whether it be a ‘smile’, ‘skew’ or the existence of a term structure, points out the insufficiency of the Black–Scholes model for matching a set of option prices at a given time instant. Second, the level of implied volatilities changes with time, deforming the shape of the implied volatility surface [11]. The evolution in time of this surface captures the evolution of prices in the options market. The shortcomings of the Black–Scholes option pricing model when compared to empirical data from the options

1469-7688/02/010045+16$30.00 © 2002 IOP Publishing Ltd

PII: S1469-7688(02)32334-0

45

R Cont and J da Fonseca

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E the options market and which are not present in the underlying asset dynamics [12]. In order to prevent the instability of model parameters resulting from this misspecification, it is necessary for the model to recognize these extra sources of randomness specific to the options market and incorporate the statistical features of their dynamics in the model. The aim of this work is to move a step forward in this direction and identify, through the study of dynamical features of implied volatility surfaces for two major option markets, some of the salient dynamic properties of option prices. Based on an empirical study of time series of implied volatilities of SP500 and FTSE index options, we show that the implied volatility surface can be described as a randomly fluctuating surface driven by a small number of factors. Using e a Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition, we recover and interpret the shape of these factors and study their dynamics, in relation to the underlying index. The implied volatility surface is then modelled as a stationary random field with a covariance structure matching the empirical observations. This model extends and improves the well known ‘constant smile’ or ‘sticky delta’ model [3] used by practitioners, while matching some salient features of implied volatility time series. Our stochastic implied volatility model allows a simple description of the time evolution of a set of options and provides a rationale for Vega hedging of portfolios of options. This modelling approach also allows us to construct a Monte Carlo framework for simulating scenarios for the joint behaviour of a portfolio of call or put options, leading to a considerable gain in computation time for scenario generation. Section 2 defines the implied volatility surface and the parametrization used. Section 3.2 describes the nonparametric smoothing procedure for constructing implied volatility surfaces from data. Section 3 describes the Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition and its implementation. This e method is then applied to two data sets: SP500 index options (section 4) and FTSE index options (section 5). The stylized empirical features of these two data sets are summarized in section 6.1. Based on these empirical observations, a factor model for the implied volatility surface is proposed in section 6.2. Section 7 presents implications for risk management, indicates potential applications and discusses topics for further research.

market have led to the development of a considerable literature on alternative option pricing models, in which the dynamics of the underlying asset is considered to be a nonlinear diffusion, a jump-diffusion process or a latent volatility model. These models attempt to explain the various empirical deviations from the Black–Scholes model by introducing additional degrees of freedom in the model such as a local volatility function, a stochastic diffusion coefficient, jump intensities, jump amplitudes etc. However, these additional parameters describe the infinitesimal stochastic evolution of the underlying asset while the market usually quotes options directly in terms of their market-implied volatilities which are global quantities. In order to see whether the model reproduces empirical observations, one has to relate these two representations: the infinitesimal description via a stochastic differential equation on one hand, and the market description via implied volatilities on the other hand. However, in the majority of these models it is impossible to compute directly the shape of the implied volatility surface in terms of the model parameters. Although it is possible to compute the implied volatility surface numerically, these numerical studies show that simple jump processes and one factor stochastic volatility models do not reproduce correctly the profiles of empirically observed implied volatility surfaces and smiles [7, 10, 13, 40]. This problem is also reflected in the difficulty in ‘calibrating’ model parameters simultaneously to a set of liquid option prices on a given date: if the number of input option prices exceeds the number of parameters (which should be the case for a parsimonious model) a conflict arises between different calibration constraints since the implied volatility pattern predicted by the model does not correspond to the empirically observed one. This problem, already present at the static level, becomes more acute if one examines the consistency of model dynamics with those observed in the options market. While a model with a large number of parameters—such as a non-parametric local volatility function or implied tree—may calibrate well the strike profile and term structure of options on a given day, the same model parameters might give a poor fit at the next date, creating the need for constant re-calibration of the model. Examples of such inconsistencies over time have been documented for the implied-tree approach by Dumas et al [17]. This time instability of model parameters leads to large variations in sensitivities and hedge parameters, which is problematic for risk management applications. The inability of models based on the underlying asset to describe dynamic behaviour of option prices or their implied volatilities is not, however, simply due to the mis-specification of the underlying stochastic process. There is a deeper reason: since the creation of organized option markets in 1973, these markets have become increasingly autonomous and option prices are driven, in addition to movements in the underlying asset, also by internal supply and demand in the options market. This fact is also supported by recent empirical evidence of violations of qualitative dynamical relations between options and their underlying [6]. This observation can be accounted for by introducing sources of randomness which are specific to

2. Implied volatility surfaces
2.1. Definitions and notations
Recall that a European call option on a non-dividend paying asset St with maturity date T and strike price K is defined as a contingent claim with a payoff of (ST − K)+ . Denoting by τ = T − t the time remaining to maturity, the Black–Scholes formula for the value of this call option with CBS (St , K, τ, σ ) = St N (d1 ) − Ke−rτ N (d2 ) − ln m + τ (r + d1 = √ σ τ σ2 ) 2

(1) σ2 ) 2

− ln m + τ (r − d2 = √ σ τ

(2)

46

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E where m = K/St is the moneyness and N (u) = 2 u (2π )−1/2 −∞ exp(− z2 ) dz. Let us now consider, in a market where the hypotheses of the Black–Scholes model do not necessarily hold, a call option whose (observed) market price is denoted by Ct∗ (K, T ). The Black–Scholes implied volatility σtBS (K, T ) of the option is then defined as the value of the volatility parameter which equates the market price with the price given by the Black–Scholes formula ∃! σtBS (K, T ) > 0, (3)

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces

CBS (St , K, τ, σtBS (K, T )) = Ct∗ (K, T ).

The existence and uniqueness of the implied volatility is due to the fact that the value of a call option as a function of volatility is a monotonic mapping from [0, +∞[ to ]0, St − Ke−rτ [. For fixed (K, T ), σtBS (K, T ) is in general a stochastic process and, for fixed t, its value depends on the characteristics of the option such as the maturity T and the strike level K: the function σtBS : (K, T ) → σtBS (K, T ) (4)

is called the implied volatility surface at date t. Using the moneyness m = K/St of the option, one can also represent the implied volatility surface in relative coordinates, as a function of moneyness and time to maturity: It (m, τ ) = σtBS (mS(t), t + τ ). This representation is convenient since there is usually a range of moneyness around m = 1 for which the options are liquid and therefore empirical data are most readily available.

a conditional volatility model (e.g. GARCH) or ‘calibrated’ with options data. In the first case, the quantity obtained is model dependent and in the second case it is the solution of a non-trivial and ill-posed inverse problem [8, 18]. Second, implied volatilities give a representation of the state of the option market which is familiar to the practitioner. A market scenario described in terms of the level or behaviour of implied volatility is easier to understand for a practitioner than the same statement rephrased, for instance, in terms of a local volatility or a jump intensity. Third, shifts in the level of implied volatility are highly correlated across strikes and maturities, which suggests that their joint dynamics is driven by a small number of factors and makes parsimonious modelling of their joint dynamics possible. Finally, implied volatility is increasingly used as a market reference by various market participants, as attested by the recent emergence of implied volatility indexes and derivative instruments associated with them, and also as a market risk indicator [32]. All these points motivate the study of the behaviour of implied volatility surfaces as a foundation for a market-based approach for modelling the dynamics of the options market.

2.3. Empirical study of implied volatility
At a static level, the dependence of implied volatility on strike and maturity has been studied in many markets by various authors. While the Black–Scholes model predicts a flat profile for the implied volatility surface It (m, τ ), it is a well documented empirical fact that it exhibits both a non-flat strike and term structure [11, 13, 17, 21, 25, 27, 33]. A typical illustration is given in figure 1 in the case of SP500 index options. The dynamic properties of implied volatility time series have also been studied by many authors in the literature; however most of these studies either focus on the term structure of at the money implied volatilities or study separately implied volatility smiles for different maturities. In other words, they study a cross-section of the surface in one direction, either moneyness or maturity, while maintaining the other parameter fixed. One then obtains a series of curves (smiles or term structures) to which most authors apply a principal component analysis (PCA). The term structure of at the money implied volatilities was studied in [27, 29, 30, 41]. In particular, Avellaneda and Zhu [41] performed a PCA of the term structure of at-themoney implied volatilities, modelling them with a GARCH process. H¨ rdle and Schmidt [29] perform a similar study on a the term structure of the VDAX and report the presence of level, shift and curvature components in the deformation of the term structure. Das and Sundaram [13] study the term structure of implied skewness and kurtosis, showing that empirical patterns differ from those predicted by simple models. Skiadopoulos et al [39] perform a PCA of implied volatility smiles of SP500 American options traded on the CME for different maturity buckets and distinguish two significant principal components. Alexander [1] performs a

2.2. Implied volatility as a state variable
As opposed to ‘local’ volatility, uniquely defined as the instantaneous increment of the quadratic variation of the underlying asset, there are a multitude of implied volatilities associated with a given asset, one for each traded option. Therefore, one is faced right from the start with a multivariate problem. Also, implied volatilities represent prices of traded options on the same underlying asset, which are linked by various arbitrage relations. It is therefore obvious that implied volatilities for different strike and maturity levels cannot evolve independently and that they form a highly correlated multivariate system. Arbitrage restrictions on the dynamics of implied volatilities have been discussed by Schonbucher [38] in the case of a single implied volatility and more recently by Ledoit and Santa Clara [31] in the case of an implied volatility surface. The above points seem to indicate that defining a model in terms of implied volatility rather than local volatility may complicate somewhat the modelling procedure. However, using implied volatility as state variable has some important advantages which greatly simplify the analysis. First, implied volatilities are observable: they are directly derived from market data without making any modelling assumptions on the processes involved. By contrast, the local volatility or conditional variance of returns is not directly observable and has to be filtered out either from price data using

47

R Cont and J da Fonseca
Average profile of implied volatility surface
0.30

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
S&P ATM implied volatility: 11/08/1999 –31/08/2001

0.34 0.32 0.30 0.28 0.26 0.24 0.22 0.20 0.18 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 0 Moneyness 1.5

0.25

Implied volatility

1.5

0.20

Ti m

et

om

0.5

atu r

ity

1.0

0.15

0

100

200 Days

300

400

500

Figure 1. Typical profile of the implied volatility of SP500 options as a function of time to maturity and moneyness, March 1999. options, Aug. 1999–Aug. 2001.

Figure 2. Evolution of at the money implied volatility for SP500

similar analysis but using the deviation of implied volatilities from the at-the-money volatility. Hafner and Wallmeier [24] study the dynamics of smile curves for DAX options. Fengler et al [20], use a common principal components approach to perform a joint PCA on implied volatility smiles of different maturity buckets. By contrast to the studies mentioned above, our aim is to consider, following our earlier work on SP500 options [11], the joint dynamics of all implied volatilities quoted on the market, looking simultaneously at all available maturity and moneyness values.

2.4. Deterministic models for implied volatility surfaces
The observation that the implied volatility surface evolves with time has led practitioners to develop simple rules to estimate its evolution [14]. A commonly used rule is the ‘sticky moneyness’ rule which stipulates that, when viewed in relative coordinates (m, τ ), the surface It (m, τ ) remains constant from day to day: ∀(m, τ ), It+ t (m, τ ) = It (m, τ ). (5)

Unfortunately these simple rules are not verified in practice: as shown in figures 6 and 17, the implied volatility surface It (m, τ ) has a noticeable standard deviation that cannot be neglected when considering either hedging or risk management of portfolios of options. Similarly, figure 2 shows the evolution of the at-the-money implied volatility for SP500 index options: as seen in this figure, even the at the money implied volatility, assumed to be constant or ‘slowly varying’ in the fixed smile model, fluctuates between 15 and 40% in less than a few months. Insufficiency of this ‘fixed smile’ approach has also been pointed out in previous studies [32, 35]. In this empirical study we precisely focus on these fluctuations of the surface It (m, τ ): what is the nature of these fluctuations? How can they be quantified, modelled in a parsimonious fashion and simulated in a simple way?

3. Methodology
We first describe in section 3.1 the data sets used. From the data we construct a time series of smooth surfaces, via a procedure described in section 3.2. This time series of smooth surfaces is then modelled as a stationary random surface to which we apply a Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition: section 3.3 presents e the method and section 3.4 discusses how it is applied to the analysis of implied volatility surfaces.

Another well known rule is the so-called ‘sticky strike’ rule: in this case one assumes that the level of implied volatilities for a given option (i.e. in absolute strike and maturity coordinates) does not change: ∀(K, T ),
BS σt+ t (K, T ) = σtBS (K, T ).

(6)

3.1. Data sets
The data sets studied contain end-of-day prices of Europeanstyle call and put options on two major indices: the SP500 index and the FTSE 100 index. We observe every day implied volatilities for traded options It (mi , τi ), i = 1 . . . n where n is a deterministic way. In a detailed study Balland [3] shows that in fact the only arbitrage-free models in which σtBS (·, ·) is deterministic are Black–Scholes models with deterministic (that is, time dependent but not strike dependent) volatility. He also shows that if It is deterministic then the underlying risk neutral dynamics is a process with independent log-increments.

These rules are described in more detail in [14] and [33]. Before proceeding further, let us note that the above rules are actually deterministic laws of motion for the implied volatility surface: given today’s option prices, there is no uncertainty (according to these rules) as to the value of implied volatilities tomorrow, up to errors due to smoothing/interpolation of today’s implied volatility surface4 .
4

More generally one can consider models where It (·, ·) or σtBS (·, ·) evolve in

48

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
Density of number of contracts

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces

one: the filtered data set is used to construct for each day a smooth estimator of the implied volatility surface, defined on a fixed grid, using a non-parametric Nadaraya–Watson estimator [2, 28]: ˆ It (m, τ ) = n i=1 It (mi , τi )g(m − mi , τ − τi ) n i=1 g(m − mi , τ − τi )

1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.5
Mon

(7)

1.0 eyne ss

1.5 0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8
Tim

1.0

1.2 atu 1.4 rity 1.6

m e to

Figure 3. Distribution of observations with respect to moneyness and time to maturity: SP500 options.

the number of options actively traded on that day. Typically n is around 100. Time to maturity τ range between a month and a year. Moneyness values outside the interval [0.5, 1.5] are filtered out since the numerical uncertainty on implied volatility may be too high and the liquidity very low. All options used are out of the money options: calls are used for m > 1, puts for m < 1. These are precisely the options which contain the most information about implied volatility movements. Implied volatilities are observed for a discrete set of moneyness and time to maturity values; the grid of observation is both irregular and changing with time as the level of the underlying fluctuates. Figure 3 shows the distribution of the number of observations as a function of the level of moneyness and time to maturity. As illustrated in this figure, the number of traded strikes decreases as we move far from the money and as time to maturity increases. Also, the maximum number of observations occurs at the money (m = 1) and not forwardat-the-money (m = −rτ ) which would create a linear bias in the position of the peak as τ increases. Also, the number of observations does not seem to be skewed towards m > 1 or m < 1 (this would advocate for example the use of logmoneyness instead of moneyness). Hence the choice of m as coordinate seems reasonable. Similar properties are observed for FTSE options (figure 15).

where g(x, y) = (2π )−1 exp(−x 2 /2h1 ) exp(−y 2 /2h2 ) is a Gaussian kernel. It is simply the convolution of the observed data points with the smoothing kernel g. The choice of the Gaussian kernel instead of another kernel does not influence the results very much. The important parameters are the bandwidth parameters h1 , h2 , which determine the degree of smoothing. Too small values will lead to a bumpy surface, too large ones will smooth away important details. The bandwidth can be determined using a cross-validation criterion [28]. A more efficient method is to use an adaptive bandwidth estimator in order to obtain an ‘optimal’ bandwidth h [9, 23]. Large sample properties of these estimators have been extensively studied, we refer to the monograph by H¨ rdle [28] or to [2]. a We thus obtain a daily time series (It (m, τ ), t = 0 . . . N ) of smooth implied volatility surfaces I : [mmin , mmax ] × [τmin , τmax ] → [0, ∞[ to which we apply an analysis of variance, described in the next section. Note that τmin > 0: it is around 2 weeks. In particular, we do not use points very close to maturity since it is well known that, in this range, implied volatilities may have highly irregular behaviour which makes them unexploitable for risk management purposes. Also, we do not attempt to extrapolate to τ = 0 since such an extrapolation will highly depend on the (arbitrary) choice of the estimator.

3.3. Principal component analysis of random surfaces
In order to analyse the joint dynamics of all implied volatilities, we model the implied volatility surface as a stationary random field, to which we apply a Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition. e The Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition is a generalization of e PCA to higher dimensional random fields. Let A = [mmin , mmax ]×[τmin , τmax ] be the range of values of moneyness and time-to-maturity. A surface parametrized by A ⊂ R 2 is a smooth map u : A → R. For two surfaces u, v define the scalar product u, v by u, v =
A

u(x)v(x) dx

(8)

3.2. Construction of smooth volatility surfaces
In order to obtain an implied volatility for arbitrary strikes and maturities, the practice is to interpolate or smooth the discrete data. This can be done either with a parametric form or in a non-parametric way. For instance, it is common practice in many banks to use (piecewise) polynomial functions to fit the implied volatility smile [17]. These choices are driven more by convenience than by any fundamental consideration. Given the absence of arguments pointing to a specific parametric form, the approach we have used here is a non-parametric

where x = (m, τ ) designates a point in the moneyness/maturity plane. Let U (ω, x), x ∈ A be a two-dimensional real-valued random field, defined as a family of random variables indexed by a two-dimensional parameter x ∈ A, such that each realization of the random field U is a smooth surface U (ω, ·) : A → R. One can then view the random field U (ω, x) as a random surface U (ω, ·). Viewing U as a family of real-valued random variables, one may define the covariance coefficients of two points on the surface as K(x1 , x2 ) = cov(U (x1 ), U (x2 )) x1 , x2 ∈ A. (9)

49

R Cont and J da Fonseca

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E described below. Choosing a family of smooth functions (surfaces) (hn ), one expands each eigenfunction on this basis: fi (m, τ ) =
N n=1

The function K(x1 , x2 ), x1 , x2 ∈ A is analogous to the covariance matrix of a random vector. One may also define the correlation coefficients C(x1 , x2 ). The covariance coefficients define the kernel of an integral operator K acting on a surface u through
Ku(x) =
A

aij hj (m, τ ) +

N.

(14)

K(x, y)u(y) dy.

(10)

K is a bounded symmetric positive operator; its eigenvectors fn 2 2 define an orthonormal family (fn ). Let ν1 ν2 · · · 0 the 2 associated eigenvalues: K · fn = νn fn . Each eigenfunction fn is therefore a surface fn : A ⊂ R 2 → R which is the solution of a Fredholm integral equation defined by the kernel K:
2 K(x, y)fn (y) dy = νn fn (x).

For example, one can choose as approximation functions (hj ) spline functions, commonly used for interpolating volatility surfaces and yield curves in financial applications. Substituting the truncated sum into equation (11) yields an error term εN =
N n=1

aij

A

dm dτ K(m, m , τ, τ )hj (m , τ )

(11)

2 −νj hj (m, τ ) .

The singular value decomposition of the covariance operator K can translate into a decomposition of the kernel K: K(x1 , x2 ) =
2 νn fn (x1 )fn (x2 ).

The Galerkin method consists in requiring that the error εN be orthogonal to the approximating functions (hn , n = 1 . . . N ): ∀j = 1 . . . N, εN , hj = 0 ⇐⇒
2 −νj N n=1

(12)

aij

Let Un (ω, x) = U (ω, ·), fn be the (random) projection of the random surface U on the eigenfunction fn . By orthogonality of the (fn ), (Un ) is a sequence of uncorrelated random variables and U (ω, ·) = Un (ω)fn (·) = Un fn . (13) Equation (13), which expresses the random field U as a superposition of uncorrelated random variables (Un · fn ), each of which is the product of a scalar random variable with a deterministic surface, is called the Karhunen– Lo` ve decomposition of the random surface U . Note e that the random variables (Un · fn ) are orthogonal both as random variables—elements of L2 ( , P )—and as surfaces— e elements of L2 (A)—which makes the Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition very convenient for computational purposes.

A

dx hi (x)

A

dx K(x, x )hj (x )

A

dx hi (x)hj (x) = 0. A = [aij ] Bij = hi , hj

Using matrix notation (15) (16)

Cij =

dm dτ
A A

dm dτ hi (m, τ )K(m, m , τ, τ )hj (m , τ ) (17) (18) (19)

D = diag(νi2 , i = 1 . . . N ) the orthogonality condition (15) can be rewritten CA = DBA

3.4. Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition: numerical e implementation
Given the high autocorrelation, skewness and positivity constraints on the implied volatility itself, we apply the above approach to the daily variations of the logarithm of implied volatility Xt (m, τ ) = ln It (m, τ ) − ln It−1 (m, τ ). First, we use market implied volatilities to produce a smooth implied volatility surface It (m, τ ) using the nonparametric procedure described in section 3.2. Next, we compute the daily variation of the logarithm of implied volatility for each point on the surface: Xt (m, τ ) = e ln It (m, τ ) − ln It−1 (m, τ ). We then apply a Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition to the random field Ut (m, τ ) = Xt (m, τ ). To this end, we compute the sample covariance coefficients K(m, τ, m , τ ) = cov(Ut (m, τ ), Ut (m , τ )), which specify the covariance operator K. Formally, we are faced with an eigenvalue problem for an operator in a function space. In order to solve the problem numerically, we reduce it to a finite-dimensional one using a Galerkin procedure for the Fredholm equation (11), as

where C and B are symmetric positive matrices, computed from the data. Numerically solving the generalized eigenvalue problem (19) for D and A and substituting the coefficients of A in (14) yields the eigenmodes fk . D yields their 2 associated variances νk . We then compute the projection xk (t) of Xt (m, τ ) on the eigenmode fk : xk (t) = Xt − X0 , fk =
A

Xt (m, τ )fk (m, τ ) dm dτ (20)

and analyse the scalar time series (xk (t), t = 1 . . . N ) (principal component processes). The surface then has the representation It (m, τ ) = I0 (m, τ ) exp k xk (t)fk .

(21)

Finally, we analyse the correlation between the movements in implied volatilities and the underlying asset returns by computing the correlation coefficients between xk (t) = xk (t)−xk (t −1) and the underlying returns ln S(t)−ln S(t −1) for each principal component k. We now describe the results obtained by applying this technique to two sets of data: SP500 index options (section 4) and FTSE index options (section 5).

50

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces
Standard deviation of implied volatility

0.40 Implied volatility 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.5 1.0 Moneyn ess 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 y 0.6 turit a 0.4 M 1.5 0.2 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 Money 1.4 1.5 0 ness 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2
Ti me to ma tur ity

Figure 4. Average implied volatility surface for SP500 options.
Average of log implied volatility: SP500 options

Figure 6. Daily standard deviation of SP500 implied volatilities as a function of moneyness and time to maturity.
Eigenvalues

100 –0.9 –1.0 –1.1 –1.2 –1.3 –1.4 –1.5 –1.6 –1.7 –1.8 –0.5
Mo ney

Log implied volatilty

10–1

10–2 1.0 nes sK /S(t ) 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 turity 0.4 Ma 1.4 1.6

1.5

0.2

10–3 200 199 198 197 196 195 194 193 192 191 190 Rank

Figure 5. Average log-implied volatility surface, SP500 options.

4. Empirical results for SP500 index options
The first data set contains end of day prices for all traded European style call and put options on the SP500 index between 2 March 2000 and 2 February 2001. These options are traded on the Chicago Board of Options Exchange and differ from the American style options, studied in [39], traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. Using the time series of smooth volatility surfaces estimated via the procedure described in section 3.2, we compute the sample average of the random volatility surface It (m, τ ), shown in figure 4. Here the average implied volatility is shown as a function of time to maturity in years and moneyness m = K/S(t). The figure shows a decreasing profile in moneyness (‘skew’) as well as a downward sloping term structure. Figure 5 shows the surface obtained when logarithms of implied volatilities are taken before averaging. Note that, while the skew persists, the term structure is less pronounced. This remark also pleads in favour of studying logarithms of implied

Figure 7. Sorted eigenvalues of covariance operator as a function of their rank for daily variations of SP500 implied volatilities.

volatilities instead of volatilities themselves. The sample standard deviation of implied volatilities, shown in figure 6, illustrates that the surface is not static and fluctuates around its average profile. This figure can also be seen as a test of the the ‘fixed smile’ model [3], which would predict a small or negligible variability in implied volatilities, plotted in moneyness coordinates. Clearly this is far from being the case. More precisely, the daily standard deviation of the implied volatility can be as large as a third of its typical value for out of the money options, resulting in an important impact on option prices. 2 The eigenvalues νk decay quickly with k (figure 7), showing that a low-dimensional factor model gives a good approximation for the dynamics of the surface. In fact the first three eigenmodes account for 98% of the variance, so in what follows we shall focus on their properties only. The shape of the first eigenmode is shown in figure 8. All of its components are positive: a positive shock in the

51

R Cont and J da Fonseca

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
Autocorrelation function of first principal component

1.0
0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0.5

0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6
Mo ney
1.0 nes sK /S 1.2 0.8 1.0 0.6 yrs) 0.4 rity ( 1.5 0.2 Matu 1.4 1.6

0.5 0.4 0 5 10 15 Lag (days) 20 25

(t)

Figure 8. First eigenmode of daily implied volatility variations for
SP500 index options. This eigenmode, which accounts for around 80% of the daily variance of implied volatilities, can be interpreted as a level effect.
Projection on first principal component: SP500 implied volatility 6 4 2 x1(t) 0 –2 –4 –6 0 50 100 Days 150 200 250

1.0 Sample partial autocorrelations 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.2 0 5

Sample partial autocorrelation function

10

15

20 25 Lag (days)

30

35

40

Figure 10. Top: in blue, autocorrelation function of x1 (t); in red, decaying exponential with time constant of 28 days. Bottom: partial autocorrelation coefficients. Time unit: days.

Figure 9. Time evolution of the projection x1 (t) of SP500 implied volatilities on the first principal component.

direction of this eigenmode results in a global increase of all the implied volatilities: it may therefore be interpreted as a ‘level’ factor. Figure 9 shows the projection x1 (t) of the surface on this eigenmode: it is observed to have a mean-reverting behaviour with a typical mean-reversion time of around a month. Figure 10 shows the autocorrelation function of the principal component process x1 (t): the autocorrelation coefficients are significantly positive up to a month, showing persistence in the values of the principal component process. As the partial autocorrelation coefficients show, this persistence can be conveniently represented by a low-order autoregressive process: an AR(1)/Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process already captures most of the persistence. Estimating an AR(1) process on the series gives an autoregression constant of 0.965 which gives a mean reversion time of 28 days. This time scale should be compared with the maturity of liquid options which is

around 3 months: they are both of the same magnitude showing that mean reversion of implied volatility is neither ‘slow’ nor ‘fast’ but happens at the time scale of the option maturity. Movements along this eigenmode, which account for around 80% of the daily variance, have a strong negative correlation with the underlying index returns. This observation is consistent with the so-called leverage effect: the overall negative correlation of implied volatility and asset returns. Note also that although the dependence in τ is weak, it is not zero, and multiplying the surface by a constant can amplify this dependence. Since the variance is large along this direction, large movements along this direction can induce term structure fluctuations. The second eigenmode, in contrast, changes sign at the money: the components are positive for m > 1 and negative for m < 1 (figure 11). A positive shock along this direction increases the volatilities of out of the money calls while decreasing those of out of the money puts. By biasing the implied volatilities towards high strikes, positive movements along this direction increase the skewness of the risk neutral

52

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces

0.06 0.04 0.02 0 –0.02 –0.04 –0.06 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 0 Moneyness 1.0 1.5 atu rity

Figure 11. Second eigenmode of daily implied volatility variations for SP500 index options.

2nd principal component process, SP500 implied volatilies, 1999–2000. 1.0 0.5 0 –0.5 –1.0 –1.5 –2.0 –2.5 –3.0 –3.5 –4.0 0 50 100 Days 150 200 250

0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 –0.1 –0.2 –0.3 –0.4 0

Projection of daily variation on 2nd eigenmode (SP500)

density. Note also that this mode exhibits a systematic slope with respect to maturity, which accounts for the term structure observed above5 (figure 6). Figure 12 shows the evolution of the projection of the surface on this eigenmode. Again, it exhibits a mean-reverting behaviour but with more intermittency, showing jumps and spikes. Inspection of the partial autocorrelation function, shown in figure 13, shows that the correlation structure can be well approximated by an AR(1) process. Estimation of an AR(1) model gives an autoregression coefficient of 0.924 which corresponds to a mean reversion timescale of 12.6 days. In contrast to what was observed for the first eigenmode, movements along this eigenmode are only weakly correlated with the underlying returns. This suggests that the leverage effect is not a general feature of implied volatility movements but is related to movements in the general level of implied volatilities, while relative movements of implied volatilities can be decorrelated with respect to the underlying. For a fixed maturity, the cross sections of this mode correspond to the shape found by Skiadopoulos et al [39] on another data set (SP500 futures options traded on the CME). The third eigenmode, shown in figure 14, is a ‘butterfly’ mode which is interpreted as a change in the convexity of the surface, accompanied by a downward sloping term structure which biases the magnitude of the fluctuations towards short term implied volatilities. In terms of risk, movements along this direction contribute to the ‘fattening’ of both the tails of the risk neutral density. This component only contributes to 0.8% of the overall variance. Table 1 gives summary statistics for the time series of the first three principal component processes. Each of them is highly autocorrelated and mean-reverting with a mean reversion time close to a month: figures 9 and 12 illustrate the sample paths. Inspection of the partial autocorrelation functions show that the autocorrelation structures (shown in figures 10 and 13) are well approximated by AR(1)/Ornstein–Uhlenbeck processes. Although the unconditional distributions are not Gaussian (all series have excess kurtosis and some skewness), the deviation from normality is mild. Similar results were found for DAX options in [24]. Also, none of these factors is perfectly correlated with the underlying returns. The largest (negative) correlation value is between the underlying and the first factor, corresponding to a value of −66%, but still remains significantly smaller than 1. Movements in other directions, which reflect changes in the shape of the surface, seem to have little correlation with the underlying asset.

Tim

et

om

5. Empirical results for FTSE options
20 40 60 80 100 Days 120 140 160 180

Figure 12. Top: time evolution of the projection x2 (t) of SP500 implied volatilities on the second principal component. Bottom: daily increments x2 (t). Time unit: days.

In this section we present the results obtained when applying the methods described in section 3 to a database of FTSE 100 index options. The options under study are European call and put options on the FTSE 100 index (ESX options). The database contains more than 2 years of daily transaction prices and quoted Black–Scholes implied volatilities for all quoted
5 Actually figure 11 shows a downward sloping term structure but recall that eigenmodes are defined up to a sign and normalization so the sign is irrelevant.

53

R Cont and J da Fonseca

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
Table 1. Summary statistics for principal component times series: SP500 index options.
Daily standard deviation 0.10 0.09 0.05 Proportion of variance (%) 94 3 0.8 Kurtosis (1 day) 6.4 7.9 7.8 Skewness (1 day) 0.4 0.15 0 Mean reversion time (days) 28 12.6 22 Correlation with underlying −0.66 0 0.27

Eigenmode 1 2 3

1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 Lag 12 14 16 18 20 Exponential decay with time constant = 12.6 days

0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 –0.02 –0.04 –0.06 1.5 1.0 0.5 1.0 1.5

0.5

0

Figure 14. Third eigenmode of daily implied volatility variations for SP500 index options.
Density of observations

1.0 0.8

Sample partial autocorrelation function

Sample partial autocorrelations

1.0 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 –0.2 0 5 10 15 20 Lag 25 30 35 40 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0.5
Mo 1.0 ney ne

ss

1.5 0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

1.4

1.6

t Time

o ma

turity

Figure 15. Distribution of observations with respect to moneyness volatilities. Top: autocorrelation function of x2 (t) (blue) compared to exponential decay (red) with a time constant of 12.6 days. Bottom: partial autocorrelation coefficients of x2 (t).

Figure 13. 2nd principal component process, SP500 implied

and time to maturity: FTSE options.

options on the LIFFE6 market (Aug.–Sept. 2001). Maturities range from one month to more than a year, moneyness levels from 50 to 150% with respect to the underlying. Observations are unevenly distributed in time-to-maturity and moneyness. Figure 15 shows the frequency of observations for a given moneyness and time to maturity as a function of these two variables, obtained via a non-parametric kernel estimator; it has a shape similar to the one observed for SP500 options (see
6

London International Financial Futures Exchange.

section 3.1). As in the preceding section, we first construct a time series of smooth surfaces by using the non-parametric smoothing procedure used in section 3.2. We then perform an analysis of some of the dynamical properties of the smoothed time series. We first compute the sample mean of the surface. The average profile of the implied volatility surface is shown in figure 16, on a logarithmic scale. As in the case of the SP500 index options, it displays a strong skew, the implied volatility decreasing as a function of moneyness, as well as some curvature in the moneyness direction. Note that the term structure is relatively flat. However, as seen from the standard

54

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
Mean surface

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces
1st eigenmode, FTSE options.

0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 0.5 1.0 1.0 Moneyness 0.5 1.5 0
Tim et o tu ma

1.5 rity 0.040 0.035 0.030 0.025 0.020 0.015 0.010 0.005 0 0.5 1.0 Moneyn ess

1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 y 0.4 rit 0.2 atu M 1.5 0

Figure 16. Average profile of FTSE implied volatility surface.
Standard deviation of daily log variations

Figure 18. First eigenmode of daily implied volatility variations for FTSE index options.
5

0.09 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.5
Mo

0

–5

–10

1.0 ney nes s

1.5 0

0.2

0.4

0.6
M

1.0 0.8 ty aturi

1.2

1.4

–15

–20 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500

Figure 17. Standard deviation of daily variations in FTSE implied volatilities. Figure 19. Projection x1 (t) on first eigenmode, FTSE options.

deviation of their daily log-increments (figure 17), the daily variations of implied volatilities do display a systematic term structure: short term implied volatilities fluctuate more than longer ones. Applying the Karhunen–Lo` ve decomposition (section 3) e to the daily log-variations of the implied volatility yields the eigenmodes (principal components) and their associated eigenvalues (variances). We then project the implied volatility surface each day on each eigenmode and study the principal component time series thus obtained. The variances, ranked in decreasing order, decrease very quickly: as in the case of SP500 index options, the variance of daily variations is well captured by the first three principal components which account for more than 95% of the observed daily variations. The shape of the dominant eigenmode is shown in figure 18. This eigenmode contains around 96% of the daily variance. Similarly to the first eigenmode for the SP500 surface, all of its components are positive: a positive shock

in the direction of this eigenmode results in a global increase of all the implied volatilities: it may therefore be interpreted as a ‘level’ factor. The projection of the implied volatility surface on this eigenmode is shown in figure 19: this time series is highly persistent mean-reverting. The one day lagged partial autocorrelation coefficient is significant and falls to insignificant levels after 1 day, pointing to an AR(1) correlation structure. Estimating an AR(1) model on the data gives an autocorrelation coefficient of 0.9808 which corresponds to a mean reversion time of 51 days, reflecting a high degree of persistence. The autocorrelation function, shown in figure 20, is well represented by the corresponding exponential decay over a timescale of 51 days. As in the case of the SP500 options, the mean reversion time is close to the lifetime of an option, not much shorter nor longer. The second eigenmode, shown in figure 21, reveals a clear slope effect: the signs of the coordinates are negative for moneyness levels m < 1 (out of the money puts) and positive for m > 1 (out of the money calls), changing sign at the money.

55

R Cont and J da Fonseca

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
Table 2. Statistics for principal component times series: FTSE options.
Daily standard deviation 2.9 0.43 0.27 Proportion of variance (%) 96 2 0.8 Kurtosis of xk (1 day) 9.3 5.7 7.5 Mean reversion time (days) 51 65 81 Correlation with underlying 0.7 0.08 0.7

Eigenmode 1 2 3

Partial autocorrelation function for 1st principal component, FTSE 1.0 Sample partial autocorrelations 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 –0.2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Lag Autocorrelation function of 1st principal component: FTSE options. 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Lag (days) 35 40 45 50 Exponential decay with time constant = 51 days 12 14 16 18 20

FTSE options: 2nd eigenvector

0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 –0.02 –0.04 –0.06 –0.08 0.5

1.0 Moneyness

1.6 1.4 1.2 y 1.0 rit 0.8 atu 0.6 om 0.4 et im 1.5 0.2 T

Figure 21. Second eigenmode of daily implied volatility variations for FTSE index options.

first three factor loadings. As in the case of SP500 options, they exhibit persistence and mean reversion. Their correlation structure is well approximated by an AR(1) process with mean reversion times around two months. However, for the second and third principal components both the unconditional distributions and the distribution of residuals have significant non-Gaussian features and exhibit intermittency, suggesting the use of an AR(1) model with non-Gaussian noise.

6. A mean reverting factor model for the implied volatility surface
6.1. Summary of empirical observations
Let us now summarize the statistical properties of implied volatility surfaces observed in these two data sets: (1) Implied volatilities display high (positive) autocorrelation and mean reverting behaviour. (2) The variance of the daily log-variations in implied volatility can be satisfactorily explained in terms of a small number of principal components (two or three). (3) The first eigenmode reflects an overall shift in the level of all implied volatilities. (4) The second eigenmode reflects opposite movements in (out of the money) call and put implied volatilities. (5) The third eigenmode reflects changes in the convexity of the surface.

Figure 20. Top: partial autocorrelation coefficients of the projection of FTSE implied volatilities on the first principal component. Bottom: autocorrelation function of x1 (t) compared to an exponential decay with time constant = 51 days. Time unit: days.

A positive shock in this direction therefore results in a decrease in the prices of out of the money puts accompanied by a rise in the prices of out of the money calls. In terms of the risk neutral distribution it corresponds to a (positive) increase in the skewness. The third eigenmode, shown in figure 24, again represents changes in the curvature/convexity of the surface in the strike direction, associated with a smaller slope effect in the maturity direction. Table 2 gives summary statistics for the time series of the

56

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
FTSE X(2)

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces
Log increments of implied volatilities projected on 2nd eigenmode 1.5 1.0 0.5 0 –0.5 –1.0 –1.5 –2.0 –2.5 –3.0

8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 –1 0 50 100 150

200 250

300

350 400

450

500

0

50

100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 Days

Figure 22. Projection x2 (t) on second eigenmode, FTSE options.

(6) Movements in implied volatility are not perfectly correlated with movements in the underlying asset. (7) Shifts in the global level of implied volatilities are negatively correlated with the returns of the underlying asset. (8) Relative movements of implied volatilities have little correlation with the underlying. (9) The projections of the surface on its eigenmodes (principal component processes) exhibit high (positive) autocorrelation and mean reversion over a timescale close to a month. (10) The autocorrelation structure of principal component processes is well approximated by the AR(1)/Ornstein– Uhlenbeck process. Similar results have also been obtained for DAX options, omitted here for the sake of brevity.

1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0

ACF of 2nd principal component, FTSE options.

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Lag (days)

Figure 23. Top: time evolution of the projection of FTSE implied

6.2. A factor model for the implied volatility surface
Based on these empirical results, we propose a flexible class of factor models which is compatible with these observations: in our framework the implied volatility surface is directly used as the state variable and modelled as a stationary random surface evolving in a low-dimensional manifold of surfaces. The (log-) implied volatility surface Xt (m, τ ) is represented by the sum of the initial surface and its fluctuations along the principal directions (fk , k = 1 . . . d): ln It (m, τ ) = Xt (m, τ ) = X0 (m, τ ) + fj , fk = δj,k d k=1

volatilities on the second principal component. Bottom: autocorrelation function of x2 (t) (blue) compared with exponential decay with a time constant of 51 days (red). Time unit: days.

xk (t)fk (m, τ ) (22) (23)

xk (t) = Xt − X0 , fk

Here λk represents the speed of mean reversion along the kth eigenmode, xk the long-term average value and γk is the volatility of implied vols along this direction. The ‘constant smile’ or ‘sticky delta’ model corresponds to the case where It = I0 , i.e. where xk (t) = 0. Our factor model is therefore an extension of the sticky delta model. In the stationary case, these parameters are simply related 2 to the empirical observations: denoting by νk the variance of the kth principal component, then xk = X − X0 , fk
2 νk =

where X0 (m, τ ) = ln I0 (m, τ ) is a constant surface and the components xk are Ornstein–Uhlenbeck processes driven by independent noise sources Zk , which can be Wiener or jump processes: dxk (t) = −λk (xk (t) − xk ) dt + γk dZk (t). (24)

(25) (26) (27)

γk2 2λk

corr(xk (t), xk (t + s)) = exp(−λk s)

57

R Cont and J da Fonseca

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E Arbitrage constraints for this type of model were first discussed in a risk-neutral framework by Sch¨ nbucher [38] o (see also [31]). However, in the case where the state variable is the whole volatility surface some care must be taken to define properly the available instruments and strategies in order to remain in the realm of applicability [12]. In contrast here we have studied the historical dynamics of call or put options: of course, this is the relevant point of view from a risk management perspective. Our approach bridges the gap between risk-neutral approaches [15, 31, 38] and the empirical work on historical dynamics of implied volatility [1,20,24,29,39,41] and allows automatic adjustment to today’s option prices which are simply calibrated to the initial condition I0 (m, τ ): X0 (m, τ ) = ln I0 (m, τ ). The link between the historical and risk neutral approaches is discussed in more detail in [12].

0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 –0.02 –0.04 –0.06 0.5 1.0

1.5

Moneyness

1.0

1.5

0

Figure 24. Third eigenmode of daily implied volatility variations for FTSE index options.

Ti m et o

0.5

m at ur ity

7. Applications and extensions λ1 0.035 0.0193 λ2 0.08 0.0152 λ3 0.045 0.0122

Table 3. Estimation results for factor model.
Data set SP500 FTSE

and may be estimated from discrete observations xk (t), t = 0, 1, 2 . . . of the principal component processes: indeed, under the above hypothesis xk follows an AR(1) process: xk (t + 1) = e−λk xk (t) + (1 − e−λk )xk + σk k (t) (t) IID noise σk = γk 1 − exp(−λk ) . 2λk (28) (29)

Estimation of the coefficients was done using a general method of moments procedure using the discrete observations xk (t), t = 1, 2, . . . , T . Estimation results are shown in table 3. In the case where Zk are independent Wiener processes, the implied volatilities have a log-normal distribution, which both ensures positivity and is consistent with many empirical observations in the literature.

We have presented in this work an empirical analysis of historical co-movements of implied volatilities of options on the SP500 and FTSE indices. Using a Karhunen– Lo` ve decomposition, we have shown that these fluctuations e can be accounted through a low-dimensional, but not onedimensional, multifactor model. We have extracted and interpreted the shapes of the principal component surfaces and showed that the principal component processes exhibit a mean reverting autoregressive behaviour similar to that of an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process. Of course the behaviour of these time series can be studied in more detail, going beyond second-order statistics and examining effects obtained by conditioning on various variables. However, already at this level, there are several interesting implications and potential applications, some of which we enumerate below.

7.1. The nature of volatility risk
An interesting feature of our data is that there appears to be more than one factor present in the movements of implied volatilities and these factors are not perfectly correlated with the underlying asset. While this may appear as no surprise to operators in the options market that implied volatilities of different strikes do not vary in unison, it is clearly not a feature of one-factor ‘complete’ market models which attempt to explain all movements of option prices in terms of the underlying asset. In other words: ‘Vega’ risk cannot be reduced to ‘Delta’ risk. The presence of more than one factor also shows that bivariate stochastic volatility models may lack enough degrees of freedom to explain co-movements of implied volatilities other than general shifts in their level.

6.3. Dynamics of option prices
An interesting feature of using implied volatilities as state variables is that the price of any call option Ct (T , K) is simply given by the Black–Scholes formula Ct (K, T ) = CBS (St , K, τ, σtBS (K, T )) K = CBS St , K, τ, It ,T − t (30) St and the continuous-time dynamics of Ct (K, T ) may be computed by applying Ito’s lemma to equation (30) [12]. This allows to compute Vega hedge ratios and generate scenarios for call/put options directly using the factor model (22). This should be contrasted for example with the approach of Derman and Kani [15] where the local volatility surface is modelled as a random surface: in this case the impact on option prices is complicated and non-explicit.

7.2. Relation with stochastic volatility models
Any stochastic model for instantaneous volatility also implies a model for the deformation of the implied volatility surface. This correspondence may be, however, very non-explicit [22, 34]. It would nevertheless be interesting to compare our

58

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E empirical findings with the dynamics of implied volatility surfaces in ‘traditional’ stochastic volatility models [4, 22], at least on a qualitative or numerical basis.

Dynamics of implied volatility surfaces

7.3. Quantifying and hedging volatility risk
Our model allows a simple and straightforward approach to the modelling and hedging of volatility risk, defined in terms familiar to practitioners in the options market, namely that of Vega risk defined via Black–Scholes Vegas. It also suggests a simple approach to the simulation of scenarios for the joint evolution of a portfolio of call and put options along with their underlying asset. Such approaches have already been considered in the case where the at-the-money implied vol is perturbated by random shocks while the shape of the smile is fixed: Malz [32] uses this approach for stress-testing; see also Rosenberg [35]. Our framework allows an extension to the case of a random smile/surface. These points shall be studied in a forthcoming work [12].

on Empirical Finance, HEC Montreal, Bedlewo workshop on Mathematical Finance, the Verona Conference on Credit and Market Risk, the AMS-SMF 2001 Congress (Lyon, France) and RISK Math Week 2000 (London and New York) for their comments and suggestions.

References
[1] Alexander C 2001 Principles of the skew Risk January S29–32 [2] Ait-Sahalia Y and Lo A 2000 Nonparametric estimation of state-price densities implicit in financial asset prices J. Finance 53 499–548 [3] Balland P 2002 Deterministic implied volatility surfaces Quant. Finance 2 31–44 [4] Barndorff-Nielsen O E and Shephard N 2001 Non-Gaussian Ornstein–Uhlenbeck-based models and some of their uses in financial economics (with discussion) J. R. Stat. Soc. B 63 167–241 [5] Black F and Scholes M 1973 The pricing of options and corporate liabilities J. Political Economy 81 637–54 [6] Bakshi G, Cao C and Chen Z 2000 Do call prices and the underlying stock always move in the same direction? Rev. Financial Studies 13 549–84 [7] Bakshi G, Cao C and Chen Z 1997 Empirical performance of alternative option pricing models J. Finance LII 2003–49 [8] Berestycki H, Busca J and Florent I 2000 An inverse parabolic problem arising in finance C. R. Acad. Sci. Paris I 331 965 [9] Brockmann M, Gasser T and Herrmann E 1993 Locally adaptive bandwidth choice for kernel regression estimators J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 88 1302–9 [10] Busca J and Cont R 2002 Implied volatility surfaces in exponential L´ vy models Working Paper e [11] Cont R and da Fonseca J 2001 Deformation of implied volatility surfaces: an empirical analysis Empirical Approaches to Financial Fluctuations ed Takayasu (Tokyo: Springer) [12] Cont R, da Fonseca J and Durrleman V 2002 Stochastic models of implied volatility surfaces Economic Notes at press [13] Das S R and Sundaram R K 1999 Of smiles and smirks: a term structure perspective J. Financial Quant. Anal. 34 211–40 [14] Derman E 1998 Regimes of volatility Risk [15] Derman E and Kani I 1998 Stochastic strike and term structure Int. J. Theor. Appl. Finance 1 61–110 [16] Derman E, Kani I and Zou J Z 1995 The local volatility surface: unlocking the information in option prices Goldman Sachs Quantitative Strategies Research Notes [17] Dumas B, Fleming J and Whaley R E 1998 Implied volatility functions: empirical tests J. Finance 8 2059–106 [18] Dupire B 1993 Pricing with a smile Risk 7 18–20 [19] Engle R and Rosenberg J 2000 Testing the volatility term structure using option hedging criteria J. Derivatives 8 10–29 a [20] Fengler M, H¨ rdle W and Villa C 2000 The dynamics of implied volatilities: a common principal component approach, Discussion paper no 38/2001, SfB 373, Humboldt University, Germany [21] Franks J R and Schwartz E J 1991 The stochastic behaviour of market variance implied in the price of index options Econ. J. 101 1460–75 [22] Fouque J P, Papanicolaou G and Sircar R 2000 Derivatives in Markets with Stochastic Volatility (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) [23] Gasser T, Kneip A and Khler W 1991 A flexible and fast method for automatic smoothing J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 86 643–52 [24] Hafner R and Wallmeier M 2000 The dynamics of DAX implied volatilities Working Paper

7.4. Generating scenarios for option portfolios
Given a stochastic model for the joint behaviour of the underlying and its implied volatility surface, one can in principle generate scenarios and compute confidence intervals for future values of the implied volatility. Given the monotonic relation between implied volatility and option prices, this can allow us to compute confidence intervals for the values of various call and put options and portfolios composed of these instruments. This may be an interesting approach for computing confidence intervals for future scenarios in the option market, but needs a more detailed characterization of the link between the underlying asset dynamics and that of the option market, perhaps going beyond covariance measures as we have done above.

7.5. Dynamics of volatility indices
Another field in which this approach has potentially interesting applications is the hedging and risk management of ‘volatility derivatives’ such as options on an implied volatility index. There are several such market indices at present: VIX (CBOE), VDAX (Frankfurt) and VXN (Nasdaq) are some examples. Such an index, if well diversified across strikes and maturities, will be sensitive to the factors described above (mainly the first factor). In summary, we find that the study of dynamics of implied volatility surfaces points to the possibility of a simple dynamic representation which seems to have interesting applications and links with other topics in financial econometrics and option pricing theory. We hope to pursue some of these research topics in the near future.

Acknowledgments
We thank Carol Alexander, Marco Avellaneda, Raphael Douady, Nicole El Karoui, Vincent Lacoste, Ole Barndorff Nielsen, Eric Reiner and seminar participants at Aarhus University, CNRS Aussois Winter School, Nikkei Symposium

59

R Cont and J da Fonseca [25] Heynen R 1993 An empirical investigation of observed smile patterns Review Futures Markets 13 317–53 [26] Hodges H M 1996 Arbitrage bounds on the implied volatility strike and term structures of European style options J. Derivatives 3 23–35 [27] Heynen R, Kemma A and Vorst T 1994 Analysis of the term strucure of implied volatilities J. Financial Quant. Anal. 29 31–56 [28] H¨ rdle W 1990 Applied Nonparametric Regression a (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) [29] H¨ rdle W and Schmidt P 2000 Common factors governing a VDAX movements and the maximum loss Humboldt University Working Paper [30] Heynen R 1995 Essays on Derivative Pricing Theory (Amsterdam: Thesis Publishers) [31] Ledoit O and Santa Clara P 1999 Relative pricing of options with stochastic volatility UCLA Working Paper [32] Malz A 2001 Do implied volatilities provide an early warning of market stress? J. Risk 3 no 2 [33] Rebonato R 1999 Volatility and Correlation in the Pricing of Equity, FX and Interest Rate Options (New York: Wiley)

Q UANTITATIVE F I N A N C E
[34] Renault E and Touzi N 1996 Option hedging and implied volatilities in a stochastic volatility model Math. Finance 6 279–302 [35] Rosenberg J V 2000 Implied volatility functions: a reprise J. Derivatives 7 [36] Rubinstein M 1994 Implied binomial trees J. Finance 49 771–818 [37] Sabbatini M and Linton O 1998 A GARCH model of the implied volatility of the Swiss market index from option prices Int. J. Forecasting 14 199–213 [38] Sch¨ nbucher P J 1999 A market model for stochastic implied o volatility Phil. Trans. R. Soc. A 357 2071–92 [39] Skiadopoulos G, Hodges S and Clelow L 2000 Dynamics of the S&P500 implied volatility surface Rev. Derivatives Res. 3 263–82 [40] Tompkins R 2001 Stock index futures markets: stochastic volatility models and smiles J. Futures Markets 21 4378 [41] Zhu Y and Avellaneda M 1997 An E-ARCH model for the term structure of implied volatility of FX options Appl. Math. Finance 4 81–100

60

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Fluid Dynamics

...FLUID DYNAMICS In physics, fluid dynamics is a subdiscipline of fluid mechanics that deals with fluid flow—the natural science of fluids (liquids and gases) in motion. Fluid dynamics is "the branch of applied science that is concerned with the movement of liquids and gases," according to the American Heritage Dictionary. Fluid dynamics is one of two branches of fluid mechanics, which is the study of fluids and how forces affect them. (The other branch is fluid statics, which deals with fluids at rest.)  Scientists across several fields study fluid dynamics. Fluid dynamics provides methods for studying the evolution of stars, ocean currents, weather patterns, plate tectonics and even blood circulation. Some important technological applications of fluid dynamics include rocket engines, wind turbines, oil pipelines and air conditioning systems. FLOW The movement of liquids and gases is generally referred to as "flow," a concept that describes how fluids behave and how they interact with their surrounding environment — for example, water moving through a channel or pipe, or over a surface. Flow can be either steady or unsteady. In his lecture notes, "Lectures in Elementary Fluid Dynamics" (University of Kentucky, 2009) J. M. McDonough, a professor of engineering at the University of Kentucky, writes, "If all properties of a flow are independent of time, then the flow is steady; otherwise, it is unsteady." That is, steady flows do not change over time. An example of...

Words: 1253 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Dynamic

...Part A Draw a CLD to explain the fish regeneration dynamics of ‘Lakeland Reserve’ based on the initial 500 fish in the Reserve area, assuming there is no fishing or other source of predation. Sketch a BOT graph as a reference mode that shows the pattern of change of the fish population over the 40 year period. Briefly explain the dynamics that your CLD reveals, any archetypal patterns of behaviour, and any other insights your initial analysis demonstrates. (This task has similar requirements to Assignment 1). BOT The BOT demonstrates the patterns of behaviour the fish population at ‘Lakeland Reserve’ over 40 years Year FISH POPULATION PATTERN OF BEHAVIOUR OF FISH POPULATION 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 40 Figure 1 As shown in Figure 1, at the beginning (t=0) there are only 500 fishes. Hence, more fishes are added to the reserve and the fish population in the reserve keeps growing. The rate at which fishes are added is at an accelerating rate. However, when the reserve reaches its maximum capacity at 4000 fishes, the fish population starts to decline at a diminishing rate. CLD The CLD visualizes the interrelated variables in terms of the behaviour of fish population at ‘Lakeland Reserve’ during this period Figure 2 Figure 2, the casual loop diagram including three loops (two reinforcing loops and one balancing loop), demonstrates the fish regeneration dynamics of ‘Lakeland Reserve’ based on the initial 500 fishes in the Reserve...

Words: 447 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Group Dynamics

...CODE: GCP 421 COURSE TITLE: BEHAVIOURS IN ORGANIZATION QUESTION: GROUP DYNAMICS GROUP 6 NAMES: MATRIC NO: COMB: 1. FIFONYINKEN SERAH ANU 20120104022 GCP/YOR 2. ABDULQADIR SHUKRAH ADEFOLAKE 20120104049 GCP/ISS 3. MEDAHUNSI ELIZABETH I. 20120104023 GCP/YOR 4. AJIBUWA ROSEMARY ADERONKE 20120104033 GCP/CRS LECTURER-IN-CH ARGE DR. ONABAMIRO A. A WHAT IS A GROUP A group is defined as two or more individuals who are connected to one another by social relationships. Every organization is a group unto itself. A group refers to two or more people who share a common meaning and evaluation of themselves and come together to achieve common goals. In other words, a group is a collection of people who interact with one another; accept rights and obligations as members and who share a common identity. MEANING OF GROUP DYNAMICS The word dynamics means ‘force’. Group dynamics means the study of forces within a group. Since human beings have an innate desire for belonging to a group, group dynamism is bound to occur. In an organization or in a society, we can see groups, small or large, working for the well-being. The social process by which people interact with each other in small groups can be called group dynamism. A group has certain common objectives and goals and members are bound together with certain values and culture. In organizational development, group dynamics refers to the understanding of behaviour of people in groups that are trying...

Words: 7387 - Pages: 30

Free Essay

Group Dynamics

...Group Dynamics Most people within the organizations belong to some formal work group that establishes temporary or permanent groups to accomplish tasks and achievements. These groups consist of different people within the organization who work together to accomplish objectives of the company (Jex & Britt, 2008). It is important that there is an examination of the behavior of the groups so that a complete understanding of the behavior is obtained. There are many types of groups that people become a part of in their everyday life including family, community, church, and within their profession. Memberships to these groups are important because it plays an important role in their behaviors and attitudes. This paper will identify an organizational group of which I have been a part of and will give analysis of the group dynamics of my chosen group. As a part of the analysis the group will be described including the purpose, goals, and demographic nature such as gender, education, and so forth. The stages are development experienced by the group is described and the structure and effect of the structure on the effectiveness of the group is written to help readers understand the importance of the group. Explanation of the dynamics of group behavior within the group and analysis of the effect that group has on me concerning group polarization, conformity, and groupthink concepts. Counseling Department for Georgia Department of Corrections There are many reasons to why a...

Words: 2032 - Pages: 9

Free Essay

Groop Dynamics

...Group Dynamics in Corrections Kadijah Batiste MGT 415 Angela Gillette 09/20/2010 Abstract This paper will provide understanding of group dynamics in the correctional setting using personal examples and outside research. Group Dynamics in Corrections The field of corrections is sometimes considered the lowly or “bottom feeders” in society. Correctional officers get the least respect in the public eye, but we have the most dangerous job. In society eyes we are just babysitters for adults so it benefits us to form groups within the institution so that we can have others to relate to about the job that we do. The group dynamics in a correctional setting consist of different groups. There are your 12 hour groups and your 8 hour groups. In corrections there are many groups from the small groups such as administration, kitchen staff, and janitors to the larger groups such as C.E.R.T team, disciplinary board members for inmates, and shifts. Group dynamics is the study of groups, behavior in groups, group development, and the interrelations between groups and individuals, other groups, and larger entities (Johnson & Johnson, 2009, pg. 1). In the correctional business world group dynamics is important because it enhances the group members’ productivity and how officers interact with one another can set the tone for the whole work environment. If there is discord among group members then the safety and security of the institution is jeopardized. Our textbook say that...

Words: 2200 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Group Dynamics

...In this essay I will be discussing the following group dynamics; developing a proposal, informed consent, involuntary membership, trust, and confronting. These dynamics include information on how to start a group, who the members may be, and what attitudes and actions a leader must practice while in a group. Developing a Proposal Your goals as a group leader are to find your clients, assess them, and ultimately help them with their problems. In order to accomplish this you must have good and strong proposal. It is the first step and it’s what will help launch the group off the ground. There are many questions to think about when forming your proposal. Here are some examples; * What type of group are you forming? * For whom is the group intended for? * Do you have the necessary skills needed to lead the group? * How will members be recruited and prepared for this group? * What topics will be explored? Group leaders also need to explore the following areas needed to serve the group; * Rational * Objectives * Practical Considerations * Procedures * Evaluation Informed Consent Informed consent is one of the very huge legal/ethical steps that must be taken before group counseling meetings can take place. Informed consent is a process of presenting basic information about group treatment to individuals to enable them to make rational decisions about whether to enter a group and how to participate, (Fallon 2006). Here are some examples...

Words: 721 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Group Dynamics

...Group dynamics The text defines group dynamics as interactions and processes that takes place between members of a team. When a group of people are assigned to complete a task as a team, it can sometimes be difficult. Whether the group of people know each other or not, when different attitudes, personalities, and work styles are combined, there’s always a possibility for things to go wrong. While this can present a challenge, it can also be the beginning of a great team. First and foremost, team members should first reach out to one another as a way of getting to know each other. Opening the lines of communication is key to having a successful team. From doing this, members are allowed to gain some knowledge of who their teammates are and what qualities they bring to the team. Assuming roles for team members is vital. Once those roles are assigned, members should trust their teammates to fulfill their duties accordingly but at the same time be motivating and encouraging to their teammates if and when needed. Motivating and encouraging each other builds a stronger trust among teammates which creates better team relationships. Being a successful team means everyone is on the same page. The ultimate goal is to finish the tasks successfully. Should conflict arise, and sometimes it does, it is everyone’s responsibility to resolve the issue in a mature and unbiased matter. This is when open communication is most required. References Bovee,C.L.and Thill, J.V. (2013) Excellence...

Words: 262 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Group Dynamics

...Institute of Business Administration, University of Dhaka Group Dynamics Our group for the Organizational Behavior assignment was selected by our course instructor for Organizational Behavior. Though this was a formal group, the fact that we had previously worked together and that the allotted time was limited meant that the group development processes took place quickly and the norms were already established to a great degree. All of us joined in the group discussions which was a good way to solve group conflicts. The work was divided according to individual expertise and we were sub-divided into groups; I had to work with another member on relating the motivational theories with the leader’s behavior while two other members worked on the leadership style aspects of the report. Then, the separate works of the sub-groups were compiled th by the 5 member. There was no distinct leader in our group because we were homogenous and of the same level of experience. Therefore it can be seen there was no distinct forming, norming and storming phases. But this did not have any negative impact on our performance. Tuckman’s Model of our team’s development is detailed in the table below: Stage Explanation Forming The team was formed by the instructor. Storming Subject of the assignment was chosen. Roles of the members were decided upon. Norming Members got to know each other properly. Performing All the members did what they were assigned to do. Adjourning ...

Words: 293 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Microsoft Dynamics

...Microsoft Dynamics Paper Justin Burchard Embry Riddle Aeronautical University Microsoft Dynamics The Microsoft Dynamics is a line of customer relationship management and enterprise resource planning software applications. The applications are delivered by reselling partners who offer specialized services to the business through a network. A vast majority of these software installations require the expertise of these resellers. The Microsoft Dynamics can be used by a range of the other Microsoft solutions including the office 365 and share point (Gupta, 2008). The business solutions provided by the Microsoft Dynamics include both the large business and small business enterprises. A group of enterprise-resource-planning products that are components of the Microsoft Dynamics ERP is mainly geared towards the small size business organizations incorporated with simple structures. The midsize business organizations are also equipped with the small-to-moderately complexity of their production prototypes. The Microsoft Dynamics ERP is comprised of five primary products Microsoft Dynamics AX The Microsoft Dynamics AX is simple and easy to use on large and small scale organizations. The Microsoft Dynamics AX type of ERP solution equips the user with software tools that are compatible with the other tools of the Microsoft solutions such as the Microsoft Office. The business software is comprised of features that apply to the global business...

Words: 757 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Group Dynamics

...any necessary corrections, this will hopefully not be needed for we will finish preparing the case prior to the weekend. Team members will come to the meeting having fully read the case ensuring utmost efficiency. Our team will be structured in a way that each team member will have set responsibilities prior to each meeting and presentation. Adam will be responsible for coordinating group meetings and keeping the team posted on due dates. Tyler will be responsible for final editing and bringing the completed work to class. Caio is in charge of the technology and will try to prevent any groupthink that may occur among the group. Derek will be responsible for preparing a case summary prior to each group meeting.  Team interaction and dynamics will work in such a way where everyone is respected, but debated. We will work in such a way where all assumptions are clearly discussed and no stone is left unturned. In order to achieve this we will have to be comfortable around one another when analysis time comes. Team rapport will build overtime, but we are going to try to meet bi-weekly in order to accelerate the process. We feel that fostering an environment where one has the ability to speak free of criticism if the true key to success. We all are hoping for an A grade but the skills we learn along the way are a more important goal for our group. We see real world applicability in the way this course is designed. We hope to learn many “soft-skills”, such as negotiation tactics...

Words: 422 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Group Dynamics

...The Most Important Characteristic of a Successful Group In my opinion the most important characteristic of a successful group is the Information seeker. It asks for clarification, facts and current information about the group. An information seeker is a very important person in a group because it has the ability to clarify any arguments, ideas and opinions with ease. A very good example of clarification would be that a person in the group will come up with many brainstorming ideas and opinions and is the job of the information seeker to organize and clear every theme so everyone in the group can understand what the topic is being discussed. One of the main problems in a group is that many of the group members sometimes don’t understand the material that is being discussed and more often feel very lost in the process, the information seeker does notice these problems and minimizes it’s stated in the paragraph before, the information seeker gathers facts and current information and it makes it easier for everyone in the group to understand everything that is being discussed. The information seeker also wants to stay current on the topic so it also incorporates a lot of current events regarding the information given. It is very important for an information seeker to keep every opinion and facts in order so the group can get a better understating and keep good moral in the group. In conclusion I do believe that information seeker is the most important characteristic of a successful...

Words: 277 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Group Dynamics Paper

...Group Dynamics and Processes Paper Walmart Employees No Longer “Get Happy” I recently read and article written by Rocco Pendola about the systematic struggles that the huge super-retailer Walmart is facing concerning its staff and lack of “team” environment. Rocco’s article begins when he initially posted 24 concerning pictures of various issues surrounding a huge variety of Walmart stores. Rocco began to receive a huge over pour of emails, photos and comments from Walmart employees around the country. In his article, Rocco uses the issues that he has researched about Walmart, as well as some of Walmart’s current and past employee letters to illustrate some of the current problems Walmart is facing. This article complies a great deal of information that helps us determine some of the mistakes Walmart has made on a corporate level as well as in it’s stores. Based on Rocco’s article, it is undeniable that Walmart suffers from a lack of Group Dynamics, and processes. Without continued use of Group Dynamics a company cannot continue to be successful, and ultimately a company cannot survive. According to our text, “a group is a number of individuals who join together to achieve a goal.” (Johnson & Johnson, pp. 5) this means that all members in the group are ultimately responsible for the outcome of the performance of the group, and all members have some kind of stake in the group, whether they know or understand their role, they all have one. If the group has several weak...

Words: 1476 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

System Dynamic Modelling

...1. Abstract System Dynamic Modelling is an approach to frame and solve complex problems. It is widely used for policy design and analysis. System dynamics analysis is a part of Systems Theory which is used to study the dynamic behaviour of complex systems. The theory is based on acknowledgement of the fact that the inter-relations between the various components of a model, time delays between processes are as important to analyse the behaviour of a model as is the analysis of individual components.  SD models solve the problem of simultaneity (mutual causation) by updating all variables in small time increments with positive and negative feedbacks and time delays structuring the interactions and control. In this paper, we have discussed the basic methodology of the technique, and the modelling process. Then, we have discussed the applications of SDM ranging from conventional ones like project management and science and engineering to exploring the concepts of SDM in Brand management and public health issues. 2. Historical background This technique of solving problems was developed in 1950s by Prof Jay Forrester of Massachusetts Institute of Technology, during his involvement with General Electric. He developed his insights about the foundations of engineering which helped him in the creation of system dynamics. He studied the problem of instability in GE employment. In this he did hand simulations (or calculations) of the stock-flow-feedback structure of the GE plants...

Words: 2058 - Pages: 9

Free Essay

Leadership and Group Dynamics

...Leadership and Group Dynamics-Self Assessment Summary University of Phoenix - Axia College XCOM/100-Introduction to Communications The self-assessment was very easy to complete and provided a detailed insight to my ability to work within a group, as well as my ability to lead a group of people. The results provided by the assessment showed that I was near the average or above average levels in all the results. I was not necessarily surprised to find the scores were in the levels they were, but the areas in which I need to improve I did find interesting. One area I need to improve on is being more task-oriented. While my belief of being more of a macro-manager was verified, the analysis showed I was not as balanced a leader as I had pictured myself to be. The assessment also pointed out my need to improve in disciplining others. I have to admit, I was a little surprised by this finding since I do a pretty good job of yelling at people, and that most of the people on my crew tend to make sure I don’t get upset. Some areas that I liked seeing includes my ability to trust people. This I think does coincide with my ability to lead people by allowing them the freedom to complete the task. The other good thing I saw was the assessment of my ability to build and lead a group. While I did not place in the top tier, I was in the higher section of the second tier. Being an effective leader is key in my industry and to my career...

Words: 360 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Group Dynamics-Process

...Group dynamics From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Group dynamics refers to a system of behaviors and psychological processes occurring within a social group (intragroup dynamics), or between social groups (intergroup dynamics). The study of group dynamics can be useful in understanding decision-making behavior, tracking the spread of diseases in society, creating effective therapy techniques, and following the emergence and popularity of new ideas and technologies.[1] Group dynamics are at the core of understanding racism, sexism, and other forms of social prejudice and discrimination. These applications of the field are studied in psychology, sociology, anthropology, political science, epidemiology, education, social work, business, and communication studies. Intragroup dynamics Intragroup dynamics (also referred to as ingroup-, within-group, or commonly just ‘group dynamics’) are the underlying processes that give rise to a set of norms, roles, relations, and common goals that characterize a particular social group. Examples of groups include religious, political, military, and environmental groups, sports teams, work groups, and therapy groups. Amongst the members of a group, there is a state of interdependence, through which the behaviors, attitudes, opinions, and experiences of each member are collectively influenced by the other group members.[10] In many fields of research, there is an interest in understanding how group dynamics influence individual behavior...

Words: 2624 - Pages: 11