Free Essay

The History of Finance

In:

Submitted By tianzi
Words 5360
Pages 22
The History of Finance

An eyewitness account.

Merton H. Miller

MERTON H. MILLER is Robert

R. McCormick distinguished ser-

vice professor emeritus at the

University of Chicago (IL 60637).

SUMMER 1999

* * * IT IS ILLEGAL TO REPRODUCE THIS ARTICLE IN ANY FORMAT * * *|

t five years, the German Finance Association A is not very old as professional societies go, but then neither is the field of finance itself.

Finance in its modern form really dates only from the 1950s. In the forty years since then, the field has come to surpass many, perhaps even most, of the more traditional fields of economics in terms of the numbers of students enrolled in finance courses, the numbers of faculty teaching finance courses, and above all in the quantity and quality of their combined schol-arly output.

The huge body of scholarly research in finance over the last forty years falls naturally into two main streams. And no, I don’t mean “asset pricing” and “cor-porate finance,” but instead a deeper division that cuts across both. The division I have in mind is the more fundamental one between what I will call the business school approach to finance and the economics department approach. Let me say immediately, however, that my distinction is purely “notional,” not physical — a dis-tinction over what the field is really all about, not where the offices of the faculty happen to be located.

In the United States, the vast majority of aca-demics in finance teach in business schools, not eco-nomics departments, and always have. At the same time, in the elite schools at least, a substantial fraction of the finance faculties have been trained in — that is, have received their Ph.D.s from — economics depart-ments. Habits of thought acquired in graduate school have a tendency to stay with you.

THE JOURNAL OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT 95

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

The characteristic business school approach tends to be what we would call in our jargon “micro normative.” That is, a decision-maker, whether an indi-vidual investor or a corporate manager, is seen as max-imizing some objective function, be it utility, expected return, or shareholder value, taking the prices of secu-rities in the market as given. In a business school, after all, that’s what you’re supposed to be doing: teaching your charges how to make better decisions.

To someone trained in the classical traditions of economics, however, the dictum of the great Alfred Marshall stands out: “It is not the business of the economist to tell the brewer how to make beer.” The characteristic economics department approach thus is not micro, but macro normative. The models assume a world of micro optimizers, and deduce from that how market prices, which the micro optimizers take as given, actually evolve.

Note that I am differentiating the stream of research in finance along macro versus micro lines, and not along the more familiar normative versus positive line. Both streams of research in finance are thorough-ly positivist in outlook in that they try to be, or at least claim to be, concerned with testable hypotheses. The normal article in finance journals over the last forty years has two main sections: the first presenting the model, and the second an empirical section showing that real-world data are consistent with the model (which is hardly surprising, because had that not been so, the author would never have submitted the paper in the first place, and the editors would never have accept-ed the article for publication).

The interaction of these two streams, the busi-ness school stream and the economics department stream — the micro normative and the macro norma-tive — has largely governed the history of the field of finance to date. I propose to review some of the high-points of this history, taking full advantage of a handy organizing principle nature has given us: to wit, the Nobel Prizes in Finance.

Let me emphasize that I will not be offering a comprehensive survey of the field — the record is far too extensive for that — but rather a selective view of what I see as the highlights, an eyewitness account, as it were, and always with special emphasis on the tensions between the business school and the economics depart-ment streams.

After my overview, I offer some very personal views on where I think the field is heading, or at least

where I would be heading were I just entering the field today.

MARKOWITZ AND THE

THEORY OF PORTFOLIO SELECTION

The tension between the micro and macro approaches was visible from the very beginning of modern finance — from our big bang, as it were — which I think we can all agree today dates to the year 1952 with the publication in the Journal of Finance of Harry Markowitz’s article, “Portfolio Selection.” Markowitz in this remarkable paper gave, for the first time, a precise definition of what had hitherto been just vague buzzwords: risk and return.

Specifically, Markowitz then identified the yield or return on an investment with the expected value or probability-weighted mean value of its possible out-comes; and its risk with the variance or squared devia-tions of those outcomes around the mean. This identi-fication of return and risk with mean and variance, so instinctive to finance professionals these days, was far from obvious then. The common perception of risk even today focuses on the likelihood of losses — on what the public thinks of as the “downside” risk — not just on the variability of returns.

Markowitz’s choice of the variance as his mea-sure of risk, counterintuitive as it may have appeared to many at the time, turns out to have been inspired. It not only subsumes the more intuitive view of risk — because in the normal or at least the symmetric distri-butions we use in practice the downside risk is essen-tially the mirror image of the upside — but it also has a property even more important for the development of the field. By identifying return and risk with mean and variance, Markowitz makes the powerful algebra of mathematical statistics available for the study of portfo-lio selection.

The immediate contribution of that algebra is the famous formula for the variance of a sum of random variables; that is, the weighted sum of the variance plus twice the weighted sum of the covariances. We in finance have been living on that formula, literally, for more than forty years now. That formula shows, among other things, that for the individual investor, the rele-vant unit of analysis must always be the whole portfo-lio, not the individual share. The risk of an individual share cannot be defined apart from its relation to the whole portfolio and, in particular, its covariances with

Email: reprints@iijournals.com for reprints or permission.|

--->|

Illegal To Reproduce This Article In Any Format.|

96 THE HISTORY OF FINANCE SUMMER 1999

It Is|

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

the other components. Covariances, and not mere numbers of securities held, govern the risk-reducing benefits of diversification.

The Markowitz mean-variance model is the perfect example of what I call the business school or micro normative stream in finance. And this is some-what ironic, in that the Markowitz paper was original-ly a thesis in the University of Chicago’s economics department. Markowitz even notes that Milton Friedman, in fact, voted against the thesis initially on the grounds that it wasn’t really economics.

And indeed, the mean-variance model, as visu-alized by Markowitz, really wasn’t economics. Markowitz saw investors as actually applying the model to pick their portfolios using a combination of past data and personal judgment to select the needed means, variances, and covariances.

For the variances and covariances, at least, past data probably could provide at least a reasonable starting point. The precision of such estimates can always be enhanced by cutting the time interval into smaller and smaller intervals. But what of the means? Simply aver-aging the returns of the last few years, along the lines of the examples in the Markowitz paper (and later book) won’t yield reliable estimates of the return expected in the future. And running those unreliable estimates of the means through the computational algorithm can lead to weird, corner portfolios that hardly seem to offer the presumed benefits of diversification, as any finance instructor who has assigned the portfolio selec-tion model as a classroom exercise can testify.

If the Markowitz mean-variance algorithm is useless for selecting optimal portfolios, why do I take its publication as the starting point of modern finance? Because the essentially business school model of Markowitz was transformed by William Sharpe, John Lintner, and Jan Mossin into an economics department model of enormous reach and power.

WILLIAM SHARPE AND THE

CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL

That William Sharpe was so instrumental in transforming the Markowitz business school model into an economics department model continues the irony. Markowitz, it will be recalled, submitted his the-sis to an economics department, but Sharpe was always a business school faculty member, and much of his ear-lier work had been in the management science/opera-

tions research area. Sharpe also maintains an active consulting practice advising pension funds on their portfolio selection problems. Yet his capital asset pric-ing model is almost as perfect an example as you can find of an economists’ macro normative model of the kind I have described.

Sharpe starts by imagining a world in which every investor is a Markowitz mean-variance portfolio selector. And he supposes further that these investors all share the same expectation as to returns, variances, and covariances. But if the inputs to the portfolio selection are the same, then every investor will hold exactly the same portfolio of risky assets. And because all risky assets must be held by somebody, an immediate impli-cation is that every investor holds the “market portfo-lio,” that is, an aliquot share of every risky security in the proportions in which they are outstanding.

At first sight, of course, the proposition that everyone holds the same portfolio seems too unrealistic to be worth pursuing. Keep in mind first, however, that the proposition applies only to the holdings of risky assets. It does not assume that every investor has the same degree of risk aversion. Investors can always reduce the degree of risk they bear by holding riskless bonds along with the risky stocks in the market portfo-lio; and they can increase their risk by holding negative amounts of the riskless asset; that is, by borrowing and leveraging their holdings of the market portfolio.

Second, the idea of investing in the market port-folio is no longer strange. Nature has imitated art, as it were. Shortly after Sharpe’s work appeared, the market created mutual funds that sought to hold all the shares in the market in their outstanding proportions. Such index funds, or “passive” investment strategies, as they are often called, are now followed by a large and increasing number of investors, particularly by U.S. pension funds.

The realism or lack of realism of the assumptions underlying the Sharpe CAPM has never been a subject of serious debate within the profession, unlike the case of the Modigliani and Miller propositions to be consid-ered later. The profession, from the outset, wholeheart-edly adopted the Friedman positivist view: that what counts is not the literal accuracy of the assumptions, but the predictions of the model.

In the case of Sharpe’s model, these predictions are striking indeed. The CAPM implies that the distri-bution of expected rates of return across all risky assets is a linear function of a single variable, namely, each

Email: reprints@iijournals.com for reprints or permission.|

--->|

Illegal To Reproduce This Article In Any Format.|

SUMMER 1999 THE JOURNAL OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT 97

It Is|

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

asset’s sensitivity to or covariance with the market port-folio, the famous beta, which becomes the natural mea-sure of a security’s risk. The aim of science is to explain a lot with a little, and few models in finance or eco-nomics do so more dramatically than the CAPM.

The CAPM not only offers new and powerful theoretical insights into the nature of risk, but also lends itself admirably to the kind of in-depth empirical inves-tigation so necessary for the development of a new field like finance. And its benefits have not been confined nar-rowly to the field of finance. The great volume of empir-ical research testing the CAPM has led to major innova-tions in both theoretical and applied econometrics.

Although the single-beta CAPM managed to withstand more than thirty years of intense economet-ric investigation, the current consensus within the pro-fession is that a single risk factor, although it takes us an enormous length of the way, is not quite enough for describing the cross-section of expected returns. Besides the market factor, two other pervasive risk fac-tors have by now been identified for common stocks.

One is a size effect; small firms seem to earn higher returns than large firms, on average, even after controlling for beta or market sensitivity. The other is a factor, still not fully understood, but that seems rea-sonably well captured by the ratio of a firm’s account-ing book value to its market value. Firms with high book-to-market ratios appear to earn higher returns on average over long horizons than those with low book-to-market ratios after controlling for size and for the market factor.

That a three-factor model has now been shown to describe the data somewhat better than the single-factor CAPM should detract in no way, of course, from appreciation of the enormous influence of the original CAPM on the theory of asset pricing.

THE EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

The mean-variance model of Markowitz and the CAPM of Sharpe et al. are contributions whose great scientific value was recognized by the Nobel Committee in 1990. A third major contribution to finance was recognized at the same time. But before describing it, let me mention a fourth major contribu-tion that has done much to shape the development of the field of finance in the last twenty-five years, but that has so far not received the attention from the Nobel Committee I believe it deserves.

I refer, of course, to the efficient markets hypothesis, which says, in effect, that no simple rule based on already published and available information can generate above-normal rates of return. On this score of whether mechanical profit opportunities exist, the conflict between the business school tradition in finance and the economics department tradition has been and still remains intense.

The hope that studying finance might open the way to successful stock market speculation served to support interest in the field even before the modern sci-entific foundations were laid in the 1950s. The first sys-tematic collection of stock market prices, in fact, was compiled under the auspices of the Alfred Cowles Foundation in the 1930s.

Cowles had a lifelong enthusiasm for the stock market, dimmed only slightly by the catastrophic crash of 1929. The Cowles Foundation, currently an adjunct of the Yale University economics department, was the source of much fundamental research on econometrics in the 1940s and ’50s.

The Cowles indexes of stock prices have long since been superseded by much more detailed and com-puterized data bases, such as those of the Center for Research in Security Prices at the University of Chicago. And to those computer data bases, in turn, goes much of the credit for stimulating the empirical research in finance that has given the field its distinctive flavor.

Even before these new computerized data bases came into widespread use in the early 1960s, however, the mechanical approach to above-normal investment returns was already being seriously challenged. The challenge was delivered, curiously enough, not by economists, but by statisticians like M.G. Kendall and my colleague, Harry Roberts –– who argued that stock prices are essentially random walks. This implies, among other things, that the record of past stock prices, however rich in “patterns” it might appear, has no pre-dictive power for future stock returns.

By the late 1960s, however, the evidence was accumulating that stock prices are not random walks by the strictest definition of that term. Some elements of predictability could be detected, particularly in long-run returns. The issue of whether publicly available informa-tion could be used for successful stock market specula-tion had to be rephrased — a task in which my colleague, Eugene Fama, played the leading role — as whether the observed departures from randomness in the time series of returns on common stocks represent true profit

Email: reprints@iijournals.com for reprints or permission.|

--->|

Illegal To Reproduce This Article In Any Format.|

98 THE HISTORY OF FINANCE SUMMER 1999

It Is|

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

opportunities after transaction costs and after appropri-ate compensation for changes in risk over time. With this shift in focus from returns to cost- and risk-adjusted returns, the efficient markets debate becomes no longer a matter of statistics, but one of economics.

This connection with economics helps explain why the efficient markets hypothesis of finance remains as strong as ever, despite the steady drumbeat of empir-ical studies directed against it. If you find some mechanical rule that seems to earn above-normal returns — and with thousands of researchers spinning through the mountains of tapes of past data, anomalies, like the currently fashionable “momentum effects,” are bound to keep turning up — then imitators will enter and compete away those above-normal returns exactly as in any other setting in economics. Above-normal profits, wherever they are found, inevitably carry with them the seeds of their own decay.

THE MODIGLIANI-MILLER PROPOSITIONS

Still other pillars on which the field of finance rests are the Modigliani-Miller propositions on capital structure. Here, the tensions between the micro nor-mative and the macro normative approaches were evi-dent from the outset, as is clear from the very title of the first M&M paper, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment.” The theme of that paper, and indeed of the whole field of corporate finance at the time, is capital budgeting.

The micro normative wing was concerned with finding the “cost of capital,” in the sense of the optimal cutoff rate for investment when the firm can finance the project either with debt or equity or some combi-nation of both. The macro normative or economics wing sought to express the aggregate demand for investment by corporations as a function of the cost of capital that firms are actually using as their optimal cut-offs, rather than just the rate of interest on long-term government bonds.

The M&M analysis provided answers, but ones that left both wings of the profession dissatisfied. At the macro normative level, the M&M measure of the cost of capital for aggregate investment functions never real-ly caught on, and, indeed, the very notion of estimat-ing aggregate demand functions for investment has long since been abandoned by macro economists. At the micro level, the M&M propositions imply that the choice of financing instrument is irrelevant for the

optimal cutoff. Such a cutoff is seen to depend solely on the risk (or “risk class”) of the investment, regard-less of how it is financed, hardly a happy position for professors of finance to explain to their students being trained, presumably, in the art of selecting optimal cap-ital structures.

Faced with the unpleasant action consequences of the M&M model at the micro level, the tendency of many at first was to dismiss the assumptions underlying M&M’s then-novel arbitrage proof as unrealistic. The assumptions underlying the CAPM, of course, are equally or even more implausible, as noted earlier, but the profession seemed far more willing to accept Friedman’s “the assumptions don’t matter” position for the CAPM than for the M&M propositions.

The likely reason is that the second blade of the Friedman positivism slogan — what does count is the descriptive power of the model itself — was not fol-lowed up. Tests by the hundreds of the CAPM fill the literature. But direct calibration tests of the M&M propositions and their implications do not.

One fundamental difficulty of testing the M&M propositions shows up in the initial M&M paper itself. The capital structure proposition says that if you could find two firms whose underlying earnings are identical, then so would be their market values, regardless of how much of the capital structure takes the form of equity as opposed to debt.

But how do you find two companies whose earn-ings are identical? M&M tried using industry as a way of holding earnings constant, but this sort of filter is far too crude. Attempts to exploit the power of the CAPM for testing M&M were no more successful. How do you compute a beta for the underlying real assets?

One way to avoid the difficulty of not having two identical firms, of course, is to see what happens when the same firm changes its capital structure. If a firm borrows and uses the proceeds to pay its share-holders a huge dividend or to buy back shares, does the value of the firm increase? Many studies have suggested that it does. But the interpretation of such results faces a hopeless identification problem.

The firm, after all, never issues a press release say-ing “we are just conducting a purely scientific investiga-tion of the M&M propositions.” The market, which is forward-looking, has every reason to believe that the capital structure decisions are conveying management’s views about changes in the firm’s prospects for the future. These confounding “information effects,” present in

Email: reprints@iijournals.com for reprints or permission.|

--->|

Illegal To Reproduce This Article In Any Format.|

SUMMER 1999 THE JOURNAL OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT 99

It Is|

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

every dividend and capital structure decision, render indecisive all tests based on specific corporate actions.

Nor can we hope to refute the M&M proposi-tions indirectly by calling attention to the multitude of new securities and of variations on old securities that are introduced year after year. The M&M propo-sitions say only that no gains could be earned from such innovations if the market were in fact “com-plete.” But the new securities in question may well be serving to complete the market, earning a first-mover’s profit to the particular innovation. Only those in Wall Street know how hard it is these days to come by those innovator’s profits.

If all this seems reminiscent of the efficient mar-kets hypothesis, that is no accident. The M&M propo-sitions are also ways of saying that there is no free lunch. Firms cannot hope to gain by issuing what looks like low-cost debt rather than high-cost equity. They just make the cost of higher-cost equity even higher. And if any substantial number of firms, at the same time, seek to replace what they think is their high-cost equity with low-cost debt (even tax-advantaged debt), then the interest costs of debt will rise, and the required yields on equity will fall until the perceived incentives to change capital structures (or dividend policies for that matter) are eliminated.

The M&M propositions, in short, like the effi-cient markets hypothesis, are about equilibrium in the capital markets — what equilibrium looks like, and what forces are set in motion once it is disturbed. And this is why neither the efficient markets hypothesis nor the Modigliani-Miller propositions have ever set well with those in the profession who see finance as essen-tially a branch of management science.

OPTIONS

Fortunately, however, recent developments in finance, also recognized by the Nobel Committee, sug-gest that the conflict between the two traditions in finance, the business school stream and the economics department stream, may be on the way to reconciliation.

This development, of course, is the field of options, whose pioneers, recently honored by the Nobel Committee, were Robert Merton and Myron Scholes (with the late Fischer Black everywhere acknowledged as the third pivotal figure). Because the intellectual achievement of their work has been com-memorated over and over –– and rightly so –– I will

not seek to review it here. Instead, in keeping with my theme, I want to focus on what options mean for the history of finance.

Options mean, among other things, that for the first time in its close to fifty-year history, the field of finance can be built, or as I will argue be rebuilt, on the basis of “observable” magnitudes. I still remember the teasing we financial economists, Harry Markowitz, William Sharpe, and I, had to put up with from the physicists and chemists in Stockholm when we conced-ed that the basic unit of our research, the expected rate of return, was not actually observable. I tried to parry by reminding them of their neutrino –– a particle with no mass whose presence is inferred only as a missing residual from the interactions of other particles. But that was eight years ago. In the meantime, the neutrino has been detected.

To say that option prices are based on observ-ables is not strictly true, of course. The option price in the Black-Scholes-Merton formula depends on the current market value of the underlying share, the strik-ing price, the time to maturity of the contract, and the risk-free rate of interest, all of which are observable either exactly or very closely. But the option price depends also, and very critically, on the variance of the distribution of returns on the underlying share, which is not directly observable; it must be estimated.

Still, as Fischer Black always reminded us, esti-mating variances is orders of magnitude easier than esti-mating the means or expected returns that are central to the models of Markowitz, Sharpe, or Modigliani-Miller. The precision of an estimate of the variance can be improved, as noted earlier, by cutting time into smaller and smaller units –– from weeks to days to hours to minutes. For means, however, the precision of estimate can be enhanced only by lengthening the sam-ple period, giving rise to the well-known dilemma that by the time a high degree of precision in estimating the mean from past data has been achieved, the mean itself has almost surely shifted.

Having a base in observable quantities — or vir-tually observable quantities — on which to value secu-rities might seem at first sight to have benefited pri-marily the management science stream in finance. And indeed, recent years have seen the birth of a new and rapidly growing specialty area within the profession, that of financial engineering (and the recent establish-ment of a journal with that name is a clear sign that the field is here to stay). The financial engineers have

Email: reprints@iijournals.com for reprints or permission.|

--->|

Illegal To Reproduce This Article In Any Format.|

100 THE HISTORY OF FINANCE SUMMER 1999

It Is|

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

already reduced the original Black-Scholes-Merton formula to Model-T status.

Nor has the micro normative field of corporate finance been left out. When it comes to capital bud-geting, long a major focus of corporate finance, the decision impact of what have come to be called “real” options –– even simple ones like the right to close down a mine when the output price falls and reopen it when it rises — is substantially greater than that of vari-ations in the cost of capital.

The options revolution, if I may call it that, is also transforming the macro normative or economics stream in finance. The hint of things to come in that regard is prefigured in the title of the original Black-Scholes paper, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities.” The latter phrase was added to the title pre-cisely to convince the editors of the Journal of Political Economy –– about as economics a journal as you can get –– that the original (rejected) version of the paper was not just a technical tour de force in mathematical statis-tics, but an advance with wide application for the study of market prices.

And indeed, the Black-Scholes analysis shows, among other things, how options serve to “complete the market” for securities by eliminating or at least sub-stantially weakening the constraints on high leverage obtainable with ordinary securities. The Black-Scholes demonstration that the shares in highly leveraged cor-porations are really call options also serves in effect to complete the M&M model of the pricing of corporate equities subject to the prior claims of the debtholders. We can go even further: Every security can be thought of as a package of component Arrow-Debreu state-price contingent claims (options, for short), just as every physical object is a package of component atoms and molecules.

RECONSTRUCTION OF FINANCE?

I will speculate no further about these and other exciting prospects for the future. Let me close rather with a question: What would I advise a young member of the German Finance Association to specialize in? What would I specialize in if I were starting over and entering the field today?

Well, I certainly wouldn’t go into asset pricing

or corporate finance. Research in those subfields has already reached the phase of rapidly diminishing returns. Agency theory, I would argue, is best left to the legal profession, and behavioral finance is best left to the psychologists. So, at the risk of sounding a bit like the character in the movie “The Graduate,” I reduce my advice to a single word: options.

When it comes to research potential, options have much to offer both the management science/busi-ness school wing within the profession and the eco-nomics wing. In fact, so vast are the research opportu-nities for both wings that the field is surely due for a total reconstruction as profound as that following the original breakthrough by Harry Markowitz in 1952.

The shift toward options as the center of gravity of finance that I foresee should be particularly welcomed by the members of the German Finance Association. I can remember when research in finance in Germany was just beginning and tended to consist of replication of American studies using German data. But when it comes to a relatively new area like options, we all stand roughly equal at the starting line. And this is an area in which the rigorous and mathematical German academ-ic training may even offer a comparative advantage.

It is no accident, I believe, that the Deutsche Termin Borse (or Eurex, as it has now become after merging with the Swiss exchange) has taken the high-tech road to a leading position among the world’s futures exchanges only eight years after a great confer-ence in Frankfurt where Hartmut Schmidt, Fischer Black, and I sought to persuade the German financial establishment that allowing futures and options trading would not threaten the German economy. Hardware and electronic trading were the key to DTB’s success, but I see no reason why the German scholarly commu-nity cannot duplicate that success on the more abstract side of research in finance as well.

Whether it can should be clear by the time of the twenty-fifth annual meeting. I’m only sorry I won’t be able to see that happy occasion.

ENDNOTE

This is a slightly modified version of an address delivered at the Fifth Annual Meeting of the German Finance Association in Hamburg on September 25, 1998.

Email: reprints@iijournals.com for reprints or permission.|

--->|

Illegal To Reproduce This Article In Any Format.|

SUMMER 1999 THE JOURNAL OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT 101

It Is|

Copyright @ Institutional Investor, Inc. All rights reserved.

PDF to Word[->0]

[->0] - http://pdfonline.blogspot.com

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Mathematical Economics and Finance

...Mathematical economics and finance: good or bad? Pareto and Walras were the first to use mathematics in economics and finance at the end of the nineteenth century. They created classical models of the free markets and explained these mathematically. After these models were created, other famous economists came up with mathematical economical ideas, such as Schumpeter and Keynes. Mathematics was used to simplify and clarify various complicated theories. This use resulted in both advantages and disadvantages. This essay will evaluate the uncritical use of mathematics in economics and finance on multiple aspects. Firstly, if one uses mathematics in economics and finance uncritically, one needs to know all the numerical values and other variables to actually explain and predict certain events and its mutual interdependencies. This knowledge is never entirely available, because the values depend on too many particular circumstances. What’s more, the succession of events in the history of the economics does not show any internal coherence, which makes predicting harder. Moreover, there is no controlled experiment in the economic research field and no falsifiable hypotheses are made (Von Hayek, 1989). Furthermore, different economic models have different implications, thus are applicable to according situations. Hence, not one mathematical model could be implemented (Rodrik, 2015). In addition, human beings and their behaviour should be included in the theories of economics. This...

Words: 790 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Owings And Kaplan Summary

...administrative personnel by providing a solid understanding of general finance and appropriate structure of federal, state, and local government. As the foundation, leaders have the correct knowledge to formulate and manage a school or district budget (Owings & Kaplan, 2013). After an introductory chapter on common misconceptions about school finance, the succeeding chapters delve into areas such as the legal framework for financing public education, school finance as an investment of human capital, taxation issues, equity, and structures of school finance systems. The authors illustrate the big picture of school finance,...

Words: 1234 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

History & Development

...Islamic Banking and Finance: History Development Slide #1 Some Issues History Of IBF Development of IBF -Overview- 2. Islamic Banking and Finance: History and Development History and Development of IBF in Bahrain Full Fledged IB vs. IB windows • Word ‘bank’ comes from the word ‘banco’ - A table or a bench on which Italian money-changers used to display their monies and records and conduct their transactions History of Islamic Banking and Finance • Arabic financial and economic system preIslam – Trading based arrangements were common • Bay’ al-musawamah (bargaining) • Bay’ al-muzayadah (auctioning) • Bay’ al-amanah (trust sale) – Al-murabahah (resale with profit) – Al-tawliyyah (resale at cost) – Al-wadiah (resale at loss or below cost) History of IBAF- (2) – Barter trade was common – Al-sarf (money exchange) • Lack of standardization – for e.g., 10 grams of gold in coin form = 15 grams of gold in bracelet form – Institutionalization of riba – Widespread gharar and maysir – Monopoly, fraud and economic injustice was common History of IBAF- (3) • With the advent of Islam, – Eradication of riba institutions and practices – Eradication of gharar transactions – Institutionalization of fair and equitable markets • No monopoly, fraud • Standardization of money and commodity exchanges – Hadith on the six commodities – Islamization of many business organizations and institutions • Mudarabah, musyarakah, salam, muzara’ah (sharecropping or partnership...

Words: 4259 - Pages: 18

Premium Essay

India Research Paper

...Tour of the World Research Paper-India A Business Report on India A business partnership with at global level demands that the country chosen for business must promise the new business with growth, diversification profit. A lot has been said about the countries of the West regarding their age old stable systems and their efficiency at handling business. However, western markets are highly saturated and suffer from several issues, including sanctions, clandestine policies and reduced distribution of power. Newly developed or developing countries, on the other hand, have the potential to not only accommodate a new business in their markets. Amongst the top developing countries in the world, India is considered as one of the fastest developing economies (Thapar, 2002). It is also claimed that setting up a business in this economy is beneficial in terms of growth and profit. Research of information available in the market and the media is required to understand how and why India can be considered as an option of a new market for the purpose of expanding business. India is the seventh largest country in the world, the second most in population levels and the largest democracy in the world. The government system in the country is quasi-federal, which means that it has a bipartisan political system that is based on American federal government as well on the Westminster system of the United Kingdom which has followed a two house system. The states have their own...

Words: 2381 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Ethics

...need for the role of ethics and compliance in the organization’s financial environment. The consequences can be permanent if not for the success history of the finance ethics and compliance team. The primary focus of Microsoft finance team’s mission includes providing world class financial leadership to optimize long term shareholder value as well as be recognized in the industry as setting the utmost highest degree of leadership in using innovative processes, tools, and systems. Microsoft Finance team members uphold values in each role of the company in order for each job be in compliance with the ethical policies and guidelines that includes finance service, integrity, results, and assisting other individuals be successful through their efforts. Ethical and compliance practices are maintained through Microsoft’s Overview that includes the Finance Code of Professional Conduct, Shareholder Accountability, Corporate Policies and Guidelines, and Board of Directors. Microsoft’s Chief Executive Officer (CEO), Chief Financial Officer (CFO), Corporate Controller, and the employees of the finance organization uphold important and prominent roles in corporate governance that ensure the company’s financials are balanced, protected, and preserved. The Corporate Policies and Guidelines are said to have been over the course of Microsoft's history, the Board of Directors has developed corporate governance policies and practices to help it fulfill its responsibilities to shareholders (Microsoft...

Words: 518 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Jacobs

...Jacobs Engineering Group, Inc. (JEC) Introduction Emerging from humble beginnings, Jacobs Engineering Group is as bonafide global entity. With headquarters in Pasadena, California, Jacobs’ company culture is based on investment in employees, relationship-building amongst clients, and focusing on continual growth.1 With offices on every continent, Jacobs continues to gain strength as a most viable global engineering company. History of the Company Jacobs Engineering Group was started in 1947 by Joseph J. Jacobs. Of Lebanese descent and influenced heavily by the Lebanese tradition of entrepreneurial pursuit—and coupled with Jacobs’ inability to find steady work during the Depression—lead Jacobs to eventually start his own company. Operating as both an engineering consultant and manufacturer’s broker for process equipment, Jacobs was able to offer sales and technical services to engineering companies.2 Moving the company to California put Jacobs Engineering Group in a prime location for growth and expansion. Initially, growth in the sales sector proved to be more viable than consulting services.3 However, upon securing its first and largest contract to date in 1956 with Kaiser Aluminum, Jacobs Engineering Group saw continued growth in its technical-consulting sector throughout the 1960’s and 1970’s. Enduring financial setbacks in the 1980’s and a resurgence through company expansion in the 1990’s placed Jacobs as an engineering powerhouse amongst international entities...

Words: 1131 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Consulting

...Programmes available for non-FBE students Programme School of Business Business School of Economics and Finance Economics Finance Major X √ √ Minor √ √ √ II. GPA Requirement A yearly GPA of 3.0 of above as of August 31 (excluding Summer Semester) at the end of the first year of study must be obtained for eligibility to declare any major or minor offered by the Faculty of Business and Economics. For students who fail to meet the GPA requirement at the end of their second year of study, their declaration of FBE major/minor will be removed from the SIS by their home Faculty. III. Requirements for Major Programmes Students are required to complete 60 credits of prescribed courses for each major as follows: (A) Majors offered by the School of Economics and Finance 1. Major in Economics (60 credits) Course code Course Credits Year 1 courses: 12 credits ECON1001 Introduction to economics I 6 ECON1002 Introduction to economics II 6 Year 2 and Year 3 courses: 48 credits ECON2101 Microeconomic theory or 6 ECON2113 Microeconomic analysis 6 ECON2102 Macroeconomic theory or Macroeconomic analysis ECON2114 ECONxxxx/ Year two/Year three courses listed in Economics 36 FINAxxxx or Finance electives Total: 60 2. Major in Finance (60 credits) Course code Course Year 1 courses: 18 credits BUSI1002 Introduction to accounting ECON1001 Introduction to economics I FINA1003 Corporate finance Year 2 and Year 3 courses: 42 credits ECON2101 Microeconomic theory or ECON2113 Microeconomic analysis...

Words: 1346 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Efgs

...Bayasgelan Batgerel, Constance Gully, Lau Renzo, Gauthier Schilling Professor Fillenwarth Finance-52010 July 2013 Financial Analysis of V.F. Corporation (NYSE: VFC) Table of Contents Executive Summary.......................................................................................................................................2 CompanyHistory...........................................................................................................................3 Common Size Analysis.................................................................................................................6 Ratio Analysis...............................................................................................................................7 DuPont Chain...............................................................................................................................9 Cash Conversion Cycle..............................................................................................................11 Cost of Capital...........................................................................................................................13 Company Stock value................................. ..............................................................................17 Works Cited..............................................................................................................................20 Appendix A – Excel workbook.............

Words: 4033 - Pages: 17

Premium Essay

Investment Banking &

...[pic] Master in Business Administration COURSE SYLLABUS Investment Banking And Structured Finance Analytics Course Code: IBSFA Faculty: Prof. E. B. Perez Course Description This is an advanced finance course suited for finance majors. However, the focus is on the practice and business of investment banking. Corporate finance skills are assumed, as well as concepts regarding structured finance. Grading Class Participation 50% Class Presentation 50% Course Outline |Session |Cases, Readings and Exercises | | | | |1 |Case: CML Group, Inc. (A) and (B) | | | | | |Session 1 CML Group, Inc. (A) and (B); the (C) for class distribution. | | |2 Hutchison-Whampoa LTD - Yankee Bond Offering | | |3 Chase's Strategy for Syndicating the Hong Kong Disneyland Loan (A) ...

Words: 2616 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Financial Risk Management

...Brief Introduction of Financial Risk Management Financial risk management is an interdiscipline with various researching subfields including the studies of mathematical methods to maximum the profits, quantitative analysis of financial databases and investment decisions. In other words, it is aimed to bridge the gap between mathematical theories and practical financial analysing tools (Nawrocki 1999). It could also be defined as“Living with the possibility that future events may cause adverse effects” (Kloman 1999). Risk and profit are always an integral. The variety of risks including portfolio risk, credit risk and liquidity risk became a financial conundrum which equalled to a group of destructive nuclear bombs hidden in the monetary market. Consequently, the risk management represents the core competence in insurance and banking industries. With the innovation of IT technology, more advanced computer software has been introduced in financial area which results that the risk management has made impressive strides in last decade. As the academic field mature constantly, the abstract mathematical and statistic concepts reifies to accessible programs which could predict the trends of investment returns, for example, the expected earnings at the end of next week after buying certain amount of stock at next Monday (Chapman 1996, iv). The origin of risk management could date back to the game theories introduced by two French mathematicians...

Words: 1007 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

The Development of Modern Finance

...The Development of Modern Finance "A Short History of Value" David Roubaud & Jean-Charles Bagneris 10/2011 The Main Steps of the Theory Building • Portfolio Selection (Markowitz, 1952) • CAPM (Sharpe, 1963) • Financing and Dividend Decisions Neutrality (Modigliani et Miller, 1958, 1961,1963) • Efficient Markets (Fama, 1965, 1970) • Options Pricing Theory (Black & Scholes, 1973, Myers, 1977) • Agency Theory (Jensen, Meckling, 1976) • Efficient Markets II (Fama, 1991) • Behavioural Finance (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979, Shiller, 1981, 2000) Portfolio Selection • Investors are rationals and risk averse • Diversification lowers specific risk • Any portfolio is a combination of the market portfolio and the riskless asset The CAPM Capital Asset Pricing Model • Systematic risk of an asset is measured by its beta coefficient • The model calibrates the risk-return relationship • Simple, elegant and linear model => big success • Low explaining power (strong assumptions) • Alternative models are difficult to use 1 The Development of Modern Finance 2 Financial Markets Efficiency "At any given point in time, assets prices on financial markets account for all available information." • Strong assumptions on: – markets organization – investors behaviour • One consequence of EMH is Random Walk Hypothesis • Assumptions are not always true: 3 forms of efficiency (strong, semi-strong, weak) The irrelevance of financing and dividends decisions In a world without taxes and with perfect financial markets...

Words: 678 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Sme Sector

...30% to GDP and 25% to the country’s total export earnings, and employs close to 70% of the labor force in the manufacturing industry, services, and trade. Their share in manufacturing value addition is estimated to be around 35%. Small & medium businesses play a very critical role when economies are transiting from low to middle income levels yet Pakistan has paid less attention to the growth and development of this crucial pillar of economy. Our report mainly focuses on the financial constraint to growth of this sector. Capital requirements: According to SMEDA there’re 800,000 SMEs in Pakistan that are eligible for bank loans. Another 2.4 million potential businesses that can’t qualify for bank loans mainly rely on other sources of finance for their business needs. Approximately 89% of working capital and 75% of fixed investments are financed from retained earnings. (See exhibit 1-B) Remaining financing needs are fulfilled from external sources which include family and friends, bank loans and other small sources as depicted in exhibit 2-A. Despite the importance of SMEs in the economy, as of December 2007 fewer than 200,000 borrow from the banking sector and SME lending volumes (that is, loans of up to Rs 75 million) account only for 16% of total credit. ADB survey results show that that there is a particularly acute financing gap for loan sizes between Rs 100,000 (the maximum loan size that microfinance institutions (MFIs) can offer) and...

Words: 1043 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Finance

...SUGGESTED PROGRAM PLAN FOR FINANCE MAJORS FIRST YEAR Fall Semester (14 or 15 credits) Spring Semester (15 or 16 credits) ENG106 Writing Intensive First Year Seminar* HCS100 Hum Comm Studies HIS101 World History I* HIS106 World History II* MAT108 Finite Math MAT181 Applied Calculus I ________ General Education elective ISM142 Business Computer Systems* BSN101 Foundations of Bus Admin (2 crs.)* ________ General Education elective or a General Education elective* or ECO113 Principles of Economics (4 crs.) SECOND YEAR Fall Semester (16 or 15 credits) Spring Semester (15 credits) ACC200 Fundamentals of Financial Accounting ACC201 Managerial Accounting SCM200 Statistical Applications in Business* BSL261 American Legal Environment* ECO113 Principles of Economics (4 crs) ECO280 Managerial Economics or a General Education elective ________ General Education elective ________ General Education elective ________ General Education elective ________ General Education elective THIRD YEAR Fall Semester (15 credits) Spring Semester (15 credits) FIN311 Financial Management FIN313 Advanced Financial Management (SP) MKT305 Principles of Marketing FIN333 Applied Comp. & Security Analysis (SP) MGT305 Organizational Behavior SCM330 Supply Chain & Operations Management ________ General Education elective ________ Free elective ________ General Education elective ________ General Education or Free elective FOURTH...

Words: 620 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Isb Project

...1. Introduction History of Islamic Business Transaction Without a doubt, the history of Islamic Banking is quite interesting. Since the medieval era (1,000 – 1,500 AD), businesspeople in the Middle East engaged in financial transactions. At this time though, these transactions used the same financial principles as the Europeans.   Early History of Islamic Banking Since the Arabs of the Ottoman Empire traded extensively with people in Spain, they also developed certain no-interest financial systems that worked on a profit and loss sharing method. These systems, in turn, financed trade and other business affairs. When the  Middle Eastern and Asia began to be more important trading partners for various European companies, the Europeans opened banks in these countries – with many of these banks based on the interest-bearing financial system. As the trading relationship with the Europeans continued to play an important role, these types of financial institutions began to be more prominent outside of Europe. However, even when local trading business owners used these commercial banks, they often only transferred money between accounts.  Both borrowing and depositing money was limited as the local population wanted to refrain from partaking in interest-bearing transactions. Further, certain co-operative institutions based on the original profit and loss sharing model still existed, but only in certain locations. As economic demands increased, avoiding banks was not an option...

Words: 2847 - Pages: 12

Free Essay

Training and Development

... | | | |6/13/2009 | | | |Priyanka and Baljeet | This project with International Autotrac Finance Ltd as a combination of hard works & challenges and was both exciting and simulating. No project being individualistic efforts, this is one too is a combination of the efforts and views of many people. I would like to express my gratitude to all. First I would like to thanks Dr. Gurwinder who has given me the opportunity to do summer training in Sonlaika International Tractors Limited. I am very thankful to Mr. Rohit Mohan (Manager Finance cum Company Secretary), without his efforts it would have been impossible for me to get and complete project. I want to pay my regards to Ms Richa Gautam for being my corporate guide and as well as for continuous encouragement and guidance which he has given me during the course of the project. I also wish to convey special thanks and reverence to other colleagues of the IAFL department who has provided valuable acumen into project. Last but not the least would like to express my gratitude to the faculty at ICFAI...

Words: 2414 - Pages: 10